View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
1:00 p.m. EDT
May 21, 2008

The Federal Funds Rate in Extraordinary Times
Remarks by
Kevin Warsh
Member
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Exchequer Club
Washington, D.C.

May 21, 2008

This may be the most pronounced time of testing for central banks in a
generation. 1 Let me recount just a few of our challenges: significant market turmoil,
unsatisfactory economic growth, historic housing price declines, dramatic commodity
price run-ups, risk of a secular reversal of global inflation trends, sharp changes in
exchange rates, uneven and unprecedented contours of economic growth—and policy
responses—across major trading partners, and significant domestic debate regarding
optimal economic and regulatory policies. Mind you, my intention is not to declare, oh,
woe is us.
Thanks in no small measure to the scores of professionals long found in the four
walls of the Federal Reserve System—and ample access to information—the Fed possesses
both the commitment and resources to tackle these policy challenges. And, by virtue of
the Fed's institutional credibility, bequeathed to today's Federal Open Market Committee
by its predecessors, the policy response tends to be as highly anticipated as it is
consequential. But in affirming our formidable assets, it is similarly not my intention to
suggest that we have devised error-free policies to painlessly and smoothly achieve
agreed-upon objectives.
On Monetary Policy...Today
The Fed is not omniscient. Neither are our tools uniquely and perfectly suited to
ensure that the ills of yesterday do not recur. Nor can we guarantee that our policy
response alone will set the economy on a steady and obvious path to unequalled
prosperity. We run serious risks if we overstate our knowledge or overplay our hand.
Look no further than the financial wizards in the financial sector recently who were
1
The opinions I am expressing are my own and do not necessarily correspond with those of my colleagues
on the Board of Governors or the Federal Open Market Committee. Nellie Liang and Dave Reifschneider,
of the Federal Reserve Board's staff, provided valuable contributions to these remarks.

- 2 -

convinced that risks were manageable and returns exponential. Milton Friedman
reminded us long ago, and Edmund Phelps more recently, of the "consequences of
conceit."2 For all that has been learned about the practice of monetary policy, we must
be mindful of the dangers of purporting to know more than we do about the relationship
between central bank policies and the real economy. Humility, thus, is a particularly
important attribute for a central banker, particularly when financial markets and financial
intermediaries—through which the effects of monetary policy flow to the real economyfind themselves at a crossroads.
Starting in August, my fellow Fed policymakers and I persistently subjected
ourselves to the age-old dialectic in determining the breadth and depth of our policy
response: What do we know? What do we think we know—that is, what do we suspect?
What can't we know? And, perhaps most important, in light of various forms of
uncertainty: What should we do about it?
The more we asked ourselves these questions during this period of extraordinary
tumult, the more we recognized the need to broaden our policy response beyond
monetary policy's blunt traditional tool. Changes in the policy rate affect many sectors,
not just those that seem out of balance. Charlie Munger, the under-heralded partner of
the "Oracle of Omaha," Warren Buffett (perhaps comprising the finest investment team
of the last half-century), believes that economics remains a rather insular field of practice.
He seems to delight in accusing the economics profession of suffering from "Man with a
Hammer Syndrome." He recounts, "[T]o the man with only a hammer, every problem

2

Milton Friedman (1968), "The Role of Monetary Policy," American Economic Review, vol. 58 (March),
pp. 1-17; Edmund S. Phelps (2008), "Our Uncertain Economy," Wall Street Journal, March 14.

-3 looks pretty much like a nail." 3 I suspect Munger feels similarly about the orthodoxy of
monetary policy.
Consistent with Munger's admonition, the Fed saw it necessary to expand our
toolkit beyond the proverbial hammer of the policy rate in the last nine months. And as I
discussed in remarks last month, the Fed's nontraditional policy response included the
use of innovative liquidity tools to counter the market turmoil and improve the
functioning of financial and credit markets. 4
In my remarks today, I would like to discuss the use of the hammer—the setting of
the federal funds rate—particularly in extraordinary times. Of course, determining the
proper level of the federal funds rate is rarely simple, given typical imprecision on key
economic variables and relationships. It is far more challenging still when the financial
architecture is in the early stages of redesign, the economy is adjusting to the aftermath of
a credit bubble (witnessed most acutely in the housing markets), and inflation risks are
evident.
The Federal Reserve has employed the hammer with considerable force in the last
nine months, lowering the federal funds rate by 3-1/4 percentage points, with wideranging implications for the economy. Of substantial import, we have filled the toolkit
with other implements to provide liquidity and improve the provisioning of credit during
the turmoil. But now, policymakers may be well served encouraging a new financial
architecture to emerge, aided, in part, by the actions we have taken. Even if the economy

