View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

WHY IS FRIEDMAN LIKE FREUD?

Remarks of

Jeffrey M c Bucher
Member, Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System

to the

Alumni and Students of the
Department of Economics
at
Occidental College
Los Angeles, California

April 2, 1973

WHY IS FRIEDMAN LIKE FREUD?

Lest anyone get the impression from the title of this talk
that the minutes of the Federal Open Market Committee!s current
meetings--which will be made public five years hence--are going to
disclose that a radical change has occurred in the way the Committee
assesses the monetary aggregates and their behavior, let me save you
a long wait.

I am not hinting that we are now subjecting information

about the money supply to new judgmental values akin to Dr. Sigmund
Freud1s examination and evaluation of human personalities.

Nor will

a search through these dusty records reveal that we have learned to
make the economic world as predictably responsive to changes in the
monetary aggregates as a young man’s fancy to certain stimuli in
the spring.
Unfortunately, we are still dealing with an area which, to
most, is far from romantic--nevertheless there is a message in the
heading I have given my remarks.

In part, it is related to my

days at Occidental College, where--in preparation, as it turned out,
for a career in law, that led to a career in banking, that has now
led to a career in bank regulation and monetary policy--I studied
psychology.

But, in returning to this campus, I hope that my re­

marks will demonstrate that a study of the ideas of Freud and his
followers, Jung and Adler, may not have been a misspent youth.
the contrary, it may have alerted me to the possible dangers in
certain ways of thinking and schools of thought.




It also would

On

-

2-

appear to me that pioneers in the field of psychiatry and psychology
and their followers are not the only ones susceptible to the dangers
I am to describe.

Economists, writers, businessmen, and some people

in government may well have fallen ill with the same malady.
The results of such thinking can be summed up in the
exasperated comment attributed to Karl Marx, late in his life, that
"I am not a Marxist."
If in fact the father of communism said this, he did not
mean, of course, that he had abandoned his ideas.

He meant that he

had seen--already in his lifetime--among those who called themselves
Marxists, what he regarded as serious distortions of his ideology.
What I hear and read from the proponents of the monetarist
view of economics leads me to wonder if this theory is being
strained beyond its reach.
This does not mean that I believe Dr. Milton Friedman is
at all inclined to abandon the basis tenets of his theory as to the
relationship between the rate of change in the supply of money and
changes in economic activity.

But I wonder because I know that

when much of what is called Freudian thought is tested against an




in-depth view of Dr. Freud1s theses, a great deal that passes fcr
Freudianism is doctrine more stringently held, more rigidly applied,
less subtly understood, and far less tolerant of other theories,
than Freud himself intended, or would have approved.

-3-

Freudfs doctrines made ¿1 contribution of fundamental
importance in the fields of psychology and psychiatry.

However,

far too often, his followers have seized upon some of Freudfs
truths as the whole, and upon this inadequate foundation, they have
erected a religion in place of the careful, modest, often tentative,
qualified and always interacting total views of the man--very
conscious of his fal1ibility--they idolize.
I am afraid that this is the fate of many original thinkers
and it is this tendency to substitute dogma for careful thought that,
I said earlier, can be very dangerous indeed.
It seems to me that monetarism also is in danger of becom­
ing a religion patched together out of part truths.

Like Freudianism,

monetarism has made a valuable contribution to thinking in economics,
perhaps a contribution of fundamental importance, although more time
is needed to know for sure.

However, it is certain that Dr. Friedman

has focused a great deal of thinking on the supply side of the
monetary ledger, dealing with the amount of funds that become avail­
able to the economy during a time sequence.




The interaction of

supply with demand affects the price of these funds in terms of
interest rates and the complex of factors called 'market conditions1.

Are the
Aggregates Like Sex?
Too many of those who have taken Ur. Friedman1s ideas to
heart are doing what 1 regard as a disservice to the real present




-4-

values, and future potential, of monetarist thought.

