View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

The Two-Handed Role of Money

Ninth Annual Homer Jones Memorial Lecture
by
Lawrence B. Lindsey

Washington University
St. Louis, Missouri
April 20, 1995

The Two-Handed Role of Money

Thank you.

It is my pleasure to be here today at Washington

University to deliver the 1995 Homer Jones Lecture.

My chosen

subject, "The Two-Handed Role of Money" is, I believe, fitting to
the occasion.
First, it is a fitting tribute to Homer Jones.

As you know,

it was he who developed the reputation of the St. Louis Federal
Reserve Bank as a leader in monetary research and statistics.

As

my talk this afternoon shall indicate, there are probably very
good reasons, based on the two-handed role of money, why the
monetarist research role in the Federal Reserve system developed
here in St. Louis rather than in Washington, D.C.
Jones was willing to take on the conventional wisdom.

There

were times when monetarism was a pretty lonely philosophy to
hold, both in the System, and in the economics profession more
generally.

In a tribute to Jones, former student Milton Friedman

noted Jones' faith that it was "repeated exposure to the facts
that erode illusion".

As I shall hope to show today, it is

illusions about the supposed role of money that are being sorely
tested, and hopefully eroded, by the facts now buffeting our
profession from a fast-changing "real world".
Second, my selection as a topic of the two-handed role of
money is a tribute to this state's most prominent politician.
Harry Truman is renowned for saying that he longed for a onehanded economist.
state.

I know he came from the other side of the

And, I would never even consider saying something

negative about Truman in Kansas City.
about this.
vice.

But, Truman was wrong

Ambidexterity is a virtue among economists, not a

Economics is a study of tradeoffs, and our reliance on

two-handed analysis is nothing more than a recognition that
tradeoffs exist.
As I shall hope to demonstrate today, the economics
profession has been getting itself, not to mention its clients,
into some trouble lately by prescribing one-handed advice about
money.

When we do this we may avoid Truman's complaint, but we

end up being tagged with the charge of another President —
Richard Nixon.

Nixon alleged that economists, one-handed no

doubt, were seldom right but never in doubt.
Finally, I believe that my chosen topic is fitting because
it is in the headlines.

Of course, relevance has its risks,

particularly when one is a Governor of the Federal Reserve.

A

sudden rush to the exits in the back of the room will demonstrate
that I went too far in my talk with regard to relevance.
avoid such risks, we have evolved Fed Speak.
rules.

To

Fed Speak has two

First, whenever possible, mumble unintelligibly.

Second,

when that doesn't work or seems inappropriate, try to pack as few
thoughts as possible into as many words as possible.
But, speaking in Fed Speak would not be a fitting tribute to
Homer Jones.

I would only caution those who hang on every

syllable, or sufficiently few syllables to get a soundbite, that
the lesson of Homer Jones is that the truth is found in exploring
all of the data, not in a single bit of information.

2

Although I

will re.fer to some headlines for illustrative purposes, their use
*•

is not the story or the lesson of today's lecture.
The headlines I am speaking of are inescapable.
Hits New Lows".

"Peso Devaluation".

Monetary System".

"Dollar

"Trouble In the European

"Is the Yen Too Strong?"

On every continent,

in virtually every language, the problem of money is now a
centerpiece of popular attention.

Of course, money, or the lack

thereof, has been a topic of breakfast table conversation for
generations.

What is different now is that public concern is not

about money in a direct personal sense.

In America at least,

jobs are relatively abundant.

Inflation -- the value of money in

terms of goods and services —

is relatively tame.

Instead, the

headlines focus on only a very narrow concept of monetary value - the value of one type of money in terms of another type of
money.

That is, the foreign currency value of a given national

currency.
To the overwhelming majority of readers of newspapers or
viewers of the nightly news, the foreign currency value of the
dollar is of total irrelevance from a personal point of view.

If

last year is any indication, the vast majority of Americans —
some 86 percent —

will not travel abroad this year.

Of those

relatively few who do, the great majority will travel exclusively
to countries in which either the dollar is the effective medium
of exchange —

as in the Caribbean -- or where the dollar is

rising in its foreign exchange value -- Mexico or Canada.

Eight

million Americans will visit Europe this year, only one million

3

will visit Japan.
Even looking at the direct personal effect in its absolute
broadest sense, in which we assume individuals can see through
the price tags on their purchases and know that the exchange rate
is raising the price of imports, the effect of the dollar decline
is relatively limited.

