View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For Release on Delivery
(Approximately 7:00 p.ma,
Friday, November 13, 1964)




INTERNATIONAL LI QUIDITY AND ALL THAT

Remarks by J. Dewey Daane
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
Before the Southern Finance Association
Atlanta, Georgia
on Friday, November 13, 1964

INTERNATIONAL LIQUIDITY ¿ND ALL THAT

Remarks by J. Dewey Daane
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
Before the Southern Finance Association
Atlanta, Georgia
on Friday, November 13, 1964

In the history of economic thought 1964 may well go down as
the "Year of Liquidity”.

For throughout the world economists and

financial officials, many of whom still classify themselves as
economists, have been struggling with the question of the possible
future needs for international liquidity.

And at home more than just

side glances have been given to the matter of our domestic liquidity,
amidst charges by some Europeans that the liquidity which has proven
to be the successful servant of an orderly expansion in the U. S.
economy has, at the same time, contributed to excessive liquidity
internationally and aggravated problems of inflation abroad.
All of you are, I am sure, familiar with the various liquidity
studies that were concluded and published this last August.

To begin,

there was the study initiated by the Ministers and Governors of the
so-called "Group of Ten"--the ten leading industrial countries
participating in the General Arrangements to Borrow— a study of
"the outlook for the functioning of the international monetary system
and its probable future needs for liquidity".

Paralleling this was

the study of liquidity which the International Monetary Fund included




- 2 in its Nineteenth Annual Report.

And a group of some thirty-two

academic economists from the Group of Ten countries, plus Switzerland,
carried out still another study, under private auspices.
From all of the ferment of this past year many different concepts
and possible measures of international liquidity have come to the
fore.

These concepts and measures are directly relevant to a number

of the proposals currently under review that would provide for such
future liquidity problems as might develop.

Consequently, they merit

exploration and consideration before turning to the questions of
the current and prospective adequacy of liquidity and of what form
any necessary degree of future expansion in world liquidity should take.
On the conceptual front much progress has been made in delineat­
ing the many facets and components of liquidity; in fact, one of the
most significant developments in the various liquidity studies recently
completed has been a greater recognition that there is in fact a
broad spectrum of liquidity, ranging from reserves owned outright-gold and foreign exchange holdings--through assured and readily avail­
able credit facilities, and on out to possible negotiated credits.
It has been generally recognized in the official studies by the
Group of Ten and the IMF that international liquidity consists of
all the resources that are available to monetary authorities for the
purpose of meeting balance of payments deficits.

I might mention

parenthetically that the academic group did not go quite the full
way in this.

The International Study Group of 32 economists, while

taking cognizance of the spectrum of assets and borrowing powers,




- 3 chose to confine their concept of liquidity narrowly to owned reserves
and unconditional drawing rights.

This seems to me to ignore the

fact that balance of payments deficits can be financed either by a
transfer of international reserve assets

(gold and foreign exchange)

from deficit to surplus countries, or by the extension of credit
directly by the surplus country or through an international institu­
tion— whether the credit is obtained unconditionally or otherwise.
Just as domestic liquidity means command over domestic means of pay­
ments, so international liquidity means command over international
means of payments, however that command may be obtained or arranged.
The essea'ial point is that command over means of international
payments includes both the ownership of such means and the avail­
ability of facilities that assure the ready acquisition of such means
in case of need.

While the "owned reserves11 and "credit facilities"

components of liquidity may have certain overlapping characteristics,
the distinction between them has played an important role in the
recent liquidity studies and is germane to the issues confronting
all of us in our continuing studies of international liquidity.
"Owned reserves" consist mainly of the traditional reserve assets,
gold and foreign exchange.

But for all practical purposes they also

encompass two other types of assets which have only quite recently
attained reserve character:

the so-called gold tranches of the quotas

of member countries of the International Monetary Fund; and the socalled Roosa-bonds.
Gold tranches are, very roughly speaking, the equivalent of the
gold component of member countries1 subscriptions to the IMF, plus




- 4 those amounts of their currency subscriptions that have been used for
drawings by other member countries.

Members are free to draw on the

Fund's resources to the extent of their gold tranche positions
virtually without any formality or restriction; this automatic char­
acter of gold tranche drawing rights has been emphasized by recent
steps to further streamline the Fund's procedures for such drawings.
Hence, these tranches are practically the equivalent of a demand de­
posit, or similar claim, with an international bank.

The United States

financed a sizeable part of its deficits in recent years out of just
such claims, and Italy, too, earlier this year discovered just how
useful its gold tranche, representing a build up of credit in the
IMF, could be in financing its deficit,
Roosa-bonds are obligations of the U. S. Treasury issued to
foreign central banks or governments, most of them denominated in
the currency of the creditor country.