Very much as

the students of Freud permitted--or encouraged--the idea to develop
that Freudianism was a Pandora*s box of sex drives, sex repressions
and sex manifestations--obscuring the deeper, more complex and
broader implications of Freud1s life work--so, it seems to me,
monetarists are treating the aggregates.
There is an amazingly popular monetarist view--perhaps it
should be called monetarist fundamentalism--that a steady supply of
money fed into the economy at a given rate will cure our main economic
ills, and promise steady growth of the economy.

This mistreats the

aggregates as the be-all and end-all of economics, as sex is mis­
treated as the be-all and end-all of human behavior.
Perhaps some such simple dogmatism was necessary to get
the attention of those who held a fixated view that the objectives
of monetary policy could--indeed, should--be sought only by affecting
interest rates and credit market conditions, without concern as to the
necessary supply of money.

The Federal Reserve has always had some

concern with the role of the supply of money in monetary policy, but
the degree of emphasis has varied over time.
aggregates have been given increased emphasis.

Recently, monetary
You need only look

at any directive of the Federal Open Market Committee of the Federal
Reserve System to see that full attention has for some time been
given to stating monetary policy goals in terms of money supply as




-5-

well as market conditions.

These periodic directives to the Manager

of the Open Market Account now typically read:
To implement...(the Committee1s goals)...the Committee
seeks to achieve bank reserve and money market conditions
that will support (slower, greater, etc.) growth
in the monetary aggregates...
So let me respond to all those cards and letters telling
us that a new millenium is born in economics.
We know it is there.
tant star.

We are watching it.

We see the new star.

We consider it an impor­

To a substantial degree we are guided by it.

But we do

not regard the monetary aggregates as the only important star in
the firmament.
This is to say that I believe there is little, if any,
tendency at the Federal Reserve Board to mistake the monetarist
view of economic behavior as a viable substitute for the whole of
economic thought.
Nor, let me add, can there be many who are engaged in
the day-to-day struggle that the monetary policy maker must accept—
to try and make theory fit real life--who believe that the monetarist
prescription of a smooth optimum curve of supplied money can be
implemented anywhere outside the cool recesses of the scholarfs
study.

The Federal Reserve operates in and for a real world.

It is

a world that could not--and, in my view, should not--be brought to
accept a serious economic upset such as, say, a liquidity crisis and




-6-

its entailed output and employment crises, as the price of getting
on to an optimum money supply curve.

This, in my view, would be

so, even in the face of strong evidence that such an ideal flow of
new money would result in a highly desirable, smooth and non-in::lationary optimum growth curve0
But that is by no means all.

On the contrary, there is

in fact no evidence that should the monetary authority close its
eyes, stop its ears, grit its teeth and--abdicating real world
monetary policy functions--instruct its Open Market Manager to keep
letting new money into the economy at a pre-ordained rate, an
optimum and non-inflationary economic growth curve would result.
This is no more realistic, in my judgment, than is the
notion--torn from the body of Freud*s thinking--that if we can
learn enough about the origins of sex drives and their management,
we can produce thereby a whole and serene human personality.
propositions appear to me to be false for the same reason.

Both
That is,

many factors are at work that cannot be reached by a single-minded
prescription.
In the case of monetary policy, the central fact is that
the Federal Reserve cannot alone determine the economic climate.
The Federal Reserve cannot control fiscal policy--stimulative,
restrictive or neutral spending and taxing policy--which is totally
in the hands of the Congress and the White House.

The effects of

-7-

fiscal policy can at any time overwhelm the efforts of monetary
policy.

And fiscal policy responds chiefly to non-economic stimuli.
A number of other factors external to the powers of the

monetary authority can also overwhelm, or at the very least, severely
affect, monetary policy actions.

Among these are changes in the

propensities of people to spend or to save.

The public may prefer to

invest new money in savings accounts where it is used slowly, rather
than to spend it rapidly on goods and services, thereby quickly
affecting inventories, new orders, output and employment.

Or, even

when the monetary authority is in a restrictive posture, the public
may become more aggressive spenders, thereby overheating an economy
already working at near capacity.