If we assume that the dollar has dropped

10 percent on a trade-weighted basis —

and we also assume that

the full effect of the devaluation is passed on to consumers —
which we also know to be an exaggeration -- then we would expect
to find, when all of the exchange rate change had been passed
through, a one percent rise in the domestic price level.
that this is not a one percent rise in the inflation rate.

Note
For

that to occur we would need a similar currency decline and
similar price pass-throughs in each and every year.

Surely a one

time one percent rise in prices, carried out over a period of
many months, is not of sufficient personal import to the vast
majority of consumers of news to say, compete with the Simpson
trial, or something similarly relevant to our daily lives.
Or is it?
One might make the case that, to the people of this planet,
the present exchange market instability is symptomatic of much
larger shifts in both politics and economics that are having a
profound impact on the lives of hundreds of millions of people.
Roughly one sixth of Gross World Product is now traded
internationally.

That is truly an unprecedented figure.

Further, to the hundreds of millions of people in Latin America,
4

East Asia, and elsewhere, who are seeing an explosion in their
living standards, one which dwarfs the total change in the
quality of life for a hundred generations of their ancestors,
world trade and the global opening of markets is an important
part of their lives.

Instability in foreign exchange markets

potentially threatens this continued globalization of the world
economy.

So, it is important that we reflect on why this is

occurring.
My thesis today is that, throughout the world, we are in a
period of policy conflict between the two fundamental roles of a
currency, and therefore of the two fundamental objectives of
currency policy management.

Those roles, or objectives, are to

be a medium of exchange and to be a store of value.

To be

consistent, let me put the question into the two-handed world of
economics.
—

On the one hand currency should exist to facilitate

some might say to help maximize -- the exchange of goods and

services.

On the other hand, currencies should represent a

liquid store of value which people can reliably hold as an asset.
While it is not inevitable that there be a conflict between
these objectives, it does seem that the markets currently believe
that there is no single currency which is both an ideal medium of
exchange and an ideal store of value.
market instability.

The result is exchange

This is not helped by policy disagreement

within the economics profession.

Some professional economists

strongly lean to emphasizing policies which optimize a currency's
value as a medium of exchange.

Other economists are emphasizing

5

policies designed to maintain currency values.

The resulting

apparent intellectual confusion tends to make markets even less
stable.

To understand the present policy conflict, let us

consider the intellectual case on each side of the currency
issue.
Currency as a Store of Value
Maintaining a currency as a store of value is a classical
prescription of economics, indeed to some extent it was taken for
granted.

For example, Adam Smith said in The Wealth of Nations,

"In consequence of its being the measure of value, we
estimate that of all other commodities by the quantity of
money which they will exchange for...To grow rich is to get
money; and wealth and money, in short, are, in common
language, considered as in every respect synonymous."

Maintaining a currency as a store of value has both
pragmatic and philosophical bases.

The philosophical arguments

can take on a great fervor, at times approaching a religious
conviction.

Some argue, for example, that money represents a

covenant between government and people.

In this view, destroying

the value of a currency takes on a deep significance verging on
immorality with respect to government policy.

To adherents of

this view, inflation is a form of theft.
It is fashionable in some academic and policy circles to
ridicule this point of view.

To these critics, money is not a
6

moral issue but a pragmatic policy matter.

But, these supposedly

pragmatic critics may be missing an historical point which
underpins this moral judgment about inflation.
Let us recall the practice of those first inflationists -the monarchs of old.

They would circulate specie-based coins

bearing their imprimatur signifying the coin had a certain value
in the realm.

When the exigencies of the royal purse required

funds that taxation would not produce, history tells us the
monarchs would shave a bit off the edge of the coins.

A coin of

less specie value would then be circulated under the same nominal
markings.

The accumulated shavings could then be cast into new

coins giving the monarch additional spending power.
For those who think there is no moral dimension to
inflation, this historical tale poses a compelling ethical
question.

What is the difference between shaving a bit of gold

or silver off a coin and recirculating it claiming nothing has
changed and, for want of a better term, "theft"?

Of course, the

practice was not illegal because it was the sovereign who was
shaving the coins.

But to those who make the purely

philosophical case that money should be primarily a store of
value, it is the morality, not the legality, of inflation that is
being challenged.
Proponents of currency as a store of value also claim
pragmatists among their number.

Perhaps the classic pragmatic

argument, familiar to all in this room, derives from the
conditions for social welfare maximization.
7

In the case of

currency, as with other goods, social welfare is maximized when
the marginal social benefit of additional currency equals the
marginal social cost of its production.

For all intents and

purposes, the marginal social cost of currency production is
zero.

