View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release at 7 p.m.,
Eastern Standard Time
Wednesday, March 13, 1963




The Three Faces of Economic Policy
Remarks of George W. Mitchell
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Bankers Club of Chicago
Chicago, Illinois
March 13, 1963

The Three Faces of Economic Policy
I was once persuaded to attend a lecture by a surrealist
painter because of the particularly provocative title he had
selected for his remarkst My anticipations were abruptly chilled
when at the very outset of his speech he opined that he had found,
in this case, it was much easier to think of an intriguing title
than of a speech that would match it.
I have had somewhat the same feeling toward this 3peech
tonight,

I am obviously under more compulsion to sensibly connect

the title and the speech than a surrealist painter, who might be
expected to be

influenced by the esoteric and obscure titles often

used for surrealist paintings.

But while the title gave me trouble

in constructing my remarks so they might be responsive to your advance
impressions, it was not intended to be facetious or obscure.

Thus in

referring to economic policy as having three faces 1 did not intend
to use the phrase as a graduated form of the epithet "two-faced."
Nor did I intend to introduce you to anything more abstruse than
a classification of economic policies which 1 hope might be helpf:.ti
in thinking about our economic problems and the programs advocated
to deal with them.

The three-way classification which I propose to

use groups policies under these headings: monetary, fiscal, and
structural.

In order to avoid the impersonality of classifying

ideas I will often personalize these categories and refer to th~E>
by the names of their protagonists -- the monetarist, the fiscalist,
and the structuralist.

I think you will recognize the advantages

of this form of Identification.




-2The first problem to be cleared away is why,

in an economy

based on private enterprise, I should be directing your attention to
economic policy alternatives for government.

With what we call

economic freedom goes the prerogative to pursue individually selected
economic actions and policies.

Individuals make their own decisions

regarding an occupation; businessmen make their own decisions
regarding what and how they will produce and what prices they will
charge; consumers exercise free choice regarding the use of their
incomes.

Generally speaking, it is the free play of the competitive

price system which directs resources to uses that will be most
productive for the economy as a whole.
Despite all of this, government has positive economic
functions and a pervasive influence on the environment in which the
private economy operates.

The most obvious evidence of this fact is

that government spends, and therefore taxes, and the private enter­
prise system can hardly escape the effects of both operations.

It

is mainly the size of government spending that gives rise to economic
policy issues and this is a characteristic of modern government likely
to be with us indefinitely.

Even if government did nothing more than

operate the defense establishment, the public schools, the public
highways, and police and fire departments it would be very, very big.
And this bigness, combined with the possible differences in the timing
of government capital outlays and the practicable alternatives among
deficit financing, pay as you go, or pay before you go, makes for a
considerable effect on the private economy.

An aggregative effect,

moreover, which can be subjected to economic policy objectives.




-3-

I might add that the continuing American preference for
the private enterprise system has meant that even in those areas
where we have chosen to have government (Federal or State or local)
supply services, we are not in any significant sense a socialist
economy.

Socialism as usually defined involves government ownership

of the means of production.

Yet our government, in supplying

services, purchases and utilizes materials and equipment produced
by privately-owned firms.
A second activity of government that involves economic
policies is its role as a regulator, reflecting the social conscience.
This function stems from a recognition that the private market system
does not always operate in the public interest but may, if unregulated,
involve abusive exercise of economic power.

Thus government regulates

the prices and services of natural monopolies such as public utilities;
it pursues antitrust activities; regulates entry and merger of
financial institutions, establishes minimum wages, subsidizes
industries before their prime and after their prime, and so on.
In these activities, government affects the working of the free
market system.
The third economic function of government is its
responsibility to provide a sound, adequate money system.

Before

this audience, there is no need for a detailed exposition of how
this is done today.

You are all familiar with the process by

which the Federal Reserve, in adding to, or absorbing, bank
reserves, has an influence on the credit-granting and depositcreating activities of commercial banks.




You know how, when it

-4wants to encourage economic expansion, the Federal Reserve relies
on your profit-seeking propensities for a leading edge as it
manufactures money out of I.O.U's or securities, and how it depends
on your judgment of individual creditworthiness to ration credit
when it wants to restrain the growth in economy.

And, you are even

more aware of how this chain of action and reaction, in turn, affects
interest rates, credit conditions, and the money supply and, ultimately,
aggregate spending in the economy.