3

Charles T. Munger (2003), "Academic Economics: Strengths and Faults After Considering
Interdisciplinary Needs," Herb Kay Undergraduate Lecture delivered at the Economics Department,
University of California, Santa Barbara, October 3.
4
Kevin Warsh (2008), "Financial Market Turmoil and the Federal Reserve: The Plot Thickens," speech
delivered at the New York University School of Law Global Economic Policy Forum, New York, April 14,
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/warsh20080414a.htm.

- 4 -

were to weaken somewhat further, we should be inclined to resist expected, reflexive
calls to trot out the hammer again.
Policy actions should reinforce the notion with stakeholders that further
hammering needs to be done, but it needs to be accomplished by the financial institutions
themselves in retooling their businesses and rebuilding the credit channel to help ensure a
stronger, more durable economy. Private financial institutions should raise substantial
capital, reconstitute business models, and take other actions to reinvigorate the principal
transmission channel of monetary policy. These private efforts are critical to improving
market functioning, and until this process is more advanced, the economy is unlikely, in
my view, to return to sustainable trend-rate growth. We at the Fed have taken action to
help foster this curative process to improve the real economy, but market participants will
ultimately determine its speed and success.
On Monetary Policy...Generally
The Fed is charged with promoting price stability and maximum sustainable
employment. Stakeholders advocate various strategies for achieving these objectives. In
recent years, most central banks have elected to adjust the policy rate in response to
changing economic conditions to achieve their goals. A key question for central bankers
under this approach: What level of the policy rate would bring real activity in line with
its potential? In gauging this value, a central banker seeks to be forward-looking because
monetary policy influences real activity with considerable lag. The same consideration
applies to assessing the effect of policy actions on inflation.
For analytical purposes only, let's assume that we are in a world where inflation is
running well within acceptable levels and that the central bank and stakeholders have

- 5

-

ultimate conviction it will remain as such. This, of course, smacks of the old joke about
economists and can-openers. 5 I'll revisit this heroic assumption later in my remarks. But
with the assumption in mind, monetary policy can focus on the real side of the economy.
The Taylor rule provides a convenient rule-of-thumb for setting monetary policy. 6
The rule posits that the appropriate setting of the real federal funds rate incorporates three
components. The first component is the economy's natural rate of interest. This is the
real federal funds rate consistent with output equal to potential, on average, over the
medium- to long-run. If policymakers set the real federal funds rate at this level, the Fed
would be neither artificially boosting nor restricting the real economy over long periods.
Holding the federal funds rate at the natural rate, however, may yield an undesirably slow
return of real activity to normal, particularly if shocks have a persistent effect on
aggregate demand and supply.
To expedite the process, the Taylor rule adds a second component to the real
federal funds rate, one that purports to be proportional to the size of the current output
gap. By setting the real federal funds rate below the natural rate when resource
utilization is loose—and, correspondingly, above the natural rate when resource utilization
is tight—policy purports to help move the real economy back to normal at a speedier pace.

5

A physicist, a chemist, and an economist are shipwrecked on a desert island. Starving, they find a case of
canned vegetables washed up on the beach, but they cannot locate a can opener. They consider possible
solutions. The physicist says: "I've got it. We find a rock and propel it at the lid of the can at, oh, 40
meters per second at an angle of 82 degrees." The chemist thinks for awhile and responds: "No, let's
weaken the can's seams with an acid made from decaying leaves, and then heat the can until the internal
pressure is enough to burst it open." The economist merely shakes his head at his compatriots and says in a
condescending tone: "Gentlemen, gentlemen, I have a much more elegant solution. Let's assume we have
a can-opener..."
6
John Taylor, professor and confidante, originally presented the construct for what later became known as
the Taylor rule at a Carnegie-Rochester conference in the early 1990s; see John B. Taylor (1993),
"Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice," Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol.
39, pp. 195-214, http://econpapers.repec.org/article/eeecrcspp.

