View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Remarks by Governor Laurence H. Meyer
The Gillis Lecture, Willamette University, Salem, Oregon
April 2, 1998

Come with Me to the FOMC
The title for my lecture today is "Come with Me to the FOMC." When I suggested this title, I
was informed by some on your faculty that, from a marketing perspective, this might be an
unwise choice. It was alleged that few potential attendees of this lecture would know what
FOMC stands for and that my audience, as a result, might turn out to be worldly, but small.
That analysis reinforced my motivation for lecturing on this topic, but I allowed the
marketing gurus to use the more boring but nevertheless still quite descriptive title, "The
Making of Monetary Policy." So let me begin this lecture with a question for the audience.
How many of you know what FOMC stands for?
My concern about the public awareness of the FOMC was heightened recently during one of
the weekly luncheons Governors host for a small group comprised of the staffs at the Board
and Treasury. A very senior member of the Treasury staff, during our luncheon conversation,
asked me if I knew what "FOMC" stood for. A strange question, I thought, coming from so
knowledgeable a person. I replied that I thought I did, but, just to be sure, what did he believe
it stood for? He replied "Fruit Of the Month Club."
So I begin my lecture by noting that FOMC, for the purpose of this lecture, stands for the
Federal Open Market Committee. This Committee, established in the Banking Act of 1935,
came into existence on March 1, 1936. It consists of the seven Governors of the Federal
Reserve Board and five presidents of the regional Federal Reserve Banks.
Before I proceed further, I have an admission to make. I borrowed the title of this lecture
from a paper written by Edward A. Wayne, President of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond, in 1951.1 Former Fed Governor Dewey Daane was chief economist at the
Richmond Fed at the time and contributed to this effort and I have had the pleasure of
hearing first hand from Dewey about the origins of this paper. At any rate, it was such a
snappy title, that I thought--marketing guru that I apparently am not--that this would be an
effective way of attracting a large audience to this lecture.
In preparing this lecture, I took advantage of the fact that Willamette University prides itself
on its commitment to the liberal arts. Willamette University, I understand from your Home
Page on the Internet, is the oldest institution of higher education in the west and its College
of Liberal Arts is both the largest and oldest college in the University. My lecture will
accordingly take advantage of the broad perspective and interests at this institution, by
blending history, economics, political science, and even a bit of mathematics with the
interplay of institutions and current events.
I will momentarily be your guide at an FOMC meeting. But, as is often the case on such

tours, you get a little historical and topical background before the main event. The FOMC is
widely recognized as the primary decision-making body with respect to monetary policy. So
I'll start with a brief discussion of the policy instruments and objectives of the Federal
Reserve and the historical evolution of the FOMC.
The Federal Reserve has a dual mandate, as embodied in the Federal Reserve Act since 1977.
Its objectives are maximum employment and price stability. To insure that these objectives
are consistent, we have interpreted maximum employment as maximum sustainable
employment, or what we generally refer to as full employment. I'll return to this issue below.
The current language governing the Federal Reserve's objectives, as well as other
requirements related to reporting and testimony before the Congress, is contained in the Full
Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978 (often referred to as the Humphrey-Hawkins
Act).
The Federal Reserve has three principal instruments of monetary policy--the discount rate,
reserve requirement ratios, and open market operations--that can be used in support of these
objectives. The discount rate is the interest rate on borrowing by depository institutions from
the Federal Reserve. Requests for changes in the discount rate are made by the Board of
Directors of the individual regional Federal Reserve Banks, subject to approval by the Board
of Governors. Depository institutions are currently required to hold 10% of their transactions
balances in reserves, either in vault cash or in reserve balances held at Federal Reserve
Banks. Changes in the required reserve ratios, within limits dictated by congressional
legislation, are made by the Board of Governors. Open market operations refer to the
purchase or sale of government securities by the Federal Reserve, with the effect of injecting
or withdrawing reserves. Decisions about open market operations are made by the FOMC.
Changes in the discount rate are, for the most part, made to keep the discount rate in
appropriate relation to other short-term interest rates. Therefore, discount rate changes can be
thought of as complementary to open market operations. Changes in reserve requirements are
rare, and not used in the routine conduct of monetary policy. The last change was in 1992. So
open market operations are the principal instrument of monetary policy. Which makes the
FOMC a very important Committee, indeed the principal decision-making body with respect
to monetary policy.
Now some historical background. The Federal Reserve Act, passed in 1913, was "virtually
devoid of policy prescriptions" and there were, in particular, no guidelines for the conduct of
open market operations.2 The role of the Federal Reserve was viewed as more passive than
active. The emphasis was on the provision of currency and reserves to meet seasonal
demands and on assisting the banking system to accommodate the needs of commerce and
business by allowing reserves and therefore loans to expand during expansions. The amount
of reserves limits the amount of loans the banking system, as a whole, can make. When
seasonal or cyclical demand for loans was high, banks could bring eligible loans to the
Federal Reserve for rediscounting, increasing the aggregate amount of reserves and hence
lending capacity for the banking system. This meant that the Federal Reserve would lend
banks reserves at a rate set by the Federal Reserve, the discount rate. Therefore the discount
rate and the discounting of eligible bank loans were the central tools of the Federal Reserve
in the early days.
The impetus for open market operations was the experience in the early 1920s when bank
rediscounting had declined to a very low level and the Federal Reserve Banks needed another