They are usually redeemable

before maturity if the creditor country confronts a payments deficit.
Last spring, for instance, Italy had payments troubles.

In agreement

with the U. S. Treasury, it presented its Roosa-bonds for advance
redemption, and used the proceeds for a transfer to Germany;
Germany, in turn, converted those proceeds back into new Roosa-bonds.
Hence, although the Roosa-bonds themselves are non-marketable, they
could be used by Italy to pay a debt to Germany--just as if they had
been international means of payments.
"Credit facilities" can be considered part of a country's inter­
national liquidity if their availability, even when subject to
negotiation, is sufficiently assured that the country can reasonably




- 5 -

count on using them in case of need.

At present, such facilities

include the swap arrangements between the Federal Reserve and major
foreign central banks, and the credit tranches of member countries
of the IMF*
Facilities under the Federal Reserve swaps are practically
identical with mutual credit lines, with predetermined amounts avail­
able to either party to the arrangements as circumstances may require.
The IMF credit tranches correspond to the part of a country's quota
that exceeds the gold tranche.

Utilization of IMF credit tranches

has various degrees of assurance, ranging from virtual certainty in
the case of so-called stand-by arrangements to the need for present­
ing effective stabilization programs in the case of applications for
drawings> or new standby arrangements, on tranches in excess of
one-half of a country's Fund quota.
Translating the broad spectrum of financing facilities into the
world of fact, what are the real magnitudes of the various components
in total world liquidity in the present setting?

First of all,

look­

ing at the attached table, total world liquidity (official) amounted,
at mid-1964, to almost $87 billion, of which about three-fourths
represented owned reserves in traditional gold and foreign exchange
form and one-fourth other assets and credit availability.

Of the

traditional owned reserves, gold totaled some $40 billion, or about
607o, and foreign exchange totaled some $25 billion, or about 407o.
New types of reserve assets with characteristics similar to owned
reserves--gold tranches and Roosa-bonds— added almost $5 billion more.




- 6 -

In addition, credit facilities, in the form of Federal Reserve swaps
and IMF credit tranches, totaled slightly more than $16 billion.
These absolute magnitudes, however, conceal the increasing reliance
on newer forms of liquidity in the growth of the total in recent
years.

For of the $20 billion growth of total world liquidity since

the advent of the era of currency convertibility at the end of 1958,
only about two-fifths of the $20 billion increase in liquidity took
the traditional form of gold and foreign exchange, while other
similar type assets and credit availability accounted for three-fifths.
Against this background of concept and measurement of inter­
national liquidity, what about its adequacy?

Here we begin to get

into very muddy water indeed for there are no adequate criteria of
adequacy.

Some would appraise adequacy--neither too little, nor too

much, international liquidity--as most clearly discernible in the
actions of monetary authorities.

In their view, international

liquidity is adequate if there is prima facie evidence that no coun­
try is either taking unduly restrictive steps in the interest of
conserving reserves, or following overly expansionary policies by
virtue of having recourse to the external liquidity tap.

In the

light of a recommended and prospective increase of Fund resources,
both the Group of Ten and IMF studies, noting the difficult judg­
ments involved and decrying any quantitative formula, concluded that
liquidity is fully adequate for the present.

If the pace and con­

tinuance of economic growth is taken as an indicator, the recent
past and present adequacy of international liquidity can hardly
be doubted.




- 7 -

While recent past and present adequacy of international liquidity
may be demonstrable by record and sustained economic growth alone,
future adequacy can be no more than a guess.

On the supply side we

can make some reasonable forecasts about the future supply of the
various components of liquidity.

But the demand side is equally

relevant, and here we are confronted with two major indeterminate
factors; the first, that of attitudes, and the second, that of
adjustments.
As to the first, attitudes have much to do with prospective
liquidity needs.

Sometimes I wonder whether international liquidity

is not simply a state of mind.

This is much more than a facetious

observation because, as we have learned during the past year, atti­
tudes taken toward available assets, such as gold tranches, and
other credits are importantly determinative of the adequacy of
liquidity and, specifically, of the supposed needs for additional
owned reserves.

If countries were to become engaged in a competi­

tive race merely to pile up owned reserves and then to protect
rather than to use such reserves,
assume one form and dimension.

future liquidity needs would

If, on the other hand, countries

chose to maximize the potential usefulness of an existing stock of
liquidity by more efficient mobilization, supplemented by a larger
and more effective credit mechanism under multilateral review,

liquid­

ity needs assume a different shape altogether.
The second major imponderable in forecasting liquidity needs
is how smoothly and rapidly the adjustment process works.