Therefore, the optimal amount of currency in circulation

occurs when individuals have as much currency as they could
possibly want.

But, for this to occur, individuals should be

indifferent between holding currency and other riskless forms of
wealth.

In turn, that would require the return to holding

currency to equal the return to holding other forms of wealth,
again adjusting for risk.

In short, the return to holding

currency should be equal to the riskless return on productive
capital.

But, that would require the value of currency to rise

over time —

i.e. for prices of goods to be falling.

Under this

line of reasoning, social welfare maximization occurs when prices
are falling at a rate equal to the riskless return on capital.
In sum, while inflation may be optimal from the point of view of
the issuer of the currency, deflation is socially optimal.
This pragmatic point of view is not without its problems.
In the real world, a transition to a deflationary economic
environment requires shifts in both the preferred level of
consumption and preferred composition of wealth which are likely
to prove inimical to the level of economic activity, at least in
the short run.

A sudden increase in the preference for cash

would be likely to cause both consumption and the prices of other
assets to fall.

Financial intermediaries are likely to endure a
8

sharp deterioration in the condition of their balance sheets as
nominal liabilities remain unchanged while the nominal values of
assets tend to fall.

In America, the prospect of deflation has a

bad historical connotation because it is most closely associated
with the Great Depression of the 19 30s.
The difficulties of a deflationary economy —
foreign exchange ramifications —
Japan.

as well as the

are best witnessed today in

Prices of real assets, most notably real estate, have

fallen precipitously, and many market participants anticipate
further increases in the real value of what the yen can purchase.
There have been clear signs of stress among financial
intermediaries.

Economic growth has been decidedly below

historic norms.

The very low prevailing level of nominal

interest rates may be belying the perceived very high real level
of these rates because of anticipations of further deflation.
Some have suggested that Japan may be in the classic Keynesian
"liquidity trap".
Indeed, the advent of highly efficient international capital
flows may be exacerbating this phenomenon.

Absent these

international markets, the so-called speculative demand for a
currency is limited to domestic wealth holders who may wish to
hold additional currency as a hedge against falling domestic
prices.

International capital markets with low transactions

costs make this potential demand global in scope.

Furthermore,

because foreign currency demand incorporates the potential for a
capital gain in terms of foreign currency values, and not just
9

appreciation against domestic goods prices, the practical limits
to speculative currency demand become much greater.
In the early 1990s, Japanese monetary policy pursued a
controlled disinflation from the bubble economy which had
categorized much of the 1980s.
appropriate course of action.
pursue without costs.

That may well have been an
But it is a difficult policy to

In effect, deflating a speculative bubble

requires a policy which emphasizes a currency as a store of
value.

This one-handed currency policy may have its

philosophical and practical advantages, but as we are now seeing,
it is not without its risks.
Currency as a Medium of Exchange
Let us then turn to the "other hand" of policy —
as a medium of exchange.
any moral claims.

currency

Proponents of this approach do not make

Their approach is purely pragmatic -- amoral

as opposed to immoral.

In this world view, the value of a

currency is like any other price.

After all a price may be

relatively high or relatively low, but it is utterly without
moral significance.

For instance, economists do not make the

claim that 89 cents for a dozen eggs is virtuous while $2 for a
pound of hamburger is sinful.
Absent any moral trappings, currency policy becomes a matter
of expediency.

More precisely it becomes a "policy variable",

one that can be used to influence economic results about which
one attaches some value —
for example.

the levels of output or employment,

It should surprise no one that this view, and not

10

the moralistic store of value perspective, is the dominant
approach favored by economic policymakers.

In a world in which

electorates hire and fire governments based on perceived economic
performance, having an extra parameter to manipulate is something
which would naturally be viewed positively.
But it should come as no surprise to economists that there
is no free lunch.

Carrying an extra degree of freedom also

entails an extra degree of responsibility.

If one frees oneself

from the moral precept that zero inflation is the "right" amount
of price change, then one has lost a moral anchor.

The policy

maker is set adrift on what constitutes the right amount of price
change.

The freedom to set an inflation rate is traded off for

the responsibility to set an inflation rate which is at least
politically acceptable.
When this is set in the foreign exchange context, other
problems with this extra degree of freedom become manifest.

Let

us, for argument sake, assume that policy makers can actually
pick a degree of inflation which is acceptable to the electorates
they serve.

Two neighboring countries which trade extensively

with one another may have electorates with different tastes for
inflation.

Over any extended period of time these inflation

rates make it impossible for the currencies of the two countries
to maintain a stable exchange rate.