The effects of such action would,

of course, be damaging upon the interest rate structure, the price
structure, productivity, and international movements of money.
Business too can go on a capital spending spree, or snap the business
purse shut, and either of these actions may be at odds with monetary
policy and offset its effects.
It is not only the fact that the Federal Reserve cannot
ignore, and may find itself unable to control, such developments
through monetary policy.

It is also the fact that the Federal Reserve

must observe, be alert to, make judgments about such developments, and
take appropriate action.
We have neither the information nor the wisdom to insist
that the Federal Reserve, and the Federal Reserve alone, knows what







-8-

is besto
what.

That it has set its course and will not change no matter

Or that the Congress and the President elected by the people,

to say nothing of the judgments or desires of businesses and families
as to how to use funds available to them, must all take second place
to our judgment as to what is best for the economy.

The
Experiment
Let me come now to some aspects of current monetary policy
and the techniques being used to effect it.

I hope the foregoing

remarks may be useful backgound for this concluding section of my
talk.
I want to emphasize that I will be talking about a techni­
cal device for achieving the goals of monetary policy--for improving
our aim.

In setting monetary policy we set up objectives in the

context of what we see happening in the economy and what we see coming.
We set these financial objectives, I should emphasize, in the knowledge
that monetary policy actions take effect with a rather extensive lag
of at least three to six months and perhaps out to a year or more.
It takes some time for changes in liquidity conditions to work them­
selves through the economy, and they reach some parts of the economy
with greater or lesser degrees of delay.
As the evidence of this piles up in our computers, we are
more and more keenly aware that while we cannot ignore the current
scene and while our actionswill havesome .

-9-

effects on the short run situation, we are in fact making monetary
policy in an economic continuum in which current policy continued
for, say, as much as three to six months will have lagged effects
of restraint or ease in the future.

Thus, with our sword raised to

slay the dragon of inflation, we must be aware that restraint--or,
to take the opposite case, ease-applied today may have relatively
less effect upon very near term conditions than upon conditions nine
months, a year, or more ahead.
The implications of this policy making problem are many.
They involve, among others, the fact that in real world conditions
we cannot appear to be supplying more funds than the need to fight
off present and evident inflationary trends suggests, or negatively
affecting money supply and bank deposits or credit when the economy
clearly needs to be stimulated.

All this, however, concerns what

target to select at any given time.

The knowledge that the financial

goals we choose will have effects far into the future is, at least, an
argument for being as accurate as possible in hitting them.

If you are

worried that restraining actions today may result later in more
restraint than you want, or that today's ease is inflationary tinder
for the future, you certainly do not want to over-restrain, or over­
ease today.
Just over a year ago, the FOMC adopted a revised technique,
designed to give the Federal Reserve more accurate control of the
monetary aggregates.




This has become known as the RPD technique,

-10-

standing for Reserves Available to Support Private Deposits.

As

Chairman Arthur F. Burns explained shortly after this new technique
was put experimentally into effect, the object was to try to get a
better "handle" on the problem of controlling the aggregates.
It is not a neat, clean, reproducible laboratory experiment.
It takes place in the hurly-burly of the market place.

There have

been recent times when interest rate patterns seemed to be of such
commanding importance that some thought we had abandoned the RPD
experiment, and with it our interest in the aggregates, and had gone
back to a fixation on money market conditions.

Also, there have been

outbursts of growth in the aggregates--for instance in July and
December of last year— which convinced some that we must abandon the
experiment because it was not working.
The fact is that the experiment is alive and well.

Given

the very bumpy year in which it has existed, we have seen nothing thus
far to suggest that it should be abandoned.

The past year has seen

accelerating economic growth at home, leading to almost explosive
growth conditions early in this year.

There have been waves of

speculative attack on the international monetary system that have at
times given extraordinary prominence to our interest rate pattern,
and that required close attention to money market conditions to
cushion the effects at home.

