View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
Expected 10:00 A.M. E.S.T.

Statement by
J. Charles Partee
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System




before the
Commerce, Consumer and Monetary Affairs
Subcommittee
of the
Committee on Government Operations
House of Representatives
March 22, 1979

I am pleased to testify this morning on behalf of the
Federal Reserve Board concerning the administration of deposit
rate ceilings and their effects on the rate of return available
to small savers.

It has been nearly 13 years since Congress

mandated the establishment of a coordinated set of deposit rate
ceilings by the Federal financial regulatory agencies.

Most

economists believe that these ceilings are anticompetitive—
amounting to price-fixing for the depositary 1nstitut1ons--and
that they have a particularly Inequitable Impact.on the small
saver.

Moreover, though deposit rate ceilings may successfully

restrict competition among déposltary Institutions, when Interest
rates are high they cannot protect the institutions as a group
from exposure to loss of a significant amount of savings business
to open market instruments attractive to the small saver.
Even though market developments are rapidly undermining
the efficacy of deposit rate celling regulations, many of the
factors that caused the Congress to establish the framework for
such regulations in 1966 are still at work.

Savings and loan

associations and mutual savings banks, because of constraints on
the kinds of assets they hold, are still unable to pay marketoriented rates of return oh all deposit liabilities during periods
of high Interest rates.

Before the thrift Institutions can pay

such rates, without jeopardizing the financial solvency and
stability of individual Institutions, reform of their asset powers
will be necessary.

Nevertheless, the Board believes It Important

to make progress whenever possible to restore rate flexibility to
the institutional deposit




structure, and toward this end it has

-

2-

favored a phase-out of rate celling

regulations over some

reasonable period— say 5 years or so.
In considering the actions that can be taken by the
Federal financial regulators to move toward a less constrained
deposit celling rate structure* I believe It is necessary to
understand the. Institutional and legislative framework 1n which
the current structure was originally established.

Developments

over the past 13 years underscore the complexity of the conflicting
Issues surrounding Regulation Q-type ceilings, which Include not
only equity for the small saver, but also the adequacy of mortgage
credit flows, competitive balance among various types of depositary
institutions, and the financial strength and viability of some
Institutions.

The financial regulatory agencies have been forced,

both by law and economic necessity, to attempt to balance these
conflicting goals, and hence have been required to make trade-offs.
In m1d-1966, as interest rates rose sharply, many thrift
institutions faced sizable deposit outflows for the first time In
the postwar period, as consumers shifted their savings to higheryielding market Investments and commercial bank accounts.

Savings

and loan associations and mutual savings banks thus faced the
difficult task of trying to meet the competition in deposit markets
while their earnings were constrained by portfolios of long-term,
slowly amortizing mortgate assets

that,

on average, provided a

net return not much higher than the rates paid on deposits at some
commercial banks.

Commercial banks were not so hampered because

their portfolios were diversified, with an average maturity
considerably shorter than that of thrift assets.




The rates of

return on commercial bank portfolios were thus more responsive
to market yields and gave them greater flexibility to pay
competitive rates on deposits.

With the slackening 1n deposit

flows at thrifts* residential mortgage lending was sharply
curtailed at these Institutions, and some savings and loan
associations and mutual savings banks faced the spectre of
outflows that they could not readily meet.

It was in this

environment that the Congress enacted Interest rate control
legislation (P.L. 89-597) In the fall of 1966, authorizing the
financial regulatory agencies to establish an interrelated
structure of deposit rate ceilings.
Commercial bank earnings were not then--nor are they nowlimiting factor in the regulators' ability to set maximum rates
payable on deposits.

Thus, establishing the Initial schedule of

deposit rate ceilings in 1966, the financial regulatory agencies
attempted to determine the maximum rates that thrift Institutions
could effort to pay, given their portfolio returns.
thrift institution callings.

This set the

The maximum rates payable by

commercial banks were then established at levels up to one
percentage point below the thrift deposit ceilings.

This was

intended to give savings and loan associations and mutual savings
banks a premium or differential to help offset their competitive
disadvantage vis-a-vis commercial bar»ks--a disadvantage that
resulted, in part, from their Inability to offer a full range
of deposit and lending services to their predominantly consumer
customers.




