View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For re 1eaiseon del ivery
Expectedi0:00




a .H.

e Td .t .

Statement by
J. Charles Partee
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Subcommittee on Financial Institutions
Supervision, Regulation and Insurance
of the
Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs
U. S. House of Representatives
May 15, 1979

I am pleased to appear today on behalf of the Federal
Reserve Board to discuss H.R. 3864, the Consumer Checking Account
Equity Act of 1979.

I understand that the bill was introduced in

response to the recent ruling by the U.S. Court of Appeals for
the District of Columbia that automatic transfers from savings
accounts, credit union share drafts, and savings and loan association
remote service units will not be authorized by law after January 1,
1980. While the legal demise of these accounts is not yet certain,
since the affected regulatory agencies are planning to appeal the
decision, the Board believes that now is an opportune time for the
Congress to reconsider the issue to see whether agreement can be
reached on a more rational system permitting consumers to obtain
interest on their transactions balances.
The Federal Reserve Board for some time has supported the
principle of interest payments on transactions balances at all
depository institutions.

Our support of this principle is based

on considerations both of economic equity and efficiency. Corporate
depositors as well as some informed smaller depositors already
eern something approaching market rates of return on their trans­
actions balances through the implicit receipt of Interest in the
form of banking services provided at little or no charge.
Alternatively, sophisticated depositors are able to minimize
their holdings of non-interest bearing deposits by placing their
funds in overnight investments that can readily be mobilized for
transactions purposes.

It is only fair that smaller, less sophis­

ticated depositors have similar opportunities.




In addition, since

-2-

the prohibition against explicit interest payments on transactions
balances has led banks to compete on the basis of checking and
other services at low or no cost, deposit customers are encouraged to make
a

greater

use of such services than would be the case if they

were explicitly priced.
The payment of interest on transactions accounts would
encourage financial institutions to compete for deposits directly
and to charge for their services on the basis of costs incurred.
Most members of the public would likely be better off in an
environment in which all depository institutions offered explicit
interest on transactions balances--consumers would have a more
rational basis for choosing among financial services; they would
probably receive higher effective interest returns on their funds
due both to increased competition for transactions balances among
financial institutions and to increased efficiency in the financial
sector; and deposit customers would have less need to spend time
and money attempting to minimize their holdings of non-êarning
transactions balances.
The Board, however, would urge a more gradual and, we
believe, less disruptive approach than that contained in H.R. 3864.
Given our lack of knowledge about the transitional problems, it
seems important that the removal of the prohibition should be
accomplished gradually, by extending an activity with which
experience has already been gained.

I am referring to nation­

wide NOW accounts which could be implemented by legislation
similar to the NOW proposal passed by the Senate Banking Committee
in 1977 as part of S. 2055.

Specifically, the Board favors nation­

wide NOW accounts, authorized for all depository institutions, but



limited Initially to individuals and nonprofit institutions.

Such

accounts should be subject to deposit rate ceilings, equal among
the institutions, during a transitional period.

And the Board

strongly believes that all nationwioe NOW accounts must be subject
to reserve requirements, both because of the Importance of the
reserve requirement mechanism for the efficient conduct of monetary
policy and in the interests of institutional equity.
A major virtue of this alternative approach is that it
would moderate the transitional impact on commercial bank and
thrift institution earnings that is likely to result from
competition for market shares when a new interest-bearing trans­
action account is first introduced.

That the transitional effect

on earnings can be significant is evidenced by our experience with
NOW accounts.

In the early years of NOW's in New England the

combination of celling interest rates or. deposit balances and no
or low service charges for NOW drafts was much more costly to
depository institutions than could be justified in the long run.
Over time, the New England institutions increasingly came to link
explicit interest on transaction accounts with explicit charges
for checking and other services rendered.

Minimum balance require­

ments were developed, and service charges began to approximate
true costs.

Experience gained in the two original NOW states was

used to advantage in those states that later received NOW account
authority.

Thus, we would expect that institutions in the other

43 states, when given NOW authority, would also be able to build
upon this experience in designing their service packages.