Other things equal, one

would expect that over time the inflation differential between
the two countries would be reflected in the exchange rate.
This observation became recognized by the economics
11

profession and subsumed into the theory of Purchasing Power
Parity.

Two trading partners, one with a two percent annual

inflation rate and one with a five percent annual inflation rate
would, so the analysis went, produce an annual exchange rate
change in which the low inflation currency appreciated three
percent per year.
If only the world were so simple.

For example, we all know

that inflation rates are not constant but vary with the business
cycle.

Suppose market players come to recognize that the

variance of inflation is a function of the mean inflation rate.
Then, holding the high inflation currency is riskier than holding
the low inflation currency.
for this extra risk.

Markets would expect some premium

Thus, interest rates between two countries

might come to reflect not only mean inflation differentials, but
a surcharge for higher inflation variances as well.

Being a high

inflation currency therefore carries a burden which must be paid
for by the policymaking process.
One might also assume that varying inflation rates, not to
mention varying exchange rates, might have different political
constituencies within a country.

Exchange rates, which not only

reprice goods and services which are traded, but asset values as
well, will move on inflation expectations, which in turn might
depend on expectations about which political forces are or soon
will be ascendent.

This injects a random element into the

exchange rate calculation.

Countries which are perceived as

having highly variant electoral politics, or in which exchange
12

rate and inflation rate policies are perceived to vary with
electoral outcomes will have less attractive currencies, other
things equal, than countries in which exchange and inflation
policies are considered invariant to the election cycle.
Thus, the political credibility of inflation and exchange
rate policy soon becomes an important factor.

The political

economy of this development produces a feedback which exacerbates
the problem.

The economic price paid for a lack of credibility

is, in part, a real interest rate differential on government
debt.

This will, in turn, exacerbate the nation's fiscal

problems making the chances of establishing political credibility
even more remote.

The perceived likelihood for the political

process to engage in a prospective bout of inflation will
increase as the fiscal situation gets worse, raising still
further the real interest differential.
Of course, the resulting real depreciation in the national
currency should increase the exports of the nation's goods and
services.

Other things equal, this resulting improvement in the

trade picture should reverse the process of depreciation.
two factors may offset this.

But,

The first is that, to the extent

that the national debt is held by foreigners, the increased
interest payments may offset the improvement in trade.
that a recent example of this phenomenon is Canada.

I think

In 1994,

Canada ran a net export surplus of 2.3 percent of GDP.

However,

this was offset by net interest payments to foreigners of -3.8
percent of GDP.
13

A second potential offset to the improvement in net exports
may be a reduced taste for investment, particularly portfolio
investment.

This could result from an expectation that further

real depreciations are likely to occur.

Or, it could result from

the expectation that the government may, over the intermediate
term, attempt to ameliorate its fiscal problems by increased
taxes on capital.

Either phenomenon would tend to reduce capital

inflows from abroad and, particularly in the latter case, tend to
increase capital flight.
Thus, one cannot understate the long term value of antiinflationary credibility.

But, credibility, like other forms of

virtue, once lost, is very difficult, if not impossible, to
reacquire.

The drive for monetary credibility is one of the key

factors motivating the European efforts at currency integration.
It is hoped that the process of reestablishing credibility can be
facilitated by linking the fate of one's currency to the fate of
a currency which has credibility.
The Deutsche Mark has enjoyed a period of credibility
lasting for several decades.

It is also widely held that the

anti-inflation stance of the Bundesbank has broad political
support that derives from two disastrous experiences with hyperinflation earlier in this century.

In short, it is felt that the

German electorate, unlike other electorates, is more likely to
value the role of a currency as a store of value.

Indeed, to

many a foreign observer, it sounds like much of the rhetoric
coming out of Germany on the importance of price stability takes

14

on a tone that verges on the moralistic.

Interestingly, that

observation brings us full circle back to the other hand of the
proper role of a currency.
One can never know for certain the true motivations of
policymakers.

But, even if the Bundesbank actually acts with the

ultimate in amoral pragmatism and consciously pursues a policy
role which optimizes the role of the D-Mark as a medium of
exchange, the monetary policy management certainly likes to
convey the impression that proper conduct monetary policy
resembles a moral crusade.
It is to that apparently moralistic banner that other
European countries, with long and well-established histories of
monetary policy pragmatism now flock.

France, after abandoning a

disastrous experiment with one-handed medium-of-exchange
pragmatism a bit over a decade ago, now endures a macroeconomic
mix which would seem politically unbearable under the rallying
cry of Franc forte.

But other large European nations have not

demonstrated as much stoicism.