source of revenue to cover their costs of operation. The Federal Reserve, unlike most other
government bodies, does not receive an appropriation from the Congress. Instead, it earns
enough from its operations to cover its expenses and returns any surplus to the Treasury. We
credit Treasury on a weekly basis. In the absence of revenue from its rediscounting
operations, the Reserve Banks began to purchase government securities, as had been allowed
in the Federal Reserve Act.
As they came to appreciate the need for coordination of such activities, they established,
beginning in 1922, a series of committees to manage and coordinate these operations. The
committees, initially consisting of five Federal Reserve Bank Governors (the equivalent
today of Federal Reserve Bank Presidents), made recommendations about open market
operations which were then subject to the approval of the Board of Governors. However,
even if approved by the Board, the Reserve Banks were not required to carry them out. Very
messy, very cumbersome, and very unsatisfactory--though, in practice, the Reserve Banks
did, in most cases carry out the operations recommended by the committee and approved by
the Board.
After a lengthy debate, the Congress decided to establish the FOMC in its present form in
1935. The Reserve Banks were thereby required to carry out the operations as directed by the
FOMC. The Committee chose to continue the previous practice of centralizing its operations
at the Open Market Desk of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. The FOMC is a mix of
Presidential appointees--the seven Governors--and Reserve Bank presidents who are selected
by their respective Boards of Directors subject to approval by the Board. The Boards of
Directors of the Reserve Banks have nine members, six of whom are selected by the member
commercial Banks in the respective Districts and the remaining three are selected by the
Board of Governors. The FOMC is therefore a blend of a national board and regional input of
private and public interests. Its composition has been the subject of some controversy from
the very time it was created until today. The Congress concluded, at its inception, that, while
there should be input by the Reserve Banks, a majority of the Committee should consist of
the Board of Governors. I won't dwell on that controversy because the overwhelming view
has and continues to be that the FOMC in its present form has served the interests of
monetary policy and the nation well.
So come with me to the FOMC.
It is 9 am on one of eight days, usually Tuesdays, during the year when the FOMC meets.
The Federal Reserve Act mandates that there be at least 4 meetings each year and the number
of meetings has varied from 4 to 19 over the years. Since 1981, the FOMC has met 8 times
each year. Meetings generally begin at 9 am and continue until about noon to 1 pm. Twice
each year, prior to the Humphrey-Hawkins report and testimony, the FOMC meets over a
two-day period. But I am getting ahead of myself. Our first meeting will be of the one-day or
more precisely one-morning variety. The most recent such meeting was last Tuesday.
I will not be talking about the decision reached last Tuesday, though it was announced at the
end of the meeting. Committee members observe a black-out period, from the Tuesday of the
week preceding an FOMC meeting to the Friday following the meeting. During this period, it
is the practice not to talk publicly about the economic outlook or current monetary policy. So
I will be talking in general about the FOMC and not specifically about last Tuesday's
meeting.

I will never forget the first time I entered the Board room to take my place around the table.
Each member appreciates the heavy responsibility the Committee has for the economic wellbeing of the country and the importance of their personal participation in this process. I spent
my career up to this point studying and teaching macroeconomics, forecasting future
developments in the economy, and analyzing past and prospective macroeconomic policies.
Serving on the FOMC is, without question, the most important responsibility I could have for
which this career has prepared me.
As you enter the Board room, you will undoubtedly be struck by the impressive size of the
oval table--27 feet ½ inch long and 10 feet 11 inches at its widest point. Members of the
Committee and staff are milling around, greeting each other, but generally not talking much
shop at this point. Just before 9 am everyone moves to their respective chairs, just as the
chairman, Alan Greenspan, walks in to take his place at one end of the table. The Chairman,
by the way enters from a door that connects to his office, one of the perks of being Chairman.
I, on the other hand, have had to walk down the long corridor to enter through the main door
of the Board room.
To the Chairman's right is the Deputy Secretary of the FOMC. To the right of the deputy
secretary is the President of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, the Vice Chairman of
the FOMC and a permanent member of the Committee. The remaining Governors of the
Board sit in a pre-established order. Just so they don't get it wrong, their names appear on
plaques on the chairs. The Vice Chair of the Board sits to the immediate left of the Chairman.
The two most senior Governors, other than the Vice Chair, sit to her left. Then, in order of
seniority the remaining three Governors sit across the table, beginning next to the President
of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. I started out at what I refer to as the bottom of the
batting order when I arrived as a rookie in June of 1996. I have subsequently moved up to the
point where I now sit next to Bill McDonough, President of the Federal Reserve Bank of
New York, and, on my other side, the two most-junior members of the Board. The Reserve
Bank presidents then sit around the table in a prescribed order that no one can seem to
remember the logic for.
Only five of the presidents vote at a given meeting. The voting members are established at
the beginning of each year. Initially, the Banks were separated into three groups of two and
two groups of three, with one representative from each group selected by their boards of
directors. In practice, that meant a rotation of each bank, some every other year and some
every third year. But the New York Bank's position was deemed so important-- given that it
is located in the nation's and indeed the world's financial center and given the special
responsibility the Bank has come to have for the actual implementation of policy--that the
President of the New York Fed was, in practice, always selected as a voting member of the
FOMC. The unfortunate President of the Boston Fed, the other member of that two-group,
therefore, never got to vote. That was, after some experience, judged to be unfair to Boston
and the Congress amended the law in 1942 to make the New York Bank a permanent
member of the FOMC and to put the Boston Bank into one of the other groups, leaving three
three-groups and one two-group to govern rotations of the remaining eleven presidents.
Senior staff of the Board and of the New York Federal Reserve Bank sit at the far end of the
table. I will introduce them as they participate in the meeting. In addition, sitting in chairs
around the outer walls of the room are additional staff from the Board and the Reserve
Banks. Each President, except for the one from New York, is accompanied by one staff
member, usually the Bank's Director of Research. The New York delegation includes, in

