View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
12:3t) p.m., E.D.T.
September 17, 1986

Address

by

Manuel H. Johnson
Vice Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

before the

Conference on Exchange Rates and International Monetary Reform

American Enterprise Institute

Washington, D.C.

September 17, 1986

A discussion about exchange rates and international monetary

reform is perennially appropriate at this time of year, just a couple of

weeks before the annual meeting of the International Monetary Fund.

It

helps each of us to clarify our own thinking, if not for the formal

sessions themselves at least for the associated corridor discussions or

for reading the newspaper accounts.

This year such a discussion seems especially appropriate.

During the past year there have been two major international policy

developments related to this topic.

There was the Plaza announcement in

New York almost exactly a year ago, in which finance ministers and

central bank governors from 6-5 countries reiterated their intentions to

pursue policies consistent with restoration of better balance

internationally and expressed their view that exchange rates did not

then reflect this convergence of policy or of economic performance.

at the May economic summit in Tokyo, efforts to enhance the inter­

national coordination of economic policy were given strong political

impetus.

And

- 2 Moreover, developments in exchange markets, themselves, have

helped to make this topic interesting and important.

Over the past year

and a half, the exchange value of the dollar has declined about 40

percent against both the Japanese yen and the Deutsche mark.

This

followed a rise in the dollar's value over the previous four years or so

of 80 percent against the DM but only 20 percent against the yen.

I might observe at this point that it is not easy in general

to characterize the change in the value of any particular currency

against all others--even in nominal terms, let alone adjusted for

changes in relative price levels.

Unless a currency moves uniformly

against all others, a summary measure of the change in its value depends

upon the weighting system used.

The staff at the Federal Reserve Board

uses an index based on multilateral trade weights and G-10 currencies;

it shows that the dollar rose 80 percent from 1980 to early 1985 and

then fell about 70 percent, bringing it currently to about 20 percent

above its 1980 level.

Other weighting systems— using bilateral trade

weights or including an alternative set of currencies--would show a

different— typically somewhat damped— path.

No single weighting system

-

3

-

is best for all purposes; it depends upon the question being asked and

the analytical framework in which the index is used.

But in the context

of stability of exchange rates, the question of how one measures

exchange rate changes is not just a technical one.

Notwithstanding this measurement question, it is clear that

the dollar rose significantly from 1980 to early 1985 and subsequently

has declined significantly.

who bemoaned its rise.

As the dollar was rising, there were those

In the United States, a wide range of firms and

individuals— including those who produce manufactured goods,

agricultural goods, and even services— decried the loss of

competitiveness associated with its rise.

Abroad, some noted the

inflationary consequences of the associated decline in their own

currenci es.

So far, complaints about the decline in the dollar's value

have been more muted, though certainly not nonexistent.

Not

surprisingly, it is now exporters in other countries who have voiced

concern.

In the United States, some have expressed concern about the

deleterious effect of a decline in the dollar on the willingness of

- 4 foreign investors to purchase U.S. debt, especially at a time when the

U.S. federal budget deficit remains high.

What's going on here is clear.

Changes in exchange rates

involve changes in relative prices, at least in the short run, and

involve substantial distributional effects.

Those who readily accept

the benefits derived from an exchange rate change in one direction do

not happily give up those gains when the exchange rate move is reversed.

To use an example appropriate to a luncheon address, those who got

accustomed to dining in Paris at 9 or 10 francs to the dollar do not

digest their food quite as easily at less than 7 francs to the dollar;

they forget that not so long ago they managed to enjoy Paris at 4 francs

to the dollar.
In short, one senses a yearning for stability, in exchange

markets as elsewhere.

As a general principle, I share that yearning,

would welcome a world in which, even in a regime of freely floating

exchange rates, conditons were such that exchange rates in fact moved

relatively little.

In a world in which the mix of monetary arid fiscal

policies within each country and the mix of policies across countries

- 5 were well harmonized, and in which major shocks were rare, we would

presumably not have to worry much about the nature of the exchange rate

regime.

A floating rate regime would approximate a fixed rate regime.

It will come as no surprise, I'm sure, when I assert that we

do not live in such a world.

Obviously, economic conditions in the

industrial world over the last several years have not provided an ideal

environment for stable exchange rates.

What are the conditions I have in mind?

Let me begin with the

tax changes in the United States in the early 1980s, which I believe had

a profoundly favorable impact on this country.

They stimulated

productive activity, investment, and demand in general; they provided

the basis for a strong and prolonged recovery from the trough of the

recession in 1982.

Unfortunately, the cuts in federal government outlays that

should have accompanied the tax changes were not agreed to.

Stalemate

on the spending front and revenue losses from the recession caused the

federal budget deficit to rise dramatically.

In the face of the strong

and credible anti-inflation posture of the Federal Reserve and the tax

- 6 incentives that had been created, the United States was such an

attractive place to invest— not just for U.S. investors but also for

investors abroad— that we were able to attract savings from abroad in

great volume.

As a consequence, interest rates were lower than they

otherwise would have been, and the burden of the deficit on traditional

interest-sensitive sectors was mitigated.