As a

-4-

result, an effective implementation date of January 1, 1980,
probably would provide institutions with a sufficient planning
horizon, if the enabling legislation proceeds promptly.
Nevertheless, Board staff analysis suggests that, without
a deposit rate celling coordinated by the agencies, the actual
cost of NOW account funds to the institutions might rise temporarily
by several percentage points above the long run sustainable rate
in those states gaining NOW powers for the first time.

Our staff

estimates that, in the absence of such regulation, pre-tax earnings
of all commercial banks during the worst year of the transition
period could be expected to be between 5 and 7 per cent lower than
otherwise.

While such earnings reductions would not pose problems

for the vast majority of commercial banks, they would be trouble­
some for individual institutions that have unusual concentrations
of consumer accounts or that may already be experiencing an
earnings squeeze.

Thrifts could be expected to compete vigorously

with the banks for interest-bearing transactions accounts and such
competition could be quite costly to them, since for most this
would constitute a new service line.

The earnings of thrifts

already are being squeezed by the currently high cost of their
liabilities, especially money market certificates, and by the
limited flexibility of the yields they can earn on their long­
term portfolios of fixed-rate mortgages.
Thus, the Board is quite concerned about the transitional
impact of interest on transactions accounts and we believe there
are several reasons why pur proposal would have a much smaller




-5-

short-run impact on the earnings of financial intermediaries than
would the program contained in H.R. 3864.

First, the approach we

suggest would contain specific and clear authority for the
coordinated imposition of a ceiling rate on transaction balances,
to be followed by -an orderly phasing out of that ceiling over a
period of time.

Second, nationwide NOW accounts for individuals

and nonprofit organizations would be a logical extension of
existing programs in New England and New York.

Depository

institutions in other states could use the experience of existing
NOW institutions to avoid pitfalls in designing and implementing
their own NOW packages.

Third, limiting interest payments to

individuals and nonprofit organizations woüld reduce the exposure
of financial, instutitions to earnings drains while still providing
interest relief to those groups »east able to obtain direct returns
on their transaction balances by other means.

Finally, the basic

characteristics of a NOW account are consistent with the powers of
all depository institutions, since t**<?y can be regarded as a form
of savings account.

They thus may be less costly to develop for

thrifts, which are familiar with the structure and administration
of savings accounts.

Also, State authorities may find that permitting

thrift depositors to write drafts against savings deposits would be
less difficult to implement than obtaining demand deposit powers
for State-chartered thrift institutions.
Once the short-run impact of interest on transactions
accounts has been absorbed by the financial system, the categories
of depositors eligible for NOW's could be broadened and the ceiling




-6-

rate phased out.

However, the longer-run effects of major

Institutional changes are always uncertain and the Board believes
that such liberalization should be considered only after experience
1s gained with a more cautious program--a program that has sub­
stantial benefits for consumers, encourages efficiency and competition
in the financial sector, maintains the safety and soundness of the
financial system, allows for revision over time, and protects the
Federal Reserve's ability to regulate the money supply.
With the Board's general perference for NOW's as background,
I would like to discuss briefly some specific concerns the Board
has with H.R. 3864.
First, the legislation proposes that the level of reserve
ratios for transactions accounts at covered savings and loan
associations be set by the Federal Home Loan Bank Board and that
reserve ratios for covered credit unions be set by the National
Credit Union Board.

Although these agencies would be required to

consult with the Federal Reserve Board in setting reserve require­
ments, it is clear that the decision would rest solely with those
agencies.

However, the setting of reserve ratios on transactions

balances— that 1s, the setting of reserve ratios on money— is an
integral tool of monetary policy.

Such power ought properly to be the

province of the nation's central bank.
Second, the proposed legislation would require savings and
loan members of the Federal Home Loan Bank System to hold reserves
in the form of currency and coin, or in deposits at their respective
Home Loan Bank; the form and place of reserves held by Federallychartered credit unions would be specified by the National Credit




-7-

Union Board.

Again, to exercise control over transactions balances,

the central bank must have control over the total amount of
reserves supporting these balances.

The reserve accounting could

conceivably be handled by--and the necessary reserve deposits passed
through from— the primary regulatory agencies.