-4-

At the tin'.': of enactment, deposit rate control legislation
was viewed as a temporary but necessary measure to protect the
short-run viability of the thrift industry and to encourage an
adequate flow of credit to the mortgage market.

In this spirit,

both the Initial legislation and subsequent renewals have been of
short duration, never more than two years.

Thus, every Congress

since 1966 has reconsidered deposit rate ceilings, as will this
Congress when the present authority expires at the end of 1980.
Since 1966, the celling rate structure has been revised
a number of times.

Generally, such action was precipitated by

periods.of disintermediation when market interest rates rose well
above the deposit rate ceilings.

The pressure of higher market

yields required upward adjustments In celling rates 1f the
institutions were to be able to compete for deposits and sustain
the flow of residential mortgage credit.
These upward adjustments followed periods during which
thrift institution earnings had strengthened again, reflecting 1n
large measure the Increasing average return on assets as portfolios
turned over and higher-yielding mortgages were acquired.

The

resultant Improvement In the financial condition of thrifts
permitted the regulatory agencies to Increase deposit rate
ceilings; however, thrift earnings remained a constraint on the
magnitude of ceiling rate adjustments.

Even though the individual

Increases In maximum rates payable on deposits were moderate, they
were followed by significant reductions in the profitability of
savings and loan associations and mutual savings banks.




And,

-5-

because the ceiling adjustments were moderate, growth of deposits
subject to rate ceilings remained depressed as long as the yield
on alternative market Instruments continued high.
Changes in regulatory ceilings have taken two forms.
Celling rates on existing account categories have been Increased,
and new deposit instruments have been Introduced.

Of these actions,

new deposit instruments have been by far the most Important.

In

1970, 1973, 1974, and 1978 the Federal regulatory agencies introduced
new

longer-term time certificates with relatively modest minimum

denominations, in each instance at ceiling rates above those
prevailing on existing accounts. This approach limited the cost
Impact of ceiling rate Increases.

The higher rate on the new

certificates was paid only to those depositors willing to give up
some liquidity for additional yield.

Cost Increases occurred only

as such deposits expanded, In contrast to passbook ceiling rate
Increases, which would apply to both new and existing accounts.
The 1973 increase In the maximum rate payable on passbook accounts,
for example, led to a sharp reduction in thrift earnings with
little increase 1n deposit growth.

Thus, the desire of small

savers for a short-term deposit instrument paying market-oriented
rates of return conflicts with the necessity to permit the
Institutions to maintain and attract deposits in an environment
of high and rising market rates, without putting undue pressure
on earnings.
The Introduction of successively longer-term certificates
has dramatically changed the maturity structure of thrift Institution
deposit liabilities.




When rate ceilings went Into effect in 1966,

-6-

85 to 90 per cent of thrift deposits were in passbook form.
By mid-1978, only one-third to one-half of total deposits out­
standing were in passbook accounts.

Since savings and loan

associations and mutual savings banks hold predominantly
long-term assets, this maturity lengthening has been desirable.
Substantial early withdrawal penalties have helped ensure the
stability of these longer-term deposits in subsequent periods
of rising rates, blunting potential disintermediation.
Since ceilings on thrift institution accounts were first
imposed, there has been only one brief period in which small
savers were able to earn a market-determined rate of return on a
deposit instrument.

In July 1973, the regulatory agencies suspended

ceilings on 4-year time deposits with denominations of $1,000 or
more.

Reflecting grave doubts about the ability of thrifts to

meet such market competition without severe financial difficulties,
the Congress within three months passed a resolution terminating
the experiment and mandating the reimposition of ceiling rates on
any time account of less than $100,000.

At the end of 1975, in

order to protect thrift institutions against the possibility of
other regulatory actions that might unduly threaten their competitive
position, Congress enacted legislation (P.L. 94-200) prohibiting
the financial regulatory agencies from reducing ceiling rate
differentials on all account categories in existence at that time
without the approval of both Houses of Congress.