addition, two officers from the Open Market Desk and the Committee's Deputy General
Council. Additional senior staff at the Board attend the meetings also. It is rare that any of
these attendees speaks at the meeting, although there are specialists in key areas that are there
in case they might be needed. Access to the FOMC meeting as well as to the material
presented to the Committee in preparation for the meeting is carefully and strictly limited.
While the discussion at the meeting will ultimately become public record, the full transcript
will not be available for five years. Minutes of the meeting, providing a thorough but brief
account of the discussion, but without indicating who said what, will become available the
Thursday following the next meeting. The information in the minutes or other aspects of the
discussion at the meeting could give advantage to those who obtained this information before
it was publicly released. Their confidentiality is therefore carefully guarded.
The Chairman calls the meeting to order and we are under way. The green light goes on in
front of the deputy secretary, indicating that the meeting is being recorded.
The first order of business is approval of the minutes of the previous meeting. The minutes
are sent to each of the FOMC members during the period between meetings and any
recommended changes are incorporated into the draft that is then circulated in advance of the
next FOMC meeting. Quite often, small changes are made in advance of the meeting. The
minutes are then almost always routinely accepted by vote at the start of the meeting.
The first substantive agenda item is a presentation by the Manager of the System Open
Market Account at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Peter Fisher. His presentation
covers developments in the domestic financial and foreign exchange markets and provides
details of open market operations and any foreign exchange rate intervention during the
period since the last FOMC meeting. I expected, until I had attended my first meeting, that
this would be a rather dull and unrewarding report. But I had not yet met Peter Fisher. This
presentation is one of the highlights of the meeting, as Peter--armed with colorful charts
which identify market moves accompanying key events in the last several weeks--reads into
the developments in the financial and foreign exchange markets the response of market
participants to the flow of data, events, and comments by members of the FOMC during the
weeks since the last meeting. He might note for example: "See that blip in the Treasury bond
yield. That was in response to Governor Meyer's speech!" Eyes momentarily turn in my
direction, before returning to Peter for his next insight. At the end of his presentation, he will
ask for votes to ratify the Desk's open market operations and foreign exchange intervention,
if any, during the period since the last meeting.
Up next is the Director of Research and Statistics at the Board, Mike Prell, who presents the
Board staff's forecast. He may share the honors with the Director of the Division of
International Finance, Ted Truman, especially when international developments are
particularly important in shaping the economic outlook, as has been the case from the onset
of the Asian crisis. The forecast has previously been circulated to members of the FOMC-typically the preceding Thursday--in a document known as the Greenbook, by virtue of the
color of its cover. Part I includes the forecast and analysis of the outlook. Part II includes a
detailed analysis of recent developments in the economy and financial markets.
The forecast is put together by a group of about 25 staff members, beginning about 10 days
before the FOMC and usually concluding the Wednesday before the meeting. It is circulated
at the Board early on Thursday and arrives at the Reserve Banks during that day. It is a
judgmental forecast, constructed with the help of a variety of equations which describe the