This has taken place at a time of

winding down of our war effort and, finally, of major budget policy
changes.




-11-

Given all these real world pressures, I think that the
Federal Reserve can take some pride in the fact that, with the RPD
technique in use at a time of unusual stresses and uncertainties,
the money supply has increased near to, but somewhat less than, real
economic growth.

That is, we have financed real growth and not more.

That of course, in view of lagged effects, leaves the question whether
we should have done less or more at any particular time, but that,
again, is a matter of what is the right target, not how to hit it.
It is encouraging that after the massive bulge in the money supply
in December of 1972, we were able to balance matters with a month
of no money supply growth in January, only about 3 per cent in
February and probably--as best as can be judged from now available
data--no sizable gain this month.
More time is of course needed before it can be said that
the RPD device has fully proved itself.
me enter at this point a cautionary note.

In line with this, let
The RPD device cannot be

used mechanically, any more than an aggregates target can be used
mechanically.

Demand for money is volatile over shortperiods.

It

takes at least three to six months to tell what the basic trend of
the money supply is.

All our studies at the Federal Reserve show

that short-run changes in money--weekly, monthly or even bi-monthly-have little, if any, significance0
So the intense interest shown by many financial writers,
and some economists, in such short term changes, is misleading«




-12-

They should keep their eye much more on the three-month, six-month
and one-year changes published weekly by the Federal Reserve.
We have been asked over the past year if evidence of
considerable focus at times on money market conditions does not show
that we are reverting to old pre-aggregates form.

One part of the

answer is that the very existence of the RPD technique has helped
to avoid this because it focuses the attention of the System Account
Manager--who carries out our open market operations--on reserves.
These reserves, as I have already indicated, are not an
end in themselves.

Nor, for that matter, are money market conditions.

The reserves in RPD include reserves behind all types of deposits-including savings deposits and large negotiable certificates of
deposit, except for interbank and government deposits.

Thus, RPD

is a wide-spectrum tool.
A focus on RPD is a help in confronting the problem that
increases in the reserve base may support chiefly one or another
type of deposit, depending upon public preferences as to the form
in which people or businesses wish to maintain their liquidity.

For

example, if increased reserves support mainly types of deposits that
require relatively small amounts of reserves--deposits in small
banks, certificates of deposits* Eurodollars, or passbook savings
deposits--there would automatically be a bigger multiplier effect

1/




In the weekly statistical release titled "Weekly Summary of
Banking and Credit Measures," numbered H.9.

-13-

upon the total amount of deposits that will be supported by a given
amount of supplied reserves.

This sets up a trade-off among

and

other definitions of money and bank credit, in which, while M-^ may
be growing only slowly, broader money supplies and bank credit may
expand more rapidly.
Problems raised by shifts in the forms in which the public
holds liquidity, as well as shifting propensities to save or to spend,
merely highlight the distinction that should be made between technical
problems and policy problems.

To the degree that monetary policy

wishes to control monetary aggregates, it is a technical problem to
decide how best this might be done.
In this light, the experiment with RPD can be viewed as a
technical experiment.

But it is a policy problem to decide how

accommodative--or not--to be in the face of shifts in the demand for
money, shifts in fiscal policy and changes in a number of other
external forces that continually confront monetary policy makers.
A technical experiment cannot make those policy choices for us,
although we must have the technical basis for implementing our
decisions.

But making decisions as to desirable long-run growth

rates in monetary aggregates or desirable effects upon credit
markets is the most important part of policy making.
illusions that RPD will do this job for us.

We have no

However, we have high

hopes that it will be a genuine help to us in carrying out policy
more accurately.




-0-

GOVERNOR BUCHER'S SPEECH OF APRIL 2, 1973

ERRATA:




Read last sentence, first paragraph, Page 11 as follows:
It is encouraging that after the massive bulge in the money supply
in December of 1972, we were able to balance matters with a month
of no money supply growth in January, about 6 per cent in February
and probably - - a s best as can be judged from now available data —
no sizable gain last month.