In the process, however, as

the exchange rate for the dollar was bid up and then the trade and

current account deficits widened or expanded, sectors of the economy

that were sensitive to competition from abroad began to be disadvantaged.

The beneficial effects of the rise in the dollar on inflation in the

U.S. economy as a whole were not perceived as benefits by those

competing with producers whose prices were falling.

The economic dynamics of this process have generated a

political dynamic.

Those who have not shared in the overall expansion

of the U.S. economy over the past few years--farmers, other exporters,

and those who must compete with imports— have raised their political

voices.

Pressures for protection from imports and for help of one kind

or another for exports have intensified.

They are likely to remain

-

7

-

strong at least until we can point to a significant and sustained

decline in the U.S. trade deficit.

It was the realization that the

trade deficit could not be sustained at the levels being reached late

last year— could not be sustained in a political as well as an economic

sense— that motivated the Plaza announcement, at least from the U.S.

perspective.

I expect that the decline in the dollar that we have

experienced eventually will reduce our trade and current account

deficits, but the lags are long— perhaps even longer than some analysts

had envisioned.

Moreover, we must bear in mind that, as long as the

underlying fiscal imbalance in the U.S. economy persists, the capital

inflow that is the counterpart to the current account deficit helps to

relieve potential strains in U.S. financial markets; a reduction in the

current account deficit would simply mean that the burden would fall

elsewhere.

This ponts to the urgent need to cut public spending to

reduce the federal budget deficit.

I am hopeful that progress will be

made in that direction and that better balance in the U.S. economy will

be restored; but we are not there yet.

- 8 Imbalance within the U.S. economy, with its associated

economic and political dynamics, is not the only factor causing pressure

in exchange markets.

Coordination of policies among the United States

and the other major industrial countries is not complete, either.

Underutilization of resources and declining price levels in many

industrial countries plus a profound and urgent need to achieve a

sustained increase in real income in developing countries point to the

desirability of a more vigorous world economy.

To accomplish this and,

at the same time, to redress the external imbalances among industrial

countries, domestic demand must grow more strongly in the major surplus

countries relative

to the United States.

Frankly, I am not confident this is happening.

The magnitude

of the reported rebound in German economic growth in the second quarter

is heartening in this respect, but sustained growth even in that country

is not yet assured, and growth appears to be slower in most other

European countries.

In Japan, prospects seem to be less favorable.

While GNP rose in the second quarter, following the first quarter

decline, the rebound was less strong than in Germany, and there is not

-

9

-

convincing evidence to date that the reduced impetus from the Japanese

export sector is being offset by increasing activity in the rest of the

economy.

In the final analysis, it is up to German and Japanese

authorities alone to judge whether it is necessary to implement

additional monetary or fiscal policy actions to ensure satisfactory

growth over the medium term.

I am not raising this issue here in order

to urge particular actions, although I admit that a great deal is riding

on their ability to attain and sustain greater domestic growth. Rather,

I am raising the issue to highlight the difficulties that must be

resolved if we are to achieve full international coordination of

policies, which is essential to exchange rate stability no matter what

the regime.
Consider, for example, the context in which the Federal

Reserve has operated this year.

The slowing of growth in the United

States, along with much more favorable inflation experience and

prospects, suggested that some easing was appropriate and that

reductions in the discount rate were called for.

It was recognized that

-lOin the absence of complementary actions in other countries, such actions

by the Federal Reserve might well entail a decline in the exchange value

of the dollar.

Nevertheless, the Federal Reserve Board decided that

cuts in the discount rate were appropriate given current conditions.

To put the issue simply, the Federal Reserve Board believed

that a decision by authorities in other countries to refrain from easing

policies commensurately should not, in the existing global environment,

prevent some easing of policy in the United States.

Expressed

alternatively, in the absence of full international coordination of

policies, a desire to achieve stability of exchange rates should not

override a desire to achieve the more fundamental objective of

satisfactory growth with price stability.

I recently saw a report of an interview with Pierre Languetin,

President of the Swiss National Bank.

In addressing the desirability of

a global target zone system for exchange rates, and specifically the

EMS, he said very well what I have been trying to say here.

He said:

- 11 ...There would be no need for such a system among friendly
nations in a coherent economic region if economic policies
really were convergent and compatible with each other. The
fact that this has not yet been quite achieved [in the EMS] is
proved by the realignments that have repeatedly been necessary.
The EMS has great merits.
However, by comparison the
relationship between Germany and Switzerland is ideal.
...the exchange rate between the Swiss franc and the
Deutsche mark is right. But this is the outcome of the
convergence of the two countries' monetary policies and not
the result of an exchange rate policy.
(Wirtschaftswoche,
August 1, 1986)

By way of concluding, I will confess that I would prefer to

see exchange rates stabilize as a result of coordinated domestic policy

actions that maximized noninflationary growth across countries.

I do

recognize, however, that this view may not be realistic, at least in the

near term, due to structural rigidities and political pressures that are

difficult to change.

Thus, perhaps some approach that serves to induce

policy covergence may be appropriate.

But our fundamental objective

ought to be to redress the imbalances in domestic and world economies.