- 6 -

The third component responds to the gap between actual inflation and its desired rate,
pushing real rates up when inflation is too high and pushing rates down when inflation is
too low.
The Taylor rule provides a reasonable description of actual monetary policy
behavior on average over the past 20 years. The reasonably good macroeconomic
performance of this period suggests that central banks should pay some heed to its
prescriptions. By design, however, the Taylor rule focuses largely on what can be
observed in real-time, without accounting for some factors that influence monetary
policy. For example, policymakers may try to peer, however imperfectly, into the future
when setting the federal funds rate rather than responding solely to the current state of the
economy. Some central bankers find this more forward-looking approach to be
particularly appealing when financial market prices and other high-frequency indicators
suggest that the economy is poised to change direction markedly.
To implement a forward-looking strategy, a policymaker could seek to forecast
the average level of the real federal funds rate consistent with the economy either
approximating or expeditiously returning to potential. Such a neutral rate thus might
equilibrate the real economy over the next two or three years. Then, in our hypothetical
example where inflation is stable at desired levels, the neutral rate would be a sufficient
guide for monetary policy.

7

n

The real funds rate prescribed by the Taylor rule also would not depend on inflation, obviously, if inflation
were at its desired level. This does not mean, however, that a Taylor rule policy would replicate the neutral
rate. While the neutral rate depends in part on current resource utilization, it also depends on all of the
other factors influencing the trajectory for the real economy. Thus, the two approaches can sometimes
suggest quite different policies, even if inflation is not an issue. That said, both the Taylor rule and the
forward-looking strategy will tend to prescribe similar movements in the real funds rate over the course of
the business cycle.

- 7 -

The wisdom of emphasizing a forward-looking strategy over the Taylor rule
approach may depend in part on policymakers' forecasting acumen. To estimate the
neutral rate, central bankers must forecast how the forces affecting aggregate demand and
supply will reconcile during the forecast period. Moreover, policymakers must project
how changes in the federal funds rate—past and anticipated—will interact with asset
prices, credit provision, and real-side variables. Under the best of circumstances, these
forecasts are subject to meaningful uncertainty. Thus, peering into the future and acting
on what we think we see will invariably lead to some mistakes, certainly with the benefit
of hindsight. Ignoring the future altogether, however, hardly seems the wisest course.
Moreover, the Taylor rule approach does not remove uncertainty. Consider the
natural rate of interest, a key element in the rule. This rate depends on many thingsworldwide saving and investment propensities, the achievable trend growth rate of the
economy, the natural rate of unemployment, and the state of financial markets and
financial intermediation. Some of these factors may be measurable; others can only be
estimated indirectly. And many of these estimates demand a judgment about the path of
non-monetary policy factors that will almost assuredly change over time. Moreover,
policymakers need to grapple with uncertainty from error in real-time estimates of real
gross domestic product and estimates of potential output.
The key for policymakers, of course, is to recognize these uncertainties that, if
misunderstood or miscalculated, could lead to policy errors. Munger, the proud noneconomist, recounts another lesson born of his investment career that I find particularly
heartening in considering the calculation of the neutral rate: Avoid the error of false

- 8 -

precision. 8 Most monetary policy frameworks, while fiercely debated in the academy,
tend to suffer from a common and unavoidable weakness—relying on provisional
estimates in a complex and uncertain world. This weakness argues in favor of being
persistently inquisitive in search of a keener understanding of the economy. This
consideration applies to the making of monetary policy in normal times; in times of
turmoil, the case for humility is stronger.
On Monetary Policy...in Times of Financial Market Turmoil
The Fed sets monetary policy to support the real economy through several
important channels. In times of financial market turmoil, policymakers like me are
especially focused on disruptions in the so-called credit channel. After all, much of the
Fed's policy prescriptions are carried out through financial intermediaries—commercial
banks, investment banks, others—to affect the real economy.
When the economy is operating below-trend, so long as financial markets are
functioning well, a lower federal funds rate can encourage lending by financial
institutions to bolster the real economy. 9 Hence, the Fed typically establishes the federal
funds rate in anticipation of a customary market response, returning output to potential
within a reasonable period, as well as to achieve its price objectives. In normal times,
then, the neutral rate is equivalent to the real federal funds rate that incorporates typical
transmission effects and normal market functioning. Thus, subject to the qualifications I
raised in the prior section, changes in the federal funds rate have a reasonably wellunderstood impact on the real economy, at least most of the time.