The need for monetary policy is

vividly expressed in the statement that "money does not manage itself."
Our history of financial panics and price instability in the century
and a half before the establishment of the Federal Reserve System
provides ample support for such a statement.
So much, very briefly, for reasons why we are, even in a
free enterprise system, inevitably, continuingly, and deeply concerned
with the formulation of national economic policies.
The major issues of economic policy are semi-permanent or
at least recurring.

In recent years we have been most anxious to

find a method of reducing unemployment, of achieving a higher rate
of economic growth, of reaching a balance in our international
payments.

Not so many years ago we were trying to curb inflation

while rebuilding and upgrading our stock of factories, homes,
consumer hard goods, and community facilities.
the problem was deep depression.

In the Thirties

In the Twenties it was maintaining

prosperity, concern for European economic restoration, and what to
do about a wild credit-financed boom in the stock market.




For all

-5-

of these problems the monetarist, the fiscalist, and the structuralist
have answers or comments -- some positive, some negative.

But

running through the prescriptions advanced in particular cases
there is a line of cleavage between the structuralist and the other
two which is noteworthy.
Management of money--and its balance sheet counterpart,
bank credit— is concerned with the total supply of money and credit.
By its nature, monetary policy does not aim at influencing one
sector of the economy more than another.

Everyone uses money and

most of us use credit.
It is true that some types of expenditures— those that
are heavily financed by long-term borrowing— are especially sensitive
to changes in credit conditions.

But as monetary measures affect

these types of activity, the secondary effects spread throughout
the economy.

In any case, the greater impact

of monetary policy

on some types of activities results from the characteristics of
those activities rather than from the nature of monetary policy.
General monetary policy cannot be aimed at a single target while
other targets are exempted from its impact.

When we have had

reason to direct monetary or credit measures exclusively at
individual areas, we have had to develop special-purpose instruments,
such as regulation of margin requirements in the case of stock
market credit, and this type of approach, as I note later, comes
under the heading of structural policies.




-6Just as money cannot manage itself, a budget will not
manage itself, especially when it has become large in relation to
the size of the economy.

The actions of a dominant firm in a small

town have an enormous impact on the economic well-being of that
community; similarly management of its outlays and tax revenues
by the Federal Government--the largest single unit in our economy-affects the welfare of the entire population.

Changes in government

expenditures, taxes, and the relation between them inevitably affects
total economic activity, for good or ill.

When it was recognized

that this impact exists, it became desirable to adapt budgetary
decisions to the goal of steady growth and stability of the economy.
To this effort, we give the name fiscal policy.
Fiscal, like monetary, policy has generalized effects
throughout the economy.

Though Federal expenditures are concentrated

on certain industries, their effects on incomes and output spread
everywhere.

Similarly, we all feel the impact of taxation.

Yet

fiscal policy is also adaptable to the solution of specific problems,
regional or otherwise.

For example, some expenditures can be

deliberately directed to depressed areas; some types of activity
can be given special tax treatment as an inducement or deterrent.
These selective uses of fiscal policy, and of monetary policy, are
illustrations

of the third type of policy approach —

the structural*

As 1 have stressed, monetary and fiscal policies are
aimed primarily at influencing the level of aggregate demand
and, therefore, of total economic activity, with a view to preventing
both

inflation and deflation and encouraging steady economic

growth at stable prices.




-7Yet not all economic problems within the Government's
sphere of responsibility are amenable to a generalized approach such
as that of monetary and fiscal policies.

In the case of some problems,

we utilize specific remedies which can be focused on specific problems.
These specific diagnoses and remedies are what I call the structural
approach to economic problems.

The vital difference between the

structuralist approach and the monetary-fiscal tools lies in this
very specification.

The structuralist diagnoses the cause and

prescribes a remedy— in the political-economic world he sticks his
neck out— and the more specific his diagnosis and remedy the farther
out his neck.

It is not surprising that even in a world of short

memories structuralists with positive proposals are relatively rare.
The monetarists and fiscalists have no such handicap.
The reactions that monetary and fiscal actions induce are
obscure to most people— not because these moves are some sort of
financial shell game--but because there are, for the public at least,
no equivalents of isotope tracers which can be used as connective
evidence of effects on the economic community.

This lack of a

generally accepted demonstration causes some to say that monetary
policy, for example, did not, or could not have had any effect,
while at the same time others say it did or could have had the
desired effect.

There are no controlled laboratories for testing

the effectiveness of general monetary or fiscal policy.

In the

real world, the environment, the cyclical condition, and the
dosage vary so much as to require involved analytical techniques




-8to demonstrate results.