As we

- 8 -

know from the record, the demand for liquidity does not, of necessity,
rise pari passu with the growth of international trade.

Looking

back at the period betx^een mid-1958 and mid-1964 the annual trade
volume (exports plus imports) grew from $196 billion to $311 billion,
or nearly 607®.

From the attached table it may be seen that inter­

national liquidity rose only half as fast in that period, from
$67 billion to $87 billion, or about 30%.

There is no sacrosanct

fixed relation between liquidity and rising world economic activity,
any more than there is between the money supply and a given rate of
domestic economic growth.
More determinative of liquidity needs than the total trade level
is the speed and efficiency of the process of adjusting imbalances.
Inevitably the many transactions between countries--more specifically
between the individuals, businessmen, traders and financial institu­
tions of the various countries--result in imbalances in total pay­
ments between countries.

It is the function of international liquid-

ity--both reserves and credit--to finance these inevitable imbalances,
until they are reversed either by normal, more or less automatic,
processes or by deliberate policy measures.

The process by which

surpluses or deficits are reversed has come to be called the
"adjustment process".
I should hasten to add that while the adjustment process may
importantly affect liquidity needs, the reverse does not hold in
quite the same way--liquidity cannot for long substitute for efforts




i

i i’— y

j-i r ' - i - w

- 9 -

the adjustment process, however, do color judgments about the role
of international liquidity in that process.

Limited liquidity may

force rapid, and perhaps undesired, adjustment, while rapid adjust­
ment should reduce liquidity needs.

Liberal liquidity would permit

gradual, perhaps too gradual, adjustment and means, in effect, much
higher liquidity needs and supplies.

Again this distinction is

central to the differences in view between the U. S. and some conti­
nental countries regarding a balance of payments program and the r(/le
in it of monetary policy.
One of the major recommendations in the Group of Ten Report was
that Working Party-3 of OECD undertake a study of the adjustment
process of correcting imbalances in international payments, with a
view to determining appropriate policies for avoiding such imbalances.
A related major recommendation called for "multilateral surveillance
of bilateral financing and liquidity creation"--basically, nothing
more nor less than a decision among the Ten to exchange information
more promptly and regularly regarding means of financing any sur­
pluses or deficits.

As a result, Working Party-3— with the benefit

of more current information derived in the multilateral surveillance
process--will be undertaking to review possible "rules of the game"
that might serve to improve the adjustment process in the more com­
plex world in which economic policies must be flexibly adapted to
differing national needs.

Much has been said about the diminished

role of monetary policy in this process.

I would not dispute the

point that the same kind and degree of monetary policy actions that
may have served the simpler classical model of disequilibrium might




- 10 -

not as often be appropriate to the different sort of world in which
we live.

At the same time we should not lose sight of the fact that

monetary policy in the United States, and elsewhere, has played and
will,

I am sure, continue to play, an important role--with techniques

appropriately tailored to both internal and external considerations.
Despite the imprecision of any appraisal of future liquidity
needs, the outlook for the various supply components provides im­
pressive assurance of reasonable growth in total world liquidity to
meet foreseeable needs over the next few years.
Quite recently,

the contribution of gold to monetary reserves

has greatly increased; in the first half of 1964 monetary gold
accrued at an annual rate in excess of $1 billion, about twice the
average of the preceding five years.

This high rate is attributable

not only to steady expansion of gold production and larger Soviet
sales, but, most importantly, to steadily rising confidence in the
stability of the monetary system of the free world, deterring
speculative hoarding.

Continuance of these favorable developments

may well result in gold contributing more to international liquidity
supply in the period ahead than in most recent years.

On the other

hand, the contribution of additional foreign exchange holdings to
world reserves cannot be expected to continue as in the past.
the last twelve months,

for example,

Over

the aggregate of foreign

official dollar holdings has not changed.

At best,

perhaps the

future aggregate additions to liquidity from the two traditional re­
serve assets may be in the neighborhood of the average increase
over the past 5 years.




- 11

On the credit facilities side, however, which has been provid­
ing the necessary expansibility of world liquidity, another major
increase in supply in the form of IMF quotas is in prospect.
IMF quotas will presumably be raised next year by at least 25%, or
some 4 to 5 billion dollars.

While further additions to Roosa-

bonds and swap arrangements may be modest, the strengthening of
cooperation involved in the process of "multilateral surveillance"
assures possible further elaboration and use of such bilateral
facilities.
Finally, no discussion of future needs for, and supplies of,
international liquidity would be complete without recognizing that
they are also influenced by the volume of private holdings of
foreign exchange.