Both of these

Congressional actions made it abundantly clear that protection of




-7-

thrift institutions and concern for the mortgage market were
still the dominant factors to be considered 1n determining the
structure of ceiling rates.
Meanwhile, the small saver has become increasingly
aware of alternative Investments that pay returns well in excess
of deposit rate ceilings when market yields are high.

The public

has learned the relative ease with which market securities-particularly Treasury and agency issues--can be purchased.
Moreover, innovative instruments have developed to attract the
deposits of the small saver, such as money market mutual funds
and unit investment trusts.

Shares in these funds are ordinarily

quite liquid, bear market rates of return, and are often available
in minimum denominations ,of $1 ,000 or less.

In the last six nonths,

such mutual funds have attracted over $9.5 billion, and it
is a reasonable presumption that a sizable share of this
flow might have gone to or remained in depositary institutions
if deposit rate ceilings had been more competitive.
In late 1977 and early 1978, deposit inflows began to
slacken as market rates of interest moved above regulatory ceilings.
Recognizing the threat of increasing disintermediation arising
from the growing public awareness of deposit alternatives, the
financial regulatory agencies on June 1, 1978 introduced the
6-month money market certificate.

This instrument represented

a significant change in the rate ceiling structure, providing
institutions with a short-term instrument whose ceiling varied
with market rates.




The thrift institutions were thereby able

-8-

to compete fpr funds during high interest rate periods and thus
to sustain residential mortgage credit flows at relatively high
levels.
A minimum denomination of $10,000 was established on the
money market certificate--the same as is required on 6-month
Treasury bills to which the rate ceiling is tied--since it was
considered that depositors with relatively large amounts at stake
would be the ones most likely to shift into open-market instruments.
The new certificate has proven to be extraordinarily popular,
providing many savers with their first investment bearing a
market-determined rate of return.

But this new instrument also

has been a very costly source of funds for the institutions.
Even with the $10,000 minimum denomination, the Board staff
estimates that about half of the $116 billion of money market
certificates outstanding at the end of February represented funds
that would otherwise have remained In lower-cost passbook or
fixed-celling time accounts.

Indeed, the developing earnings

pressure on savings and loan associations and mutual savings banks
was a major motive underlying the recent regulatory action to
reduce somewhat the celling rates paid on money market certificates.
This was only the second time since 1966 that the regulatory
authorities have reduced the celling rate on an account category,
the first occurring In 1973 when Congress mandated an end to the
"wild card" experiment.
Lowering the minimum d»no<ijiatai^pn on the money market
certificate or taking any othe^\i£t£o*i,‘tp provide more attractive
deposit Instruments to the saver^^.ttii^Pess then $10,000, of




-9-

course, would serve to heighten the earnings pressure on thrifts.
After 13 years of deposit rate ceilings, the same set of problems
prevailing in 1966 still constrain the options available to the
regulators to increase rates of return paid to small savers.
The earnings of thrift Institutions are already being squeezed
by their effort to compete for funds in a high interest rate
period.

Even though the average return on mortgage portfolios

at thrifts is more than 2-1/2 percentage points higher than in
1966, inflation-induced increases in market rates have amounted
to over 3-1/2 percentage points in short-term markets and about
4 percentage points in intermediate-term markets over the same
period.

And, with small savers' increased awareness of alternative

market Instruments, the potential threat of disintermediation is
even greater today than when celling rates were first introduced.
Consumer groups and some members of Congress have correctly
argued that the existing ceiling rate structure has placed the
small saver at an increasing disadvantage.

Growing sentiment for

relief for the small saver has been voiced simultaneously with
mounting pressure by thrifts to curb the rising cost of their
deposit funds and concern that increasing deposit costs would be
reflected in higher mortgage rates.

Not only the consideration of

equity for the small saver, but also the growing threat of dis­
intermediation, indicates to us that some regulatory action is
becomming imperative.

A wide range of suggestions have been made

to give the consumer more attractive deposit instruments.

For

example, some have suggested a reduction in the minimum denomination




-10-

on the money market certificate, perhaps with a ceiling rate
that floats at some fixed differential below the 6-month Treasury
bill rate.