8

See Munger (2003) in footnote 3.
This is due in part to an increase in the value of financial institution balance sheets and collateral that can
be pledged to back loans.
9

- 9 -

What about the role of the federal funds rate when the real economy is performing
smartly but financial markets are functioning with exceptionally low volatility, and
liquidity and credit spreads are extremely narrow? In these periods, the relationship
between the federal funds rate and real activity is more difficult to decipher. If abundant
credit availability is perpetuated by investor overconfidence, I would submit,
policymakers may need to target a higher federal funds rate than otherwise to help the
economy attain a sustainable equilibrium. That is, a federal funds rate that is satisfactory
in times of normal market functioning may turn out be lower than required to ensure that
the economy performs at potential through the horizon. Making that judgment represents
an important, but difficult task for policymakers.
And how about when the real economy is operating below-trend in large part
because financial markets are impaired, many financial intermediaries are
undercapitalized, and risk and liquidity premiums are large and especially volatile? What
happens when banks and other financial institutions that stand between the Fed and the
real economy restrict the supply of credit beyond that implied by higher premiums or,
potentially, economic fundamentals? Should markedly higher doses of monetary
medicine (read: lower rates) be proffered to compensate fully for the reduced efficacy of
the transmission channels?
Financial turmoil lowers real activity expected to accompany a given level of the
federal funds rate. Such a development is equivalent to a fall in the neutral rate. But
policymakers should recognize that financial market turmoil is not a garden-variety shock
to output. It is different than, say, a demand shock caused by a change in exports.
Financial market turmoil can lower output growth and limit the efficacy of the

- 10-

transmission mechanism concurrently. The federal funds rate, I maintain, will generally
need to be lowered, and by more than in normal circumstances, to achieve an operative
monetary policy rate that helps to restore the economy expeditiously to equilibrium. But
policymakers need to think carefully about two issues: the degree of reduction in the
federal funds rate and the pace at which the rate returns to normal. The prudence of these
moves in the funds rate may ultimately depend on one's diagnosis of what ails the real
economy, the risk to that diagnosis, expected benefits of changes in wealth and the cost
of capital to businesses and households, and the effect of a lower federal funds rate on the
sum of credit availability to the real economy. Of no less importance, it may depend on
policymakers' judgment on tradeoffs with other critical policy objectives. More on that
to come.
The differing nature of these infrequent episodes of financial turmoil makes it
difficult to place great confidence in available econometric evidence. Almost by
definition, there are few historical precedents that might usefully guide forecasts of
aggregate demand and supply. My favorite saw of this period has it about right: If you
have seen one financial crisis, you have seen one financial crisis. So, by necessity,
policymakers must make judgments about how the crisis will unfold. Economics, and the
conduct of monetary policy, after all, is not physics.10 At least it isn't yet. Still, a strong
case for a forward-looking approach to monetary policy in these episodes seems
compelling. Waiting for the effects of the turmoil to reveal themselves in spending and
production data before policy action, as in an unadjusted Taylor rule approach, could risk
prolonged weakness.

10

Kevin Warsh (2007), "The End of History?" speech delivered at the New York Association for Business
Economics, New York, November 7, www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/warsh20071107a.htm.

- 1 1

-

On Monetary Policy...in Times of Inflation Risks
Up to this point, I focused almost exclusively on the conduct of monetary policy
in a non-inflationary environment. But we cannot assume inflation concerns away.
Determining appropriate policy necessarily involves more than figuring out the neutral
real federal funds rate. This reality is especially obvious at present. Inflation has been
elevated for some time and prices of commodities are surging. I find these trends
particularly vexing at a time when global demand growth, most likely, has slowed.
Concerns about price stability and concerns about the real economy may conflict
with one another in the short run. These short-run tensions arise, for example, if shocks
to energy prices hit the economy, boosting overall inflation while simultaneously
weakening output and employment. In the medium and long run, the Fed's dual
objectives are not in conflict. Investment, productivity, and real economic growth fare
best in an environment of low and stable inflation. Central banks that ignore this lesson
invariably pay a substantial cost, both economic and reputational.
My ode to humility would not be complete without acknowledging our imperfect
understanding of the mooring of inflation expectations. Survey measures suggest that
long-run inflation expectations have remained quite stable since the mid-1990s. This
stability is due, in substantial measure, to our predecessors' success in bringing inflation
under control after the 1970s. We cannot be certain, however, about the durability of this
legacy. If a central bank enjoys a high degree of credibility with its stakeholders, the
anchoring of inflation expectations gives policymakers some scope for supporting real
activity in the face of adverse shocks. But, such a strategy poses risks. If the Fed were
deemed too accommodative for too long, credibility could be undermined, threatening to

