View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
1:15 p.m. EDT (12:15 p.m. CDT)
September 25, 2009

Longer Days, Fewer Weekends

Remarks by
Kevin Warsh
Member
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
12th Annual International Banking Conference
Co-sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago and the World Bank
Chicago, Illinois

September 25, 2009

Recent media stories and more substantial works chronicle in great detail the events of
the past couple of years.1 A pair of conclusions might be fairly drawn from these early drafts of
history. One, the financial market turmoil of the past year proved to be of significant
consequence to the economy. And two, the Federal Reserve distinguished itself from historical
analogues by taking extraordinary actions to address risks to the economy. The commentary,
however, tends to part ways as to whether the extraordinary actions undertaken were to the good
or the detriment of the U.S. economy in the long-run.
As my fellow members of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) and I stated
earlier this week, economic activity has picked up, conditions in financial markets have
improved further, and longer-term inflation expectations are stable.
Nonetheless, the second anniversary of the onset of the financial crisis--and about a year
from the darkest days of the Panic of 2008--is no time to declare victory, scarcely the moment to
hand out medals.2 I cannot help but think of the strong but weary athlete who, after a morning
swim, embarks upon a grueling cycling contest to a rising din of cheers and a smattering of
boos…only to be reminded that he is participating in a triathlon, and that he has a long run still
before him.
In my view, it is unwise to prejudge the Fed’s policy strategy--or to declare the victor or
the vanquished--by the split time, however notable it might be. We are at a critical transition
period, of still unknown duration, and we must prepare diligently for an uneven road race ahead.

1

The views expressed herein are my own and do not necessarily reflect the views of other members of the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System or of the Federal Open Market Committee. I am grateful for the valuable
assistance of Daniel Covitz, Eric Engstrom, Nellie Liang, and David Reifschneider of the Board staff who
contributed to these remarks.
2
See Kevin Warsh (2009), “The Panic of 2008,” speech delivered at the Council of Institutional Investors 2009
Spring Meeting, Washington, April 6, www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/warsh20090406a.htm.

-2If policy is not implemented with skill and force and some sense of proportionality, the success
of the overall endeavor could suffer.
Judgments made by policymakers in the current period are likely to be as consequential
as any made in the depths of the panic. That means policymakers should continue to
communicate as clearly as possible the guideposts, conditions and means by which extraordinary
monetary accommodation will be unwound, including the removal of excess bank reserves.3
It also means that policymakers should acknowledge the heightened costs of policy error.
The stakes are high, in part, because the policy accommodation that requires timely removal as
the economy rebounds is substantial. And our policy judgments will ultimately prove worthy of
the accolades, and tender the ultimate rejoinder to their critics, if we rise to meet this heightened
responsibility. I am confident we will.
The final recounting of economic history, I submit, will judge that winning the battle
against the Panic of 2008 was a necessary but insufficient condition to win the peace and ensure
a strong foundation for economic prosperity. That outcome will require that policymakers have
equal parts capability, clairvoyance and courage, perhaps the most important of which is
courage.
For those of us at the Federal Reserve, the task ahead involves longer days, but in all
likelihood, fewer weekends. While the undertaking is as challenging as any we faced in the
preceding period, it is exceptionally well suited to the Federal Reserve’s comparative advantages

3

See Ben S. Bernanke (2009), “Semiannual Monetary Policy Report to the Congress,” statement before the
Committee on Financial Services, U.S. House of Representatives, July 21,
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke20090721a.htm; and Ben S. Bernanke (2009), “The Fed’s
Exit Strategy,” Wall Street Journal, July 21,
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052970203946904574300050657897992.html.

-3of deliberation, dispassion, and a determination to make judgments based on the long-term
interests of the U.S. economy.
The Task Ahead
Economic histories in the United States and elsewhere are packed with examples in
which the monetary authorities, with the overwhelming benefit of hindsight, may have
misjudged the communication, timing or force of their exit strategies. In some cases,
policymakers may have waited too long to remove easy-money policies. In other cases,
policymakers may have acted too abruptly, normalizing policy before the economy was capable
of self-sustaining growth.
Errors of each sort are neither uncommon nor unexpected in the normal conduct of
monetary policy. During normal turns in the business cycle, the consequences of policy error to
the broad economy tend to be meaningful. Forgone output. Higher unemployment. Threats to
price stability. None of which are--or should be--acceptable to the Federal Reserve, or to the
broader body politic. And the current environment is anything but normal. There are
uncertainties regarding the trajectory of the economy recovering from a major financial crisis
and a deep recession. Equally, there are uncertainties about the performance of the monetary
transmission mechanism and the operation of the Federal Reserve’s unconventional policy tools.
A nimble, even-handed approach toward our risk-management challenges will prove necessary.
Monetary policy rules have for some time served as an alluring guide for policymakers,
particularly at transition points when guidance is especially useful. In particular, the Taylor rule
has proven to be informative in describing, if not prescribing, how a central bank might adjust its
interest rate policy instrument in response to developments in inflation and macroeconomic