After attempting linkage to the

virtues of the D-Mark, Britain and Italy ultimately returned to
their long running post-war traditions of running their
currencies as mediums of exchange.
The currency instability in much of Europe seems to focus on
the seeming incongruity of mixing a moralistic store-of-value
policy with a policy based on pragmatic medium-of-exchange needs.
There is widespread skepticism that monetary policy can be two
handed.

Indeed, within Germany, monetary union with Europe is

15

deeply unpopular.

Many are quite suspicious that the value of

their currency can be sustained in a European-wide political
process which is decidedly two-handed.
Ambidexterity is Messy. But Inevitable
The lessons of Europe should convince us that ambidexterity
in monetary policy is a difficult thing to achieve.

Even more

important, we should recognize that it is a virtually impossible
thing to import.

Here, I would turn to the case of Mexico and an

analysis of what the Economist has called a foreign exchange
impossibility theorem.

Three policies cannot be sustained

simultaneously over the long run.

They are:

(1) An independent monetary policy
(2) A fixed exchange rate
(3) Free capital mobility
Mexico attempted to import credibility by pegging its
exchange rate to the U.S. dollar.
succeeded.

For a long while this

Indeed, this pegging, coupled with other vital

domestic reforms may have worked too well.

Mexico became a

suddenly more attractive place to invest and money flowed in,
particularly in the form of portfolio investment in Mexican
stocks and bonds.

It is now easy to forget, but as recently as

late 199 3 the Mexican central bank was intervening in the
currency market to stop the peso from rising.

For a variety of

reasons, including political uncertainties and a failure to
follow American monetary policy developments rigidly, capital
began to flow out of Mexico.

The result was ever increasing
16

stress on the peso exchange rate.
Mexico could have averted this problem through capital
controls.

But this is hardly an attractive solution.

Importation of capital into Mexico is probably key to domestic
economic development.

Furthermore, such controls are rarely

effective at actually preventing the flight of capital when
investors get scared.
Alternatively, some have suggested that Mexico could have
abandoned an independent monetary policy stance by adopting a
currency board.

This rigid conversion of foreign exchange

holdings into domestic currency probably would have successfully
pegged an exchange rate for as long as the currency board was in
force.

But, such a policy would mean that monetary policy

conditions in Mexico would be determined, in large part, by the
Federal Reserve's perceptions of the U.S. economic situation.

It

would only be by an extremely fortuitous set of circumstances
that appropriate policy for the 50 states north of the Rio Grande
would coincide with appropriate policy for the 32 states south of
that national boundary.

Furthermore, the rigid adherence to a

currency board would eliminate the possibility of the central
bank acting as a lender of last resort.

Given the situation in

the Mexican banking system, this would not be a central banking
role which should be lightly abandoned.
The third possibility would be to have a floating exchange
rate.

One can certainly understand the motivation to establish

credibility for peso monetary policy by linking the exchange
17

rates.

On the other hand, by pegging the peso to an external

value rather than an internal one, the authorities could avoid
taking appropriate domestic monetary policy measures by
intervening in the exchange markets.

This policy could work, but

only for a time.
In short, the Mexican situation, like that in Europe,
suggests to me that monetary policy credibility cannot be
imported.

It must be home grown.

It must come from a

fundamental conviction, borne out of experience, that the central
bank is going to do the right thing and that the political
process is going to support, or at least not undermine, that
policy.
In the context of the two-handedness of monetary policy
objectives, I would term "doing the right thing" as ambidexterity
with a strong preference for the right -- i.e. store of value —
hand.

I think that this characterizes the kinds of policies the

Fed has pursued for the last 14 years.

Over this period the

confidence and credibility of our monetary policy has increased
dramatically.

We are continually, with each business cycle,

reducing the underlying rate of inflation.

The underlying rate

of inflation and resultant peak of interest rates was lower in
the late 1980s than in the early 1980s, and I believe will almost
certainly be lower in this cycle than it was in the late 1980s.
Should this trend continue, I would imagine that we are within
one, or at most two, business cycles of attaining effective price
stability.

And, I believe that pursuing this policy in a

18

gradualist fashion has maintained maximum political support for
our position.
But, markets will always be skeptical judges of the long run
capacity for the political process to support the role of a
currency as a store of value.

As a result, it does seem likely

that foreign exchange market instability may be with us for some
time to come.

The two-handed nature of money and monetary policy

will see to that.

Until there is convergence on the degree of

ambidexterity in monetary policy across countries —
degree to which we favor one hand over the other —
is likely to continue.

19

and on the
instability