Another alternative might be to introduce a small-

denomination long-term certificate whose ceiling either floats
with longer-term market rates, or is fixed a reasonably competitive
level.

Chairman Reuss of the House Banking Committee has recently

suggested a small-denomlnation savings instrument, with attractive
liquidity characteristics, whose maximum return to the saver would
rise the longer it Is held.
I want to assure you that the regulatory agencies in
recent weeks have been analyzing and evaluating a large number
of such alternatives In an effort to develop a more attractive
deposit Instrument for the small saver, without putting undue
pressure on thrift Institution

earnings.

It is the Board's

hope that constructive action in this area can soon be taken.
The Chairman of this Subcommittee, in his letter Inviting
the Board to testify, asked what unilateral actions the Federal
Reserve could legally take to give small savers a more nearly
market-determined rate of return on their savings.

The Board,

after consultation with the other regulatory agencies, has the
authority to create new deposit categories for member banks--bearing
any deposit rate ceiling believed to be 1n the public interest-where unique characteristics or conditions exist.

In 1977, the

Board used such authority to create the new IRA/Keogh time
deposit to accommodate the Congressional objective in the Employee
Retirement Income Security Act of 1974.

I am also advised that,

after consultation, the Board could raise the ceiling rate for




-11-

member banks on any deposit category created since the 1975
enactment of P.L. 94-200, or reduce the minimum denomination on any
member bank account category.
certificate.

This would include the money market

While the Board thus could take action on its own

to create an attractive instrument for member banks to offer
to the small saver, we are aware that such unilateral action
would risk shifts of funds from thrift institutions, thereby
threatening the flow of mortgage credit.
Regardless of what actions the regulatory agencies
may take in the period just ahead, the asset characteristics of
savings and loan associations and mutual savings banks will still
constrain their ability to pay substantially higher rates on
deposits without seriously threatening the viability of some
institutions.

When inflationary pressures moderate, and market

Interest rates decline, thrifts will be 1n a much better position
to compete.

Over the longer run, however, any depositary Institution

that specializes in fixed-rate mortgages is likely to remain vulnerable
to the pressures of disintermediation, which include the risks of
illiquidity, insolvency, and possible forced merger.

As I have

noted, these risks are being heightened by financial Innovations
facilitating the acquisition by small savers of nondeposit
instruments bearing market rates of return.
In the Board's view, these problems can be eliminated
only if the Congress acts to liberalize the asset powers of thrift
Institutions.

Increasingly in recent years, banks and other

financial Intermediaries have Insisted that their long-term loan
contracts include provisions for rate adjustments keyed to some




-12-

index of market rates.

This stance reflects their desire to

avoid the risks associated with extending fixed-rate long-term
credit when their cost of funds fluctuates.
prohibit most savings

Restrictions

and loan associations and mutual savings

banks from offering variable-rate mortgages.

The Board believes

that Congressional authorization of nationwide VRMs, with
provisions to assure that the mortgage rate varies with market
rates in such a way as to protect consumer interests, would allow
thrift and other institutions to build up asset portfolios providing
earnings more flexibly attuned to market developments.

Over time,

this would eliminate the major constraint facing the financial reg­
ulatory agencies in providing more equitable returns to all savers.
In addition, the Board recommends that the Congress
consider exempting Federally insured depositary institutions
from anachronistic State usury ceilings on residential mortgage
rates in view of the compelling circumstances which currently
prevail.

In 14 States, usury ceilings are currently below

free-merket mortgage yields.

If our institutional lenders are

restricted from earning market rates of return on assets, then
they cannot be expected lo pay market rates of return on deposit
liabilities.

This is the fundamental problem that Impedes progress

toward unconstrained institutional competition for small-depositor
funds — an outcome that the Board has long supported and continues
to seek.