This leaves the many who subscribe to the

efficacy of monetary policy on faith prepared to believe and contend
that monetary policy supplied a necessary ingredient if not the one
which actually precipitated the desired economic effect.

The

scoffers, and some of the believers, when it suits their purpose,
can say in any given situation, that monetary action played a
passive role, implying that within practical limits it could not
have done otherwise.

Of course, using this latter argument, it is

possible for the money managers to have the better of a bad situation
and the best of a good one.

They live as blameless neuters when things

go wrong and as perceptive regulators when all is well.
Turning now to some comments on the relative merits of
these alternative types of policies, one example of considerable
topical interest can be found in the measures that are being adopted
to deal with the unemployment problem.

Both fiscal and monetary

policies have been aimed at stimulating total economic activity,
which in turn is expected to increase employment and reduce unemploy­
ment.

At the same time, however, It is recognized that some of the

unemployment will not yield merely to increased demands for labor.
In some cases, technology has changed so that demands for the
products of certain industries are unlikely to increase enough to
absorb the labor force attached to those Industries; coal mining,
for Instance.

In other cases, rapid technological advance has

rendered certain skills obsolete, or has permanently reduced the
demand for unskilled labor.




-9To deal with these structural aspects of unemployment,
structural measures have been adopted.

These include an area

redevelopment program and a retraining program for workers who are
technologically unemployed.

The existence of these programs reflects

an awareness that merely increasing aggregate demand in the economy
at large will not solve the entire unemployment problem.

In fact,

an effort by government to expand total demand for goods and services
until all the unemployed were absorbed, aside from a normal margin
of frictional unemployment, would probably send the economy off into
a severe inflation.

A fiscal-monetary solution is not appropriate

for the structural portion of the unemployment problem.
Another area in which a structuralist approach has come
to be regarded as more appropriate than the monetarist approach,
and one that goes back 30 years, is the regulation of stock market
credit.

As you know, the Federal Reserve is directed by Congress

to utilize a special-purpose instrument in regulating credit used
to purchase and carry stock*

In contrast to general monetary policy,

which operates by influencing the supply of bank credit available,
but leaves the determination of interest rates and other credit
terms to market determination, this special instrument specifies
a maximum amount of credit that can be extended to finance
individual stock purchases.

It is possible, therefore, for the

Federal Reserve to affect the amount of credit used to purchase
stock without invoking a change in general monetary policy, which
would affect credit availability for all purposes.




-10What was the rationale for adoption of this special-purpose
structural approach?

As some of you nay recall from memory and

others from a study of history, stock market speculation involving
heavy use of credit was rampant in the late 1920's.

The great crash

of 1929 imposed severe hardship on many people throughout the country
and also did much to accentuate the depression.

It became evident

that the purchase of securities with small cash payments and large
amounts of credit had contributed to the excessive rise in stock
prices and, when prices turned around, attempts to liquidate this
credit aggravated the drop in stock prices.
In the face of this developing situation in the late 1920's,
the Federal Reserve confronted conflicting policy objectives.

The

only way it could attempt to lessen the flow of credit into the
stock market was by restricting credit availability to the entire
economy.

Yet, though this was a period of general prosperity,

commodity prices were stable, and some sectors of the economy (notably
agriculture and construction) were ailing.

Aside from the stock

market situation, there was no need for a severely restrictive
monetary and credit policy.

On the other hand, there was no way

to shut off the flow of loans for stock speculation.

The only

means available consisted of general monetary policy instruments.
It is no wonder that the Federal Reserve authorities were puzzled
and internally divided in their policy recommendations.
I

have failed to do justice to this colorful, if unfortunate,

episode in our financial history.




I believe I have said enough to

-11make It clear that here was a problem calling for the tools of the
structuralist, not the monetarist.

And, as a result of that experience,

we have selectively tied treatment to a specific diagnosis.
I am naturally led by these observations to wonder whether
the policy problems raised by our present balance of payments
difficulties are not somewhat comparable to those of the late 1920's.
Not, let me hasten to say, because of a prospective crisis in the
balance of payments comparable to that in the stock market of 1929
but because this may also be a case more for the structuralist than
for the monetarist.
As you know, our domestic economy is exhibiting an inadequate
rate of expansion.

After rapid recovery from the 1960 recession,

total output in the past year has increased too slowly and has not
made any further inroads on the margin of unemployed manpower and
unutilized productive capacity.
generally stable.

At the same time prices have been

In these circumstances both fiscal and monetary

policy have been directed to stimulating economic activity.