But unless required

réserves are held only in vault cash or in balances at Federal
Reserve Banks, the Federal Reserve's ability to control reserve
availability is compromised.
Apart from the monetary policy implications of the treatment
of reserve requirements under H.R. 3864, the bill could lead to a
worsening of the competitive imbalances that already exist among
our various financial institutionsand could lead to operational
difficulties as well.

For example, if the agencies were to set

reserve ratios for S&L's and credit unions lower than those imposed
on transactions accounts at member commercial banks, member banks
would be placed at a disadvantage to thrifts--as they are now to
non-member banks--in competing for checking-type funds.

Also,

unless thrifts' reserve balances are credited to their accounts
at the Federal Reserve Banks, such funds could not be used as
clearing balances for purposes of settling checks passed through
the Federal Reserve payments system.

The clearing mechanism is a

vital part of our monetary system, and should be accessible to all
kinds of transactions accounts on equal terms and conditions.
In addition, the reserve requirement provisions contained
in H.R. 3864 seem inequitable and deficient with respect to the classes
of depository institutions that would be subject to required reserves




-8-

and the types of deposit account that would be subject to reserves.
According to our reading of the bill, four classes of instltutions-insured non-member commercial banks, insured mutual savings banks,
State'chartered credit unions, and State-chartered savings and loan
associations that are not members of the Federal Home Loan Bank
System--would not be subject to any reserve requirements under the
bill.

Further, it would appear that financial institutions (except

for Federal Reserve members) would be required only to maintain
reserves against demand deposits, but not against NOW's.

Obviously,

if reserves are not required to be maintained against NOW accounts,
thrifts would avoid offering interest-bearing demand deposit accounts,
but instead would gain a competitive advantage over member banks by
offering reserve-free NOW's.
The ambiguities and exclusions in the treatment of reserves
under H.R. 3864 not only would complicate the conduct of monetary
policy and lead to competitive inequities, but also might encourage
unnecessary and disruptive switching of charters by savings and
loan associations and credit unions in order to avoid reserve
requirements.

Indeed, as you know, the non-universality of reserve

requirements for banks has created substantial competitive problems
within the commercial banking industry; H.R. 3864 would likely
extend these difficulties to thrift Institutions.
I would like to turn now to a final point that I hope will
demonstrate the complexity of this area as well as underscore the
Board's strong belief that Interest on transactions balances should
be coupled

with a solution to the membership problem.

earlier, the payment of interest
exert downward pressure on bank

As I noted

transactions accounts would
earnings.

This would make member

banks even more aware of the costs of membership and, in all




-9-

likeTihood, serve to accelerate the rate of membership attrition.
Here» again» our experience with NOW accounts in New England is
1nstruct1ve--the introduction of NOW accounts there placed
particular pressure on bank earnings, and membership withdrawals
in that region increased sharply.
But even if all institutions were required to hold equal
reserves with the System against interest-bearing transactions
balances, the membership problem might still be exacerbated.

The

question would arise as to whether, and to what extent, non-members
holding reserves with the System should be allowed access to
Federal Reserve services such as check clearing, wire transfer,
and use of the discount window.

If non-members were given access

to System services, they would be subject to a substantially lower
reserve requirement burden than members--because non-transactions
accounts would not be reserved--but would have access to valuable
rights and privileges of membership.

As a result, withdrawals of

member banks to "non-member service" status would be vastly
encouraged.
Thus» while the Board continues to endorse the general
principle of Interest on transactions balances, we could not
support such a program unless steps are taken to halt member bank
attrition and reverse the declining proportion of deposits subject
to reserve requirements administered by the Federal Reserve.

The

provisions of H.R. 3864, or even our preferred alternative of
extending NOW's nationwide, would accelerate withdrawals by
Federal Reserve members and would, therefore, undermine the ability




-10-

of the central bank to conduct monetary policy effectively and to
continue to backstop the liquidity of our banking system.

The

concerns of the Board now are even more pressing than in June of
1977 when former Chairman Burns stated before the Senate Banking
Committee:

"We could not support nationwide extension of NOW

account authority if that extension were not coupled with action
to lighten the burden of Federal Reserve membership.

The risk

to the safety and soundness of our banking system of enacting the
first part of the package without the second would, in the Board's
judgment, be Intolerably large.“




# # # # # # # # # # #