-4activity.4 But, to make the outputs operational, we need reasonable conviction in the reliability
of our estimates of current resource utilization and inflation or, for some alternative rules that
have been proposed, forecasts of these model inputs.5 And it is these kinds of estimates that
appear especially uncertain during this period of economic history, emblematic of the
challenging task ahead. Policy rules and models alike tend to presume average historical
responses, incorporating typical transmission effects and normal market functioning, which may
not fairly capture the current state of play.
Nonetheless, policymakers strive to answer the following questions: How is the
economy currently performing relative to its long-run potential, and is this likely to change in the
next few months? Where is inflation now relative to its desired level, and what are the prospects
for an acceleration or deceleration in prices in the near-term? Will changes in the federal funds
rate interact with financial conditions and affect future real activity and inflation consistent with
past practice? Or have these interactions changed, with implications for both the outlook and the
conduct of policy?
It may be, for example, that potential output has fallen by virtue of the panic and its
aftermath. If the resulting economy proves less adaptive, for example, the natural rate of
unemployment may well threaten to move upward, implying tighter labor markets at higher
unemployment rates, and lower potential output. These estimates are especially difficult to
ascertain given the uncertain contour of the financial architecture and the greater-than-usual
reallocation (and risk of misallocation) of labor and capital across sectors.

4

John B. Taylor (1993), “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice.” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on
Public Policy 39, December, 195-214.
5
Athanasios Orphanides (2007), “Taylor Rules,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2007-18 (Washington:
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, January),
www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2007/200718/200718pap.pdf.

-5Of course, countervailing risks could cause a mark-up in economic potential that cannot
be dismissed: Productivity gains may turn out to be larger and more enduring than we expect,
and the remarkable resiliency of the U.S. economy could defy skeptics as it has done repeatedly
in the post-World War II era.
Data in the past couple of months show continued improvement in real economic
performance. In combination with the repair in financial markets, the outlook for gross domestic
product (GDP) in the next few quarters appears better, improving the odds of a more enduring
positive feedback loop arising from market developments and real activity.
Nonetheless, the medium-term risks to the outlook are still disquieting. Policies, broadly
defined, that purport to bring stability to the macroeconomy could risk lowering output potential
over the horizon.6 The uncertainty of the capital and labor reallocation process, a global trade
environment in transition, and a shifting regulatory environment represent downside risks. The
possibility that we fail to accurately gauge the resulting changes in economic and inflation
prospects--by virtue of the remarkable, iterative changes in private sector practices and public
policy prescriptions--is a foremost risk for policymakers. In this environment, we should
maintain considerable humility about optimal policy.
Preliminary, Provisional, Subject to Revision, Condition-Dependent Forecast
I just sought to describe the challenges in conducting monetary policy in this
environment. That should caution us to steer clear of ironclad policy prescriptions. Nonetheless,
I would hazard the view that prudent risk management suggests that policy will likely need to
begin normalization before it is obvious that it is necessary, possibly with greater force than is

6

See Kevin Warsh (2009), “Defining Deviancy,” speech delivered at the Institute of International Bankers Annual
Meeting, New York, June 16, www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/warsh20090616a.htm.

-6customary, and taking proper account of the policies being instituted by other authorities. Allow
me to elaborate on each of these three items.
First, When Will the Fed’s Extraordinary Policy Accommodation Demand Removal?
The central banker’s standard reply, to which I would associate myself here, fits the bill:
When conditions warrant. The FOMC stated on Wednesday that “economic conditions are likely
to warrant exceptionally low levels of the federal funds rate for an extended period.” Although it
just might be a central banker’s rationalized excuse for not knowing, I genuinely believe that
more precise timing is unknowable.
In my view, if policymakers insist on waiting until the level of real activity has plainly
and substantially returned to normal--and the economy has returned to self-sustaining trend
growth--they will almost certainly have waited too long. A complication is the large volume of
banking system reserves created by the nontraditional policy responses. There is a risk, of much
debated magnitude, that the unusually high level of reserves, along with substantial liquid assets
of the banking system, could fuel an unanticipated, excessive surge in lending. Predicting the
conversion of excess reserves into credit is more difficult to judge due to the changes in the
credit channel.7
Financial market developments bear especially careful watching. They may impart a
more forward-looking sign of growth and inflation prospects than arithmetic readings of
stimulus-induced GDP or lagged composite readings of inflation.
The rapid, global revaluation of asset prices--in both directions--has served as a hallmark
of the past two years. Monitoring this trend, and gauging its durability, will demand keen

7

See Kevin Warsh (2008), “The Promise and Peril of the New Financial Architecture,” speech delivered at the
Money Marketeers of New York University, New York, November 6,
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/warsh20081106a.htm.