way various components of aggregate demand and various prices get determined. I have
written previously about how the forecast is developed at the Board. The only issues I might
note here are the questions of what the staff assumes about future monetary policy in putting
its forecast together and whose forecast it really is.
The staff appreciates that its role is not to forecast or prejudge the policy decisions of the
Committee. But how can the staff make a forecast of what is going to happen in the economy
if it does not include in that forecast a view of how monetary policy will evolve? The
compromise is, in most cases, to assume no change in policy, meaning no change in the
federal funds rate, which we will soon see is the key decision that the FOMC makes at each
meeting. The forecast thus reflects the staff's assessment of how the economy will evolve in
the absence of any change in policy today or at subsequent meetings over its forecast
horizon, which typically includes the remainder of the current year and the following year.
This can be a very effective device for making decisions about policy. The FOMC gets the
staff's view of what will happen if there is no change in policy and if they judge this outcome
both credible and unsatisfactory, they have the necessary motivation for action to change
policy. However, on those occasions where it appears clear that a constant funds rate would
be greatly at variance with the Committee's objectives, the staff will incorporate into the
forecast some judgment about the change in the funds rate over the forecast horizon.
Whose forecast is this? Is it really the staff's independent judgment, or is it the Chairman's
forecast that the staff has dutifully adopted as their own? I wondered about this myself before
joining the Board. I can only talk about my experience, though I have, as you might guess,
taken some interest in the workings and history of the FOMC, and will over time develop a
better understanding of past practice. But it is very clear today that the forecast is the staff's
independent judgment. That judgment is, to be sure, influenced, as is appropriate, by ongoing
discussions with the members of the Board and the less frequent discussions with the FOMC.
But the fact is that there are really twenty forecasts on the table, as it were, at an FOMC
meeting. Each President comes with his or her own forecast, developed by the economic staff
of that Bank. Each of the Governors comes with his or her own implicit or explicit forecast.
None of the other forecasts is put together in so much detail, by so large a staff, and represent
as many hours of careful work as that by the Board staff. Neither the Chairman nor the other
members of the Board interfere with the staff's exercise of its important responsibility to use
its best judgment to provide all the members of the FOMC with a careful forecast.
Each Monday the staff reports on the data and events of the preceding week to keep the
Board members up to date, and Board members have the opportunity to question the staff's
judgment on the interpretation of that data. On the Monday preceding FOMC meetings a
more lengthy and detailed presentation of the outlook is presented to the Board by its staff.
The presidents, of course, are briefed by their own staffs and also get copies of the briefings
presented to the Board by its staff each week.
At the conclusion of the presentation on the staff forecast, the Chairman asks if there are any
questions for the staff. Most of the questions will come from the Reserve Bank presidents
because, as I just noted, the Governors have already had the opportunity to raise questions
with the staff the previous day.
At the conclusion of the questions, we begin the first of two go-rounds, the core of the
meeting. Each member of the FOMC presents his or her own views on the outlook in the first
go-round. The current practice is that Bank presidents generally go first, because they have

information that the governors do not have--information about developments in their own
regions. The presidents, in addition to having regional information, also tend to have realtime information about consumer spending, business investment, and wage and price
developments, for example, gathered from speaking to firms in their Districts. The particular
order otherwise is not prescribed and evolves through what I refer to as the "wink system."
Each FOMC member winks at the deputy secretary when he or she wants to be put on the list
of presenters, and the Chairman calls upon the FOMC in the order on that list. The
presentations are generally about five minutes long and focus on a few key points that the
Committee member feels are of importance to the policy problem of the moment. The
presentations do not offer detailed alternative forecasts, compared to the staff, but Committee
members often seek to position themselves relative to the staff forecast--stronger or weaker
growth, higher or lower inflation, etc.
How the chairman participates in the meeting has changed over time, depending on the
preference of the incumbent. Alan Greenspan does not participate in the outlook go-round.
There is not much in the way of exchanges between members of the Committee during this
process. Each member speaks, then gives way to the next. Many speak from a prepared text
or a detailed outline, although there is a more than an occasional effort by each member to
relate his or her remarks to what has gone before. Still, the process is not one of discussion
but of a series of self-contained, only sometimes interrelated, presentations.
At the end of the outlook go-round, it's time for a coffee break. While the Committee and
staff are so occupied, I am afraid that you have additional work to do. We are about to move
to the crucial stage, the discussion of policy options, and the vote on policy. The time has
come for your economics lesson.
The outlook discussion has set the stage for the policy decision by interpreting the current
state of the economy--where we are today--and assessing where we are headed over the next
year or two in the absence of a change in policy. The role of policy is to move the economy
from where we are--and where we will be in the future in the absence of change--to some
preferred state, specifically related to the Federal Reserve's objectives of full employment
and price stability.
The policy instrument the Fed has to accomplish this is open market operations, and these
will be used to achieve a target level of the federal funds rate, the rate of interest on overnight
loans in the interbank market. These loans represent the lending and borrowing of reserves
among depository institutions. It is essentially the price associated with the borrowing of
reserves. And we all know what determines the price in any market: supply and demand. The
economy, by influencing the quantity of transactions balances, determines the demand for
reserves, and the Federal Reserve affects the supply. By judiciously influencing the supply,
the Fed can effectively control the federal funds rate. While the federal funds rate itself is not
a particularly important influence on the economy, movements in the federal funds rate (and
expectations about future federal funds rate encouraged by any change) influence the broad
spectrum of interest rates and financial asset prices in the economy. In this way, changes in
the federal funds rate exercise an important influence on the demand for goods and services,
especially those that are relatively interest-sensitive. By affecting the demand for goods and
services, open market operations can affect the level of production relative to productive
capacity and inflation pressure in the economy.