Over the last 12 months foreign private holdings

of dollars alone have risen by more than $1 billion, while there
has been virtually no increase in the flow of dollars into official
reserves of other countries taken as a group, and Western Europe
has, on balance, paid out dollars from its reserves.

Thus, a sub­

stantial part (over three-fourths) of our own deficit, and corre­
sponding need for international liquidity to finance it, has been
met by increased holdings of dollars by foreign private accounts,
no doubt largely reflecting trade needs.

All this means is that

the private demand for international liquidity has an important
bearing on both present and future needs for official reserves and
credit facilities.
The central issue remaining--the issue that undoubtedly will
be, and should be, the focus of continuing study by economists




- 12 -

within and outside governments--is whether additional owned reserve
assets will have to be deliberately created and, if so, what are
their possible alternative forms.

All of the preceding discussion

of concepts, components and adequacy of liquidity is directly
relevant to this issue.

In the light of this discussion, the first

question to be raised is whether a new system for owned reserve
creation is likely to become necessary, or whether future needs for
international liquidity can, and should, be met largely through the
continuing expansion of international credit facilities.

As was

brought out in Tokyo, during the Bank-Fund meetings, the U. S. clearly
looks toward credit facilities to furnish in major part the neces­
sary flexibility and disciplined expansibility to meet future liquidity
needs.
As to the possible form of any new reserve assets that might be
created, the conclusion of the liquidity studies thus far is that
this aspect of the matter calls for further study and, indeed, such
study is already in process.

The Group of Ten has set up a special

"Study Group on Creation of Reserve Assets" specifically for this
purpose.

The IMF made no formal recommendation on this question

either but its report contained a discussion of various techniques
whereby the Fund might create and vary the supply of reserve assets
carried by its members.
Several major alternative proposals have been put forward for
adding to owned reserves in the future.

One proposal is for the

creation, by a limited group of industrial countries, of a new




- 13 -

reserve unit--referred to as a collective (or composite) reserve
unit.

Such a unit could be created by one of a number of different

techniques but its basic characteristic, as proposed,

is that it

would serve as a supplement to gold in the reserves of this group
of countries and in the financing of payments imbalances among this
group of countries.

Each country of the group would agree to hold

the new unit in fixed proportion to its gold holdings.

Thus if one

country in deficit sold gold to the others, collective reserve units
would also be transferred,

in fixed proportion to the amount of gold

transferred.
One of the advantages claimed for this approach is that it
would provide an "objective11 means of creating reserves in place of
what the French Finance Minister and Dutch central bank Governor




described in Tokyo as an undesirable linking of the creation of
owned reserves to changes in the balance of payments of the reserve
currency countries.

A second, and related, advantage claimed for

the collective reserve unit system is an allegedly greater stability.
In contrast to dollar reserves, which are convertible into gold by
foreign monetary authorities, the proposed unit would not be so con­
vertible but would itself be useable only in rigid relationship with
gold.

One of my associates describes it as "instant gold" or

"alchemist's gold".
The United States has expressed its open-minded willingness to
explore this and other proposals.

But, as Secretary Dillon stated

in Tokyo, we see serious problems in the collective reserve unit
approach.

F i r s t h a n d this is a fundamental point in our view--it

- 14 -

goes against the U. S. belief in a "multilateral framework" for
handling problems of world liquidity.

If a new reserve unit were

to be created it ought to be considered by, and available for the
use of, a broader group of countries than the 10 or 11 leading
industrial nations.
Second, there is a danger that the collective reserve unit
approach, with its rigid link to gold, would be much too restrictive--that is, would provide an inadequate amount of reserves and
would therefore induce countries to restrict trade and domestic
economic activity.
Third, and basic to our approach to discussions of liquidity,
is a healthy scepticism as to whether the needs of the future will
call primarily for an additional reservoir of owned reserves created
to meet supposed global needs, which is the essence of the collective
reserve unit proposal, or whether the real need of the future--so
far as new deliberate action is concerned--may not be, as it is
currently, for an expansion of credit facilities in response to
specific balance of payments requirements, and a greater recognition
of the potentialities of the Fund.

Even if an expansion of owned

reserves in the future becomes necessary it can be accomplished
most appropriately within the framework of the International Monetary
Fund.

The member countries of the IMF are becoming increasingly

aware, as I have indicated, that a new type of reserve asset already
exists in the form of the "gold tranche" positions in the Fund.




- 15 Other alternative proposals that have been put forward for study
also involve adapting the IMF to meet any possible future needs for
additional owned reserves.