-7judgment. If asset prices find a new and enduring equilibrium, market participants and
policymakers alike may well gain additional comfort that the real economy is poised for
sustainable recovery. However, if asset prices retrace their recent gains, the real economy would
be adversely affected.
Understanding risk premiums embedded in asset prices will be critical to this task. In
general, risk premiums across asset classes fell significantly in the past six months, but remain
elevated, roughly consistent with prior recession periods. Some portion of the decline in
premiums and the concomitant run-up in equity prices, for example, can be fairly ascribed to the
abatement of tail risk that became apparent during the panic. Option prices across broad equity
market indexes show a substantial markdown in the likelihood of a substantial market correction.
But, the broad and continued ascent in equities appears increasingly to reflect a new
judgment about the modal outcome for economic growth and corporate earnings. If it turns out
that equity risk premiums continue their recent trajectory, real economic performance would be
bolstered further by sturdier household, business and financial firm balance sheets.
It is not just the trend or level of asset prices that should inform policymakers.
Correlations of asset prices across markets also provide important insights. In times of panic,
historic correlations break down and commonality predominates. Those firms and individuals
with purportedly “well-diversified portfolios” going into the panic bore painful witness to this
truth. During extreme conditions, sharp swings in investor sentiment often dominate changes in
relative valuations and, for a time, limit the degree to which financial markets effectively allocate
credit.
This breakdown in historic correlations is not unique to the onset of panics. It may
predominate when panic conditions are in retreat. For instance, in the past couple of months,

-8U.S. stock market indexes and corporate bond prices both moved meaningfully higher, while
Treasury yields and the foreign exchange value of the dollar fell. These movements are difficult
to reconcile with historical experience or by ascribing them to changes in the modal growth path
for the economy. Rather, this odd constellation of movements in asset prices may indicate
changes in investor preferences and in the distributions of outlooks for inflation and growth. It
would be more reassuring to growth and inflation prospects in the coming months if asset prices
were to signal a clearer, more reliable message.
Second, How Might the Policy Response Evolve?
Many of the programs created during the panic were designed to atrophy--due to their
changing relative attractiveness in price and other terms--as market conditions improved. This
natural unwinding has proven largely successful. As a result, the Federal Reserve’s balance
sheet composition has changed in recent months, even while the overall balance sheet size has
remained relatively constant.
Several of the Fed’s non-traditional programs to provide monetary stimulus were
established under section 13(3) of the Federal Reserve Act, the Fed’s governing statute. The
Congress authorized the Federal Reserve to lend to non-depository institutions, as the programs
do, only under “unusual and exigent circumstances.” The judgment that the 13(3) standard is no
longer satisfied would cause an unwinding of nontraditional policy tools by the Fed, and presage
a normalization of policy.8
Ultimately, when the decision is made to remove policy accommodation further, prudent
risk management may prescribe that it be accomplished with greater swiftness than is modern
central bank custom. The Federal Reserve acted preemptively in providing monetary stimulus,
8

This standard represents a prudent framework from which responsibility is delegated to the central bank. The grant of authority
from the Congress is standards-based with clear limits and bounds. It might serve as a useful model worthy of broader
application in the ongoing debate about regulatory reform.

-9especially in early 2008 when the economy appeared on an uneven, uncertain trajectory. If the
economy were to turn up smartly and durably, policy might need to be unwound with the resolve
equal to that in the accommodation phase. That is, the speed and force of the action ahead may
bear some corresponding symmetry to the path that preceded it. Of course, if the economy
remains mired in weak economic conditions, and inflation and inflation expectation measures are
firmly anchored, then policy could remain highly accommodative.
“Whatever it takes” is said by some to be the maxim that marked the battle of the last
year. But, it cannot be an asymmetric mantra, trotted out only during times of deep economic
and financial distress, and discarded when the cycle turns. If “whatever it takes” was appropriate
to arrest the panic, the refrain might turn out to be equally necessary at a stage during the
recovery to ensure the Fed’s institutional credibility. The asymmetric application of policy
ultimately could cause the innovative policy approaches introduced in the past couple of years to
lose their standing as valuable additions in the arsenal of central bankers.
Third, How Might U.S. Monetary Policy Be Affected by Other Macroeconomic Policies?
Monetary policy is not conducted in a vacuum. The Federal Reserve, and other monetary
policymakers, will be keen observers to the judgments made by the fiscal authorities around the
world. Central bankers will necessarily take account of these judgments.
Financial markets’ affection for decoupling--that is the disassociation of U.S. economic
prospects from the rest of the world--tends to wax and wane. My own views on the subject are
less ephemeral. Our prospects for economic growth are highly correlated with the prospects of
our large trading partners. And if fiscal, regulatory and trade policies diverge or deteriorate,
economic prospects globally could suffer. But if the better path prevails--that born of the past
couple of generations of economic dynamism, positive-sum trade flows, fiscal sustainability and

- 10 regulatory best practices--we will emerge from this crisis with a stronger, more integrated global
economy and more resilient financial markets.
Monetary policy convergence has proven remarkable, and remarkably constructive,
throughout the crisis. When the removal of accommodation begins in earnest, we should be alert
to see if this trend continues.