I will now very briefly lay out the key economics that we need to move from the outlook to
policy.
First, monetary policy cannot influence real variables--such as output and employment--in
the long run (except via the contribution of price stability to living standards). This is often
referred to as the principle of the neutrality of money. One of the most important disciplines
for policymakers is understanding what they can and what they cannot accomplish. The Fed,
for example, cannot raise the long-run rate of economic growth. It should not try.
Second, money growth is the principal determinant of inflation in the long run. This
immediately makes price stability (in some shape or form) the direct, unequivocal, and
singular long-term objective of monetary policy. No central bank around the world would
argue otherwise. When it comes to price stability, the buck, literally, stops at the central
bank.
Third, because prices in many markets are slow to react to changes in supply and demand,
shocks to the economy can lead to persistent departures of the economy from full
employment--in both directions. This proposition offers at least the potential for monetary
policy to play a role in smoothing out business cycles. This is the basis for what is sometimes
referred to as stabilization policy, adjusting the level of aggregate demand so that it supports
a level of production consistent with full employment.
Fourth, full employment and price stability are compatible. Indeed, we define full
employment as the maximum rate of employment that can be sustained without rising
inflation. Many of us define it specifically in terms of a threshold unemployment rate, the
rate below which inflation rises over time. This is the concept of the nonacceleratinginflation rate of unemployment, or NAIRU. This means that the two objectives of monetary
policy--full employment and price stability--are compatible in the long run.
Fifth, inflation pressures arise, in part, from departures of the economy from full
employment. If the economy moves below full employment, the resulting slack results in
disinflation, that is, downward pressure on inflation. When the economy moves above this
threshold there is continuing upward pressure on inflation. As a result, open market
operations which affect the demand for output relative to productive capacity provide the
FOMC with the ability to influence inflation pressures in the economy and move the
economy toward its price stability objective.
Fifth, short-run swings in inflation can also be driven by supply shocks, changes in prices of
particular goods that are unrelated to the overall balance of supply and demand in the
economy. An example would be a change in oil prices due, for example, to production
decisions by OPEC or weather developments. It would be difficult, for example, to
understand recent U.S. economic performance and monetary policy without an understanding
of the role of favorable supply shocks. This consideration means that monetary policymakers
must also try to decipher the sources and persistence of shocks to the economy.
The Committee is now reassembling to hear the presentation on policy options by the
Director of Monetary Affairs, currently Don Kohn, who, by the way, also serves as Secretary
of the FOMC. The policy options were detailed and circulated to the Committee in advance
in a document called the Bluebook, again to reflect the color of its cover. This typically
arrives at my house about mid-morning on the Saturday before the FOMC meeting. The

outlook discussion has set up the context for the policy decision. It has focused on where the
economy is relative to full employment, how fast the economy is growing relative to its longterm trend, and whether or not inflation pressures are building. The staff forecast has
provided one view of whether current policy is consistent with the Federal Reserve's
objectives of full employment and price stability.
Don Kohn's discussion will outline policy options, with the emphasis on the plural. He will
not recommend a particular course of action to the Committee. Rather he will offer options
and provide a coherent rationale for each of the options offered. This has not always been the
practice, however. The paper by Wayne that inspired this presentation indicates that the three
senior Board staff who make presentations at the meeting used to each make their own
specific policy recommendations and these might not always coincide. Today, it would be a
remarkable incident if there was any disagreement among the Board staff around the FOMC
and none of the staff venture their views about the appropriate course of policy.
The Bluebook might discuss as many as three options. Option A is always a decline in rates.
Option B is always no change in the target funds rate. And option C is always an increase.
Depending on the circumstances, the Bluebook may explicitly offer only two options. That
is, in cases where it appears clear that the decision will either be to hold rates constant or to
increase them, the staff will not offer an option of a decline. No matter. The FOMC is free to
make any decision it wants, whether or not the staff has identified that option. In addition, the
staff options will also indicate an amount of change--typically 25 basis points or 1/4
percentage point, but sometimes 50 basis points.
The second policy decision that will be made at the meeting is more subtle--a decision
between what is referred to as a symmetric and asymmetric posture. This involves two issues.
First, is there only a remote chance for a change in policy or a somewhat greater chance for a
change in policy in the period between this and the next meeting? A symmetric directive
implies less chance of a move during the inter-meeting period than an asymmetric directive.
Indeed, some would interpret an asymmetric directive as providing more of a license for the
Chairman to change policy during the period between meetings, while a symmetric policy is
more limiting of the Chairman's discretion. But this is nowhere written down. And, in any
case, the FOMC, at least this FOMC, will expect to be consulted--in the form of a telephone
conference call--in advance of any policy move. A second interpretation of the directive is
information on whether the next policy move is more likely to be up than down. This is like a
reminder to the Committee that a policy action might be in the offing. For most of 1997, Fed
policy was on hold, but the directive was asymmetric, indicating a greater prospect for a rise
than a decline in the funds rate. With the Asian crisis and the associated expectation of a
slowing in growth, policy turned symmetric in November. You will not know about whether
policy was symmetric or asymmetric at the meeting last Tuesday until the minutes for that
meeting are released on the Thursday following the next meeting.
After the staff presentation of policy options, the Chairman offers Committee members the
opportunity to question Don Kohn on issues related to his discussion of the policy options.
Then we are ready for the second go-round, this one on policy. The difference in this case is
that the Chairman goes first. He will lay out his view of the outlook and then bridge to his
policy prescription. This presents the link from the earlier outlook discussion to the current
policy decision and it gives the Chairman the opportunity to lead the Committee, both toward
the position he is advocating and toward a consensus. This is followed by each of the
members, in no prescribed order, but based on the "wink system," laying out views on the