Surplus countries might, for example,

be permitted to deposit their own currencies in the Fund and receive
the equivalent of a "gold tranche" drawing right as these funds are
drawn by other countries.

This suffers the obvious drawback of not

assuring in any systematic way the creation of needed amounts or forms
of liquidity.

Another possibility suggested in the IMF report would

involve Fund investment operations, the purchase by the Fund of
assets in order to add to countries1 reserves.

In short, there are

a number of possibilities, all of which need and deserve careful
study, for creating reserve assets by the further development of the
institutional arrangements already established in the International
Monetary Fund.
All of these, and any other, alternative possibilities of
necessity must be scrutinized in the light of such basic questions
as their compatibility with the existing system, their merits as a
contribution to a greater stability of the international monetary
system, their ability to direct liquidity to the point of greatest
legitimate need at any given time, their ability to adapt the volume
of reserves to global needs as opposed to individual shortages, the
acceptability of the claim they offer as a reserve asset, their
effect on relationships among countries and finally, their more
than mechanical problems of the machinery required for controlling
the volume and distribution of reserves so created.




- 16
Crucial to the resolution of the liquidity issue and the orderly
evolution of the world payments system is the further strengthening
of international financial cooperation, already a notable feature of
the progress made in recent years.

There is ample evidence of the

increased international cooperation that we in the United States,
along with our European colleagues, have been experiencing, and bene­
fiting from, during the past several years.

In monthly meetings in

Paris I have seen at first hand the development of a mutual under­
standing of the complex problems facing each of the participating
countries, an understanding that has provided a broader base for
cooperative efforts.

Tangible results are apparent in the agreement

among the Group of Ten to participate in the "General Arrangements
to Borrow", providing a sizeable addition in Fund resources; in the
ad hoc, Basle type, arrangements in which central banks have pro­
vided assistance bilaterally; in our own network of Federal Reserve
swaps and stand-by swap arrangements, now totaling over $2 billion;
in the investment of over $1 billion in Roosa-bonds,

And the most

recent moves toward increased monetary tightness in European
countries were tailored as far as practicable, at least, so as to
avoid, or minimize, any possible disruptive external effects on
other countries.

Again, just last week, the Group of Ten agreed in

Paris to an activation of the GAB so as to provide supplementary
resources to the IMF for use in meeting any drawing by the United
Kingdom under its existing stand-by arrangement with the IMF.







- 17

I speak with conviction of this matter of international
cooperation because I believe that the very process of continuous
confrontation--in Working Party-3 and the Economic Policy Committee
of the OECD, in the G-10 Deputies and Ministers meetings, in the
Basle meetings of central bankers--has been one of the most useful
and constructive recent achievements in the international monetary
area, and portends successful solution of any future liquidity
problems.

Simply to be able to sit down and talk directly and

candidly with our financial official counterparts in the other lead­
ing countries is in itself, in my judgment, a great gain.
As we look ahead to even greater international financial
cooperation, with the formalizing of the new e r monetary techniques
and instruments under the aegis of the "multilateral surveillance"
process, any successful choice of a new reserve asset as a possible
means of adding to liquidity must be forged out of mutual agreement.
And, similarly, without attempting to prejudge the results of the
study of the adjustment process, I am convinced that the minimizing
of future imbalances will also rest upon the achievement of an even
higher degree of international financial cooperation.
This process of mutual interchange of ideas, and mutual efforts
to improve the functioning of the payments system, has benefited
much from the contributions of economists and others outside of
governments.

In conclusion, therefore, I would invite you to

join in the exploratory process in which we are now engaged in
trying to find new solutions to possible liquidity problems.

None

- 18 of us in the United States, or in any other country, should be
fearful of further innovations in international monetary arrangements-as long as those innovations are, as they have been in recent years,
in response to real needs and represent a reasonable, useful, and
natural evolution of the present system, which has served the world
so well.




OFFICIAL RESERVES AND CREDIT FACILITIES
fin millions of dollars!

IMP Gold
Tranche
Positions

Gold

foreign
Exchange

December 1958

3^,030

19,3U0

2,560

0

June I 96U

li0 ,U80

25,2UO

3,890

950

+ 2,550

+ 6,100

+ 1,330

+ 950

Sources:




Roosa-bonds and Federal Reserve Swaps:
Jthe'rs:

Roosa-bonds

Federal
Reserve
Swaps

0

li'fF Credit

Tranche
Positions

Total

7,290

67,220

2,050

1 U ,120

86,730

+ 2,050

+ 6,830

+ 19,510

Federal Reserve Bulletin

International Financial Statistics, October 196U, pages 16-19 (all figures rounded
to nearest 10 million)