View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Fot Release on Delivery
(Approximately 1:00 p.m.
Monday, February 17, 1969)




Much Ado About International Monetary Reform

Remarks by J. Dewey Daane
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
Before The Cleveland Business Economists Club
Cleveland, Ohio
on Monday, February 17, 1969

Much Ado About International Monetary Reform

In French author Jules Romain's famous play, Dr. Knock, the central
theme concerns a new doctor who convinces an entire, and hitherto healthy,
community that each inhabitant is sick.

Dr. Knock's basic credo is

"Tout homme bien portant est urt malade qui s fignore11 which translates,
roughly, as
ill."

:Every well man is really a sick man who doesn't know he's

By the end of the play, Dr. Knock has succeeded in being so con­

vincing in implanting this credo that all income earners (to whom he caters)
are at home in bed in a darkened room with only a small light on and
medicines at hand!
Like Romain's fictional community of St. Maurice, the health of the
international monetary system has, it seems to me, often been far too
susceptible to the Dr. Knocks of the world with their unnecessary and
sometimes even harmful prescriptions.

At one point in the play Dr. Knock

frightens a prospective patient into believing himself to be a germ carrier
by citing evidence that "makes it plain as day, proves by instance upon
instance, that a man can go about looking the picture of health, clear
tongue, eye bright, appetite excellent, and be carrying in every nook and
cranny of his system trillions of germs--poisonous enough to infect a
whole county.
carrier.

I have a right to suspect any man I see of being a germ

You now!

What is there to prove to me that you are not?1'

Just so in the case of the international monetary system.
after instance" or, more recently, "crisis after crisis

"Instance

is adduced in

evidence that the entire system is malfunctioning and about to collapse.
The same doctors often, perhaps sometimes even deliberately, obfuscate what




-

2

-

are the evidences of health and strength, and very real accomplishments,
of the system--a system far from perfect but surely.not in need of
amputative surgery, nor of transplants, nor of quack medicines..

What

I mean is--not in need of freely fluctuating exchange rates, nor of a
wholesale revision of established exchange rates, nor capable of benefiting
from a gold price change.
The first question of the Dr. Knocks * however, regarding the health
of the international monetary system is, I suppose, the query "What is
there to prove that you are not (ill)?"

This query has been amplified

by the seeming succession of crises in 1967 and 1968.

But are those crises

symptomatic of the kind of germs in the system that are incapable of
eradication without destroying the organism itself?

Or are we being

victimized, instead, by a repetition of dire prophecies, causing many to
assume that deadly germs have taken over the system?

Is the system, perhaps,

much healthier than generally realized and on its way to even greater
strength after overcoming the various strains of 1967 and 1968, and
particularly after the new drawing rights in the IMF will have begun
to appear?
Here I think that some analysis of the contributions over time of the
Bretton Woods system, and an appraisal of the nature of the so-called
monetary crises of 1967-1968, shed not a small but a large light on the
sustainable health of the system.

In fact, as one reviews the accomplish­

ments of the international monetary system that has evolved since Bretton
Woods and looks forward to its further strengthening, now so clearly in
process and prospect through the creation of Special Drawing Rights, one




-

3

~

can find a firm basis for rejecting the idea that the system should be
treated as a chronically ill patient.

For it can be argued that the

several crises in 1967-1968 were basically crises of confidence in the
system rather than organic difficulties of the system.
But while one can reject out of hand the notion that the international
monetary system needs either dangerous surgery or quack prescriptions, it
is clear that further gradual improvement would make the system less
vulnerable to the actions of the speculators and'to the imperfections
(which some might call inactions) of the adjustment process.

And it is

certainly clear that the adjustment process itself--as each individual
country adapts the changes occurring in its internal economy to the necessity
for harmonious and viable relations with the economies of the rest of the
world--is capable of improvement.
Taking a look back at the usefulness, post-Bretton Woods, of the socalled fixed exchange rate system (or more accurately, perhaps, the
adjustable peg system), it is significant that we have had an unparalleled
and uninterrupted growth in world income, trade, and payments since its
establishment.

As the outgoing Council of Economic Advisers pointed out in

its most recent*. Annua 1 Report:




M .... Remarkable growth in the volume of inter­
national commerce has gone hand in hand with
sustained world prosperity; each has contributed
to the pther. At times, deep and obvious strains
in the international monetary system have imperiled
this progress, but these financial difficulties
have been weathered without a serious setback in
economic growth or world trade.”
.... In the years since the Second World War
growth has ccme to be accepted as a normal feature

-

4

-

of the world economy. It is easy to forget
that this was not the case in earlier periods.
The depression years of the 1930's present a
particularly sharp contrast. But by any
historical comparison, the economic progress
of the last 20 years is unprecedented."
"World income has more than doubled since
1950. In the fifties, growth was especially
rapid in the western European countries, while
in recent years the United States has grown
more vigorously. Japan has experienced rapid
and sustained growth throughout the period."
To accommodate this dynamic growth the international monetary system
itself has not been static but has undergone flexible adaptation.