policy decision, commenting on both the target funds rate and whether the posture should be
symmetric or asymmetric. When the decision is quite clear, there may be very little
discussion during this go-round with members mainly indicating their agreement with the
position recommended by the Chairman. In cases where the decision is less clear, there will
be individual presentations.
Many differing views are presented in the outlook go-round and, where circumstances justify
it, in the policy go-round. There is encouragement for each member to clearly present his or
her own perspective.
Now the critical moment is approaching, the time to vote. Here two traditions come into play.
The first is that the Chairman is always expected to be on the winning side of a policy vote.
There has not been a case within memory where the Chairman has not been on the winning
side of a policy vote at the FOMC. The Chairman is likely to have a good idea of how
Governors are leaning, even before the meeting. Board members discuss the appropriate
course of policy on occasion at their regular weekly meetings when they consider requests of
Reserve Banks for changes in the discount rate, especially on those occasions preceding
FOMC meetings. In addition, the economic and policy situation naturally comes up in
informal individual discussions between Board members. Moreover, as all the FOMC
members give their views on the economy during the first part of the meeting, the outlook
go-round, one can often infer their likely vote--though there are surprises from time to time.
A second tradition is to try to reach a consensus on the policy decision. It is quite common
for there to be differences of opinion and yet a unanimous vote. This would be the case, for
example, where the question was one of timing rather than of principle. Unanimous votes are
common. One or two dissents are not unusual, but more than two dissents at a meeting are
rare.
Because of these two traditions--that the Chairman is always on the winning side of a vote
and that the Committee strives to reach a consensus--the Chairman's presentation at the start
of the policy go-round is so important. It is the key moment, other than the vote itself at the
meeting. There is a special sense of anticipation here because the Chairman often will
provide some new data or some new insight in support of his position. Indeed, the Chairman
is the most likely of the Committee members to challenge the group with a new way of
thinking about recent developments. The Chairman presents a very forceful and clear
argument for a specific policy recommendation. The recommendation, nevertheless, might be
more decisive in the direction and size of the move than with respect to whether the posture
should be symmetric or asymmetric. The focus of the comments that follow are why
members agree, would prefer another course but can accept, or strongly disagree with the
Chairman's recommendation.
When the policy go-round has been completed, the Chairman summarizes his sense of the
consensus. For example: No change in the funds rate (option B) and a symmetric directive.
Next the directive to be voted upon is read by the deputy secretary, conforming to the
outcome of the discussion. The directive identifies the target funds rate and whether policy is
symmetric or asymmetric. The directive is in effect the instructions to the Manager of the
System Open Market Account at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. He is to conduct
open market operations during the intermeeting period so as to achieve the intended funds
rate as closely as possible. The wording of the directive was changed late last year to make it
more transparent. Previously, it instructed the Manager, for example, to tighten reserve

positions slightly, somewhat, or significantly. A "slight" increase in reserve positions was, in
fact, code for a 25 basis point increase in the funds rate; "somewhat" of an increase was code
for a 50 basis point increase; and a "significant" increase signaled a 75 basis point increase in
November of 1994. Of course, the Manager of the System Open Market Account attends the
meeting and knows the vote was explicitly for a 25, 50, or 75 basis point increase. The
revised practice is to report in the directive precisely the outcome of the vote--a 25 or 50
basis point increase or whatever. This is further progress in terms of transparency.
The directive also indicates whether there is a symmetric or asymmetric posture for policy by
the use of "woulds" and "mights" in the discussion of possible adjustments to the federal
funds rate in the period between meetings. For example, a symmetric policy would be
indicated by the wording: "In the context of the Committee's long-run objectives for price
stability and sustainable economic growth and giving careful consideration to economic,
financial and monetary developments, a slightly higher federal funds rate or a slightly lower
federal funds rate might be acceptable in the intermeeting period." The symmetry is indicated
by the use of slightly in this case with respect to both a higher and lower federal funds rate
and by the use of might with respect to both options. Sometimes, but not lately, symmetric
directives have used "would" instead of "might" to apply to both options. An asymmetric
posture, with a greater likelihood of a rise in the federal funds rate than a decline, would be
indicated by the wording: "a somewhat higher federal funds rate would and a slightly lower
federal funds rate might be acceptable in the intermeeting period." The asymmetry is
evidenced by the use of "would" in one case and "might" in the other, with the "would"
indicating the direction that is more likely; and by using "somewhat" to describe the size of
any increase and "slightly" to describe the size of any decline.
Now it's time for the deputy secretary to poll the Committee. The Chairman votes first, the
Vice Chairman second, and then other voting members vote in alphabetical order. This is the
first and only occasion when the Reserve Bank presidents are treated differently depending
on whether or not they are voting at that meeting. Up until that point, all have participated on
equal terms in the discussions. Of course, when the chairman gives his sense of the
consensus, he is assessing the consensus of Committee members only.
Finally, if there is a change in policy, it will be announced, at 2:15 pm that afternoon. The
announcement indicates the new intended federal funds rate and also provides a brief
rationale for the policy change. The Committee has delegated the wording of the
announcement to the Chairman, but he will read it to the Committee and take account of
members' suggestions. If there is no policy change, the announcement is simply, "The
meeting ended at 12 noon. There is no further announcement."
What I have covered is really the mechanics of the meeting. But there are subtle issues of
interest that I want to turn to now. One of them concerns setting the stage for subsequent
meetings and decisions. I've described the discussion as focused on whether or not to change
the federal funds rate at the current meeting. But, speaking for myself, a major part of my
presentation focuses on subsequent meetings and decisions. Decisions to change policy have
a way of evolving from one meeting to the next. The seeds are sown at one meeting and
harvested at the next. I listen intently to the input of the other Committee members, but I am
mainly gathering input into the formation of my decision for the next meeting. And, in my
presentations, I am trying to emphasize the factors I believe will shape the decision at the
next meeting. Thus the FOMC process must be thought of in this dynamic sense. One
meeting helps to shape the decision of the next meeting.