# # # # # # # # # # # # #

Appendix Table

Maximum Sates Payable on Sma11-Denomination Deposits
at Federally Insured Depositary Institutions
September 1966 - March 1979
(in percent per annum)

Type of deposit

Sept. 26,
1966

Jan. 21,
1970

Effective date-iJ
July 1, Nov. 1,
1973
1973

Dec. 23,
1974

June 1,
1978

Commercial banks

e , 2/
Savings—

4

4%

3/
Money market certificates—
4/5/
Other time deposits— —

wmwm

90 days - 1 year
1 - 2 years
2 - 2 % years
2% - 4 years
4 - 6 years
6 - 8 years
8 years or more

5
5%
5$

*

5%

5%

5%

5%

6

6

6

6

6%

6%

6%

**

7k

6%
7k
7%
7%

}

} 7%

Thrift institutions— ^
Savings
Savings and loan assoc.
Mutual savings banks

41

5%

5

«ff

&

Money market certificates—3/
4/5/
Other time deposits— —
90 days - 1 year
1 - 2 years
2 - 2 % years
2% - 4 years
4 - 6 years
6 - 8 years
8 years or more
*

*

]

5%
5%
4|-5%£/

}

See following page for details

Detailed notes appears on the following page.




6%

61

61

**

7%

}

Ceiling varies weekly with the 6-month Treasury bill rate.

** No ceiling.

5%
6%

5%

51
6%

} n

5%
6%
6%
7%
7%
8

See following page for details.

i

NOIES
*

From June 1, 1978, through March 14, 1979, thé ceiling rate on money
market certificates at comnercial banks was the discount rate on the
most recently issued. 6-month U.S. Treasury bills (auction average), and
the ceiling rate for thrift institutions was 1/4 percentage point higher.
Effective March 15, 1979, the compounding of interest on money market
certificates was prohibited, and the ceiling rate for thrift institutions
was set equal to the'discount râte on 6-month bills whenever this rate
is 9 percent or more. Thrift institutions may pay 9 percent on money
market certificates when the 6-month bill rate is between 8-3/4 percent
and 9 percent, and they may pay 1/4 percentage point more than the bill
rate whenever the bill rate is 8% percent or less.

**

No ceiling applied to deposits of $1,000 or more with maturities of 4
years or more during the period indicated, as long as the amount of such
deposits at an individual institution did not exceed 5 percent of its
total time and savings deposits. Certificates not meeting these
requirements were subject to the ceilings prevailing on shorter-term
time deposits.

1/

Effective dates vary slightly in some instances for different types of
institutions. .The dates shown are for commercial banks.

2/

The same ceilings applied to time deposits with maturities of 30 to 89
days at commercial banks throughout the period shown. There is no
separate 30- to 89-day account category for thrift institutions.

3/ Must have a maturity of exactly 26 weeks and a minimum denomination of
$10,000, and must be nonnegotiable.
4/ Minimum denomination requirements vary over time and among types of
institutions. At present, a minimum denomination of $1,000 is required
on certificates of deposit with maturities of 4 years or more at all
institutions in order to qualify for the ceiling rates indicated.
In addition, savings and loan associations must require a minimum of
$1,000 on all deposits with maturities of 1 year or more, except in
areas where mutual savings banks are permitted lower minimum denomin­
ations. These requirements do not apply to deposits representing funds
contributed to an Individual Retirement Account (IRA) or to a Keogh
(H.R. 10) Plan.
5/

Interest rate ceilings on time deposits of governmental units and ceilings
on deposits representing funds contributed to an Individual Retirement
Account (IRA) or to a Keogh (H.R. 10) Plan are not shown separately.
Effective November 27, 1974, governmental units could receive interest
rates on time deposits with denominations under $100,000 as high as the
maximum rate permitted on any such fixed-ceiling deposit at any Federally
insured depositary institution, regardless of maturity (currently
6 percent). Effective July 6, 1977, the same rule was adopted for IRA
and Keogh deposits with maturities of 3 years or more.

6/

Savings and loan associations and mutual savings banks only.




Notes (contd.)

Five percent for negotiable order of withdrawal (NOW) accounts effective
January 1, 1974. This is the same ceiling in effect on such accounts
at commercial banks, and applies only to institutions with home offices
in New England States and New York State.
Savings and loan associations were permitted to pay 4% percent on 90-day
notice accounts and 5% percent on accounts with maturities of 6 months or
more. A 5 percent ceiling for MSBs applied to all accounts with maturities
of 90 days or more.