The

resources of the International Monetary Fund have been increased from an
initial $8 billion to $21 billion presently, with an additional $6 billion
of resources available, if necessary, from a number of industrial countries
entering into an agreement to lend these1 resources (through the General
Arrangements to Borrow or GAB). A network of reciprocal currency agree­
ments has been established by the central banks of a number of countries for
suaps of each other's currency; the United States new has such swap arrange­
ments, that is mutual credit facilities, totaling $10.5 billion, with some
14 central banks and the Bank for International Settlements.
This growth of reserves and international credit facilities has enabled
the international monetary system to function effectively and to accommodate
the growth of world trade, payments, and income.

Even more importantly,

agreement enabling creation, for the first time by deliberate decision, of
a new reserve asset (the Special Drawing Rights or SDR's) to supplement
gold and dollars ensures that the present monetary system can be fully
responsive to the reserve needs of a dynamic and growing world economy.




Then one asks, legitimately.,.why. the seeming succession of crises?
One could, I suppose, begin with.the sterling crisis of November, 1967
and debate whether or not a credible package of internal and external
measures assembled earlier on might have dissipated the crisis, of con­
fidence that finally made sterling devaluation unavoidable.

One could

also, I suppose, ask whether--both in itself, and in the way in which it
was handled and contained in terms of immediate impact on other parities-the sterling devaluation did not demonstrate.that the international monetary
system is indeed quite able to cope with an unusually difficult problem
primarily reflecting loss of confidence in a major currency.. Again one
could give an optimistic reading of the Canadian crisis in February, 1968-a crisis which was purely speculative in nature, and was calmed by public
pronouncements of the Canadian and U. S. authorities, reinforced by the
conspicuous availability of substantial resources.
The gold crisis of March, 1968 perhaps merits somewhat more elaboration
but again, in essence, it was a massive wave of speculation--fed in part
by our own successive failures to control the American balance of payments
deficits--that forced us all to recognize the need to separate the supply
(and the price) of gold in the London and other private markets from the
official gold reserves of the monetary system.

As I have pointed out before,

the policy of maintaining the market price of gold in London had been
undertaken originally for the purpose of keeping commercial and private
transactions in gold close to the official price, thereby averting or
minimizing possible runs on the gold stock.

But it had become perfectly

clear that this was becoming a one way street for speculators and that the




gold pool operations, rather than re-enforcing the credibility of the
official price of gold, had, in fact, created a fear that official
reserves might be drawn down faster than any acceptable replacement could
be found for them.

The private speculators had provoked a demand for

gold that was feeding upon itself and menacing the continuity of official
reserves for the monetary system as a whole.
From this crisis of confidence, however, the system has emerged
stronger rather than weaker.

For the establishment of the two-tier system

for gold was linked directly to the prospective creation of new reserve
assets within the International Monetary Fund.

As the system continues

and is supplemented by SDR creation, gold will be called upon to play a
diminishing role, and speculative price movements in the private markets
for gold, if they occur, will have less and less relevance to the official
price and less and less significance for the monetary system.
The most recent ,:crisis" in November, 1968--leading to what in
retrospect appears to have been an unnecessary and largely unrewarding
international monetary conference at Bonn--was again not a reflection
of a structural defect or organic malaise of the international monetary
system, unless one assumes that official unwillingness to change rates
is now a permanently fixed doctrine.

In the first instance, it was once

more a reflection of the power of market expectations that must be met
and absorbed by any system which serves the changing needs of a dynamic
world economy.

In this case the expectation was that the German mark

would soon have to be revalued and that, in turn, this might provoke a
devaluation in France or the United Kingdom and set off a chain reaction




-

affecting other countries as well.

7

-

As my colleague and adviser to the

Board, Mr. Robert Solomon, has well stated:
!;The first observation we can make about
this crisis is that it was not in any
direct way attributable to the nature of
the present international monetary structure.
The fact that the dollar is widely held as a
reserve currency was in no way responsible
for the difficulties.
(It is notable that
the market price of gold barely rose during
the eventful week of November 18.) One
could imagine a similar crisis--involving
expectations of exchange rate changes and
the danger of competitive depreciation-in a Jacques Rueff gold standard world or
in a Robert Triffin conversion account
world in which there is only one reserve
asset. In other words, the so-called con­
fidence problem--involving the inter­
convertibility of two or more reserve assets-had nothing to do with the cause or severity of
this crisis. It is one of the many ironies of
the events of the last two weeks of November
that this international monetary crisis which
embroiled France should not reflect the
alleged weaknesses in the monetary system
that French officials have been pointing
to for years." 1/
This bare bones recital of the international monetary system’s
accomplishments and adaptations--a recital with which you are all too
familiar, I am sure--is intended mainly as a reminder of the positive
aspects of the present system.

The troublesome episodes I have touched on

reflected the power of shifting expectations concerning individual countries,
when individual countries have differences among them in their policies,
their purposes and their performance.