Many Committee members have probably had the same experience as I have had already on
several occasions. A friend may come up to me before a meeting and say: "I understand that
an FOMC meeting is coming up in the next couple of days. What do you think the Chairman
will do with rates?" Now there are two issues here. First, I would never, ever comment on
what my vote will be or speculate on what the Committee's vote will be or indicate what the
Chairman's position might be. So it is sometimes irritating to have anyone even ask this
question. Of course, they did not ask about my vote, only what the Chairman will do. The
second issue this raises is whether the Chairman controls the outcome to the point where no
one else on the Committee matters. While this is clearly an exaggeration, it would be just as
silly for me to respond: "What do you mean? I have one vote, just like the Chairman." This is
true, of course, technically. But the reality is that the Chairman in general and a highly
respected Chairman like the present one has a disproportionate influence on the outcome.
Many members will voice some disagreement in the go-rounds with the Chairman's view of
the outlook or policy recommendation, but many of those will vote with the Chairman in the
end. That partly reflects the importance of consensus and it partly reflects the respect
accorded the Chairman. But there is a limit to how the Chairman's influence can be extended
and a good Chairman never oversteps this boundary. A good Chairman sometimes has to
lead the FOMC by following the consensus within the Committee.
Let's take a quick look in on a two-day meeting. The two-day meetings occur in February and
July and precede the Federal Reserve's semi-annual report on monetary policy and the
Chairman's semi-annual testimony on monetary policy. To prepare for these the Board
members and Reserve Bank presidents submit their forecasts for real and nominal GDP
growth, for CPI inflation, and the unemployment rate. These are presented to the
congressional committees and incorporated into the policy report and testimony before the
Congress in terms of ranges and central tendencies which exclude the highest and lowest
forecasts. The two-day meetings take place from about 2:30 pm until about 5:30 or 6 pm on
the first day and conclude with a meeting from about 9 am until about noon or so the next
day. The meetings include a discussion of the target ranges for monetary aggregates, also to
be included in the monetary policy report and the chairman's testimony, and may also include
some other topic related to longer-run strategic policy. The Bluebook explicitly includes
longer-term, specifically five-year, forecasts and alternative scenarios to help the Committee
assess the policy requirements for achieving the Fed's long-run objective of price stability.
We will take a brief look in at a typical February meeting. It begins differently from all the
other meetings. The Chairman opens the meeting by calling for nominations for Chairman of
the FOMC for the coming year. The procedure is then to turn the meeting over to the next
most senior Board member--or the Vice Chair of the Board if there is one--for the election
process. You see, the Federal Reserve Act does not automatically make the Chairman of the
Board of Governors the Chairman of the FOMC. When the senior Board member asks for
nominations, there is typically a couple of seconds of silence. We like to make the Chairman
squirm a little, just at the thought that the Committee might have the audacity to nominate
someone else. But, that thought quickly passes, and someone nominates the Chairman, who
is then unanimously elected Chairman. Next, the Chairman, relieved of course at his close
victory, asks for nominations for Vice Chairman. Once again tradition triumphs over
opportunity and the President of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York is unanimously
elected Vice Chairman of the FOMC. Next, we elect a Manager of the Open Market Desk
and designate a Reserve Bank to carry out open market operations. Once again, there is little
suspense, as the Manager of the Open Market Desk at the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York is re-elected and the Federal Reserve Bank of New York is once again designated as the
Bank to carry out open market operations.