- 12-

create a persistent inflation problem that would have to be corrected, no doubt at great
cost. The public could mistakenly see the stance of policy as a sign that our commitment
to long-term price stability has wavered. That is not a perception we will countenance.
The inflation news since last summer offers little solace. Oil prices are near
record levels, food prices have risen rapidly, prices for a wide range of commodities are
up, and dollar depreciation is among the causes pushing up import prices. Some
indicators of expected long-run inflation have also risen. Given changes in investor
preferences for risk-free assets amid the market turmoil, I take less signal from the
seemingly satisfactory signals derived from spreads between Treasury securities and
comparable Treasury inflation-protected securities.
No fair recitation of inflation risks, however, should neglect the seeming steady
state of core inflation. It is running at about the same pace as a year ago, and wage
growth appears unlikely to accelerate. Moreover, if commodity prices level out as
markets expect, prospects seem decent for a gradual moderation in inflation over time.
Nonetheless, futures markets assessments of these prices have been wrong for awhile. As
a result, a benign forecast for inflation carries considerable upside risk.
On Monetary Policy...in Times of Possible Paradigm Shift
We should be reminded that a country's macroeconomy is established by the
microeconomic decisions of millions of individuals on the front lines of real business and
consumption. Adaptation, dynamism, and flexibility are watchwords of a successful
economy, but they test the capability of public authorities to encourage, measure, and
incorporate. Here again, Munger, my preferred investment pro, offers a final lesson
applicable to the crafting of monetary policy: Resist the tendency to overweight what can

be counted and thereby underweight factors that are more important. 11 If the flexibility
and resiliency of our labor, product, and capital markets change materially—resulting
from some new policy consensus on trade policies, tax policies, or regulatory policies—
the economy's potential would assuredly be affected. These changes are hard to
incorporate into monetary policy, but that should not distract us from their importance.
No surprise, then, that the determination of the proper level of the real federal funds rate
continues to be subject to considerable debate.
The Fed, of course, is not the only monetary policy maker of consequence in a
globally integrated economy. Our counterparts, particularly among our major trading
partners, bring their own prudential policy prescriptions to bear based on their judgments
on the contours of their real economies, financial markets, and inflation risks. We should
expect nothing else. Some argue that a new paradigm of global economic growth is at
hand and that traditional engines of growth like the United States are stalling, but the
effects on the world's other major economies will be of little consequence. Whether the
economies of the rest of the world have successfully decoupled from the United States is
a judgment we will have to leave to the economic historians. What I do believe,
however, is that our financial markets at the center of this turmoil have not decoupled,
not even a little bit. In fact, our financial institutions and financial markets have never
been more integrated. Policy differences, thus, should not be taken lightly.
Conclusion
In my judgment, the changes in credit availability during the past six years have
less to do with the prevailing stance of policy and more to do with changes in financial
markets and financial intermediaries. Returning the economy to equilibrium requires
" See Munger (2003) in footnote 3.

- 14-

actions more befitting than changes in the federal funds rate alone. The lending facilities
created and employed by the Fed are likely proving useful in this regard. Increasing
liquidity by having a central bank lower the federal funds rate can reduce the risk of a
more severe financial crisis, but is imperfectly suited to compensate for declines in
liquidity arising from retrenchment in the financial sector for long periods.12
As policymakers, we strive to distill truths about how the conduct of monetary
policy, the transmission mechanism of financial markets, and other determinantsdomestic and foreign—affect real economic activity. In my remarks today, I tried to
expound not only on what we know, but also on what we don't. Successful economies
are dynamic and flexible. Their citizens respond to changes in policy preferences,
financial conditions, and global forces. Central bankers must seek a better understanding
of an economy's changing fundamentals, distilling lessons learned and aspiring to reduce
monetary policy to a science. In the interim, the art of monetary policy rightly will
predominate.

12

In my view, only when private financial agents resume their role as the primary source of liquidity in
markets will proper credit market functioning and support for economic growth be restored. (See Warsh
(2008) in footnote 4.)