1/

Such differences will always occur

(See R. Solomon "Reflections on the International Monetary Crisis,
Monthly Review, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, December, 1968.)




3

so long as the world is dynamic and countries differ,

I do not, repeat

not, conclude that the system is perfect but I do continue to believe
that it is perfectible in the sense that, through further international
cooperation, it is capable of being improved and can provide a foundation
for sustainable growth in the future.

As the CEA noted in its Annual

Report:
MTo be sure, the international monetary system
has had its problems. Crises have occurred all
too frequently. Yet the system has consistently
been able to meet the needs of the day, it has
evolved and adapted, and it can be strengthened
further to meet the remaining strains.'5
Looking to the future--what can be done to strengthen further the
system?

An obvious but extremely important first step is to press for­

ward to the realization of the SDR's, to bring them from the world of
theory into the world of fact.

In the process of ratification, the latest

count shows 34 member countries, representing just over 50 percent of the
voting power, ratifying the agreement (as compared with the required 67
member countries representing 80 percent of the voting power).

Full

ratification in the near future, of course, is expected.
An equally important corollary step in improving the functioning of
the international monetary system--and vital to the bringing of SDR's
into being--is the strengthening of the adjustment process through
appropriate internal as well as external policies.

For most, if not all,

of the confidence crises that I have described reflect insufficient
willingness or effort to make the adjustment process effective through
either demand polic:




ge rates.

LIBRARY

-

9

-

Here the United States' responsibility,. as pointed out by Secretary
of the Treasury, David Kennedy, is plain.

We must contain an inflation

that is so damaging to our international position as well .as to our
domestic objectivies.
is clear.

And our own Federal Reserve role in this effort

The evidence now surfacing in the monetary aggregates, and

even in bits and pieces of economic data such as the sales and inventory
figures, of the cumulative impact of the gradual but persistent pressure
of monetary policy, alongside fiscal policy, should serve as an adequate
rejoinder to any possible misinterpretation or skepticism as to our ability
and willingness to stay on course.
Before leaving the matter of the adjustment process, I should hasten
to point out--as has, I think, been increasingly recognized in our
mutually constructive discussions with our counterparts abroad--that
improvement of the adjustment process by appropriate policies of individual
countries requires not only efforts by deficit countries, but by surplus
countries as well.
Related to this, scme--mainly academicians--have suggested that
another potential source of improvement in the system may conceivably be
found in a lessening of the degree of rigidity with respect to the present
exchange rate system--both the rigidity of the rates themselves and the
rigidity of attitudes concerning the appropriateness of some change in
these rates.
further study.

A variety of suggestions have been put forward for possible
One is to explore techniques for introducing greater but

still limited flexibility in exchange rates.




Another is to explore the

-

1 0

-

technique used in the recent crisis by France and Germany, of adjustment
of border taxes and export rebates as an alternative method of improving
21

the adjustment process. —

Seme of the technical and other problems of a

more flexible exchange rate system have recently been outlined effectively
by both Dr. Otmar Emminger of the German Bundesbank, and by Dr. -Edward M.
Bernstein, the former Chief Economist of the International Monetary Fund.
Nevertheless, we should remain open-minded and willing to engage in study,
objectively and cooperatively, when and where it seems appropriate, of
suggestions for improving the adjustment process.
This brings me full circle in my remarks here today.

I began by

stressing the exposure of the system to the attacks of its critics
which have engendered expectations and attitudes inimical to the system
itself.

Official policies, or lack thereof, cannot escape responsibility

for fostering such expectations and attitudes.

I retfcain convinced that

the present system can be best improved by gradual change, without abrupt,
or dramatic, moves that might in themselves make impossible the continued
contributions of the system to continued growth of world trade and payments.
As Secretary Kennedy has said:
"Calm study in cooperation with our friends-not unilateral actions or disruptive changes
in the vital role of the dollar and gold-must remain the foundation of real reform
and progress in the international financial
system.
Appropriate policies contributing to, rather than detracting from, the
adjustment process are an integral part of any improvement.

2/




Ibid.

Here it is

-

1 1

-

essential to recognize, and to find ways to reconcile, the aims and
objectives of the various countries concerned.

It is heartening that

the OECD is engaged currently in just such an analysis.
Recently someone from the press asked me whether I foresaw in 1969
a repetition of the monetary crises of 1968.

In the tumultuous world in

which we live conjecture of this sort would be foolish.

But in reply

I said there need not be and that I was reminded that in his memoirs
Winston Churchill records an historic conversation with Franklin D. Roosevelt,
in which they discussed what to label World War II.

Churchill said that

at the time, and for a variety of reasons, he responded immediately, "the
unnecessary war,:'
My own hope* and sincere belief, is that with the continuance of the
Bretton Woods system, strengthened by the added dimension of SDR's,
supplemented by expanded credit facilities, validated by an improved
adjustment process in which the U. S. role is vital, and amended gradually
and only after careful explorations in close and calm cooperation with our
friends, any international crisis that might develop could only merit the
label "the unnecessary crisis."