In addition, the Committee considers and generally re-confirms the various directives, rules,
and procedures governing its deliberations and operations in domestic markets and foreign
currencies.
Next comes the forecast and outlook go-round, as in the case of one-day meetings, though
the "chart" show is typically more elaborate at these meetings and the question and answer
period is typically longer than at the one-day meetings. At the beginning of the second day,
the meeting starts with a consideration of ranges for the monetary aggregates. Here I am late
into my talk and this is the first time I even have the opportunity to mention the money
supply! The Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978, in addition to setting full
employment and price stability as the Fed's dual mandate, requires the Fed to set ranges for
monetary and credit aggregates. Arthur Burns, the Chairman of the Board, successfully
discouraged the Congress from writing into the statute specific money and credit aggregates
for which ranges would have to be set. The Fed currently sets ranges for the growth of two
measures of the money supply--M2 and M3--and for total debt of the nonfinancial sector.
One way to understand the role of monetary aggregates in the monetary policy process is via
the famous equation of exchange. It is an identity that states that M V = P Q. M is the money
supply and V is the velocity of money, defined as the ratio of nominal GDP to the nominal
money supply, or the number of times money "turns over" in the evolution of nominal
income. If the demand for money is stable, V will not necessarily be constant, but would be
related in a reasonably predictable fashion to a small number of other economic variables,
most importantly, to the level of interest rates. For simplicity, lets assume that V is constant.
Then there will be unique relationship between the nominal money supply and nominal
income. Open market operations then can be conducted to yield a desired path of reserves
that in turn will result in an approximately equivalent growth rate for the money supply. The
growth in the money supply, in turn, will insure the same rate of growth for nominal income.
The growth of nominal income in turn is approximately equal to the sum of the growth rates
in real GDP and the inflation rate. This is your mathematics lesson for the day: the growth
rate of a product (in this case, nominal income, P times Q) is approximately equal to the sum
of the growth rates of the two components. On average, the growth in real GDP is
independent of the rate of money growth. Let's say its long-run average rate is about 2 ½%.
Then, on average, and in the long run, the rate of inflation will equal the rate of money
growth less the economy's trend rate of real GDP growth. Hence, a target for money growth
effectively imposes what we refer to as a nominal anchor for the economy (the rate of
nominal income growth) and also pins down the long-run rate of inflation. This connection
between money growth and nominal income and, in the long run, inflation, clearly identifies
a potentially important role for monetary aggregate targets, particularly in the long run when
any short-run variation in velocity may net out.
Unfortunately, velocity is not constant and, more importantly, is not always even a stable
function of the interest rate. When the demand for money is unstable, V will be unstable, the
simple relationship between money growth and nominal income will break down, and the
usefulness of money growth targets in pinning down inflation in the long run evaporates.
The velocity measure corresponding to M2 did have a reasonably stable pattern through
much of the postwar period and indeed did not exhibit a consistent trend. However, this
stability broke down early in the 1990s. Over the last three years, the velocity of M2 has
shown renewed stability, but this has also been a fairly calm period for the macroeconomy

and there remains some uncertainty about the fundamental stability of V2. As a result, M2
has not resumed an important role in the implementation of monetary policy. Nevertheless,
the Fed is required by statute to set ranges for the growth of money and credit aggregates.
The Fed has developed a practice of fulfilling this requirement that allows for a potential
long-run role for the monetary aggregates, but also reflects the diminished role of the
monetary aggregates in short-run monetary policy decision-making. The Fed sets the range,
not to reflect the policy it intends to implement over the coming year, but to correspond to
the rate of growth that would be appropriate in the long run in an environment of price
stability and normal velocity behavior.
The current M2 target range is from 1% to 5%. The width of the target range also reflects the
degree of uncertainty about money growth relative to nominal income, even under the best of
circumstances. The mid-point is 3%. If trend real GDP growth were 2 ½% for example-about a consensus estimate of the average growth rate expected over the long run--a 3% rate
of growth of nominal income would leave long-run inflation at about ½ percent for the GDP
price index, a rate of inflation just about equal to the consensus estimate of measurement bias
for that index. That is, the midpoint of the target range is about equal to true price stability.
The range for M3 is higher because, on average M3 has grown faster than M2.
Even if V2 continued its recent stability, money growth would probably not be the primary
focus of short-run monetary policy decisions. Even before the recent episode of instability of
M2, the Fed, most of the time, implemented monetary policy by setting a federal funds rate
target, even when it said it was adjusting the tightness of reserve positions! This preference
for interest rate targets reflected some ongoing concern about whether velocity was ever
stable enough to be a guide for the conduct of short-run policy decisions and also a desire on
the part of the Fed to smooth interest rates. Under a money supply target, where open market
operations are directed to a path of reserves consistent with a money growth target, interest
rates might be quite volatile on a day-to-day basis. Nevertheless, in the 1970's and early
1980's, monetary aggregates had a much more important role in the setting of monetary
policy than they do today. The FOMC, during this period, often moved the federal funds rate
directly in response to deviations of money growth from the mid-points of their target ranges.
Well, we have had a long day of policymaking. You may now know more than you ever
wanted to know about the FOMC. Some of my students felt that way about macroeconomics
at the end of one of my classes! But I doubt any one here will ever again be guilty of
confusing the FOMC with the Fruit of the Month Club!

References
Development of the Open Market Function of the Federal Reserve System, Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington D.C., 1940.
Hackley, Howard H., "Should the Federal Open Market Committee be Abolished or
Changed?" 1971.
"The Development of Open Market Powers and Policies: A Staff Memorandum," in
hearings on The Federal Reserve System After Fifty Years, before the Subcommittee on
Domestic Finance of the Committee on Banking and Currency, House of Representatives,

88 Cong. 2nd Sess. (Government Printing Office, 1964), pp 1985-2001.
Wayne, Edward A., Come with Me to the F.O.M.C., Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond,
1951.

Footnotes
1 Edward A. Wayne, Come with Me to the F.O.M.C., Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond,
1951.
2 "The Development of Open Market Powers and Policies: A Staff Memorandum," in
hearings on The Federal Reserve System After Fifty Years, before the Subcommittee on
Domestic Finance of the Committee on Banking and Currency, House of Representatives,
88 Cong. 2nd Sess. (Government Printing Office, 1964), pp 1985-2001.
Return to top
1998 Speeches
Home | News and events
Accessibility | Contact Us
Last update: April 2, 1998 10:30 PM