For

monetary policy, such a posture means encouraging bank credit and
monetary expansion and, as a consequence, downward pressure on
interest rates.
Meanwhile, our International accounts are in deficit with
the result that our gold stock has declined substantially and
foreign central banks have accumulated large amounts of dollar
claims on us.

Our balance-of-payments problem, however, is not

of the traditional type.

Our trading position is strong and we

have a substantial excess of exports over imports.




But we are

-12-

asking this trading balance to carry a part of the foreign aid and
military spending programs whose size and characteristics ?re
dictated by the world-wide struggle between cormunistn and our kind
of freedom and in that context balance-of-payments difficulties have
a lesser priority.

This doesn't mean that the balance-

of-payments problsm can be swept under the rug but only that additional
methods of paring down the deficit will have to be found.
The other element in our excess of payments abroad is an
outflow of private capital, both short and long term.

This capital

flow takes many forms and ordinarily would be entirely appropriate
for the richest country in the world.

When I say this, I mean there

is a very fundamental difference between a balance-of-payments deficit
based on spending beyond one's income for current consumption and
investing one's savings in the expectation of earning a return and
getting back the principal.

The latter is what we are doing and it

is no more profligate than any saving-investing act.

Actually, as a

result of these investments, we have added about 23 billion dollars to
our private holdings of foreign assets in the past 5 years, bringing the
total to about 60 billion dollars.

Moreover, U. S. Government claims on

foreigners rose about 5 billion dollars in these years to a total of
roughly 22.5 billion dollars.

As these asset categories have been rising

we have lost nearly 7 billion dollars of a non-earning asset -- gold, and
added about 12 billion dollars to our liquid liabilities.

Over-all this

is clearly a significant strengthening in our balance sheet position.
But there is a problem here, partly psychological, partly
technical, and wholly one of timing.

At the moment, our capital outflows,

though they add to our future inflows of dividends, interest, and the
return of capital, press on our current liquidity position.



13

One way to curtail the net outflow of capital is to reduce
the interest rate incentive for Americans to lend abroad and for
foreigners to borrow here.

As you know, this consideration has been

an important influence on Federal Reserve monetary policy (and
Treasury debt management policy).

In the period of relative ease

in monetary policy since 1960, the Treasury bill yield has not been
permitted to fall much below 2-1/2 per cent and recently has been
closer to 3 per cent, whereas in earlier periods of monetary ease,
bill rates fell as low as 1 per cent.
The effort to prevent short-term interest rates from falling
has operated as a constraint on the actions of the Federal Reserve to
stimulate the economy.

If monetary policy had been more vigorous,

commercial banks would have been in a position to purchase more
earning assets and interest rates would have been under greater
downward pressure.

On the other hand, if Federal Reserve adopts

a more restrictive policy in order to discourage capital outflows,
credit availability and interest rates for domestic borrowers will
be affected and, consequently, domestic credit-financed expenditures
will be deterred.
If our balance-of-payments deficit were of the traditional
type, such a monetary policy would be appropriate.

Traditionally,

balance-of-payments deficits have accompanied domestic inflation.
Thus a monetary policy designed to arrest excess demand at home also
operated to improve the balance of payments.

In our present situation,

however, domestic considerations call for a monetary policy just the
opposite of that dictated by the balance of payments.




-

14-

It is for this reason that 1 z&ll your attention to the
analogy with the late 1920fs.

And, by the same token, we need to

give more emphasis to structural approaches to the balance-ofpayments problem.
Many of the actions taken by the Government to deal with
the dollar problem have, in fact, been of a structural and selective
nature rather than aggregative.
exports.

Foreign aid has been tied to U. S.

Export promotion and export credit schemes have been adopted.

Duty-free import allowances for tourists have been lowered.

Measures of

this type are designed to deal with the specific balance-of-payments
problem without hampering domestic economic expansion.
The problem before us is whether we can, consistent with our
responsibilities as a good citizen of the international community,
find and implement enough structural approaches so that we can correct
the balance-of-payments disequilibrium without having to undertake
monetary actions that are inimical to the domestic economy.
I have not come here with a specific package of proposals
that would lead us out of the present dilemma.

If these were readily

available, and were consistent with all our obligations, they would
presumably have been adopted already.

What I am suggesting is that

we turn our minds and energies more strenuously to finding additional
structural approaches to the balance-of-payments problem.

The need

for solution to the balance-of-payments problem is pressing.

But

the need to restore vigorous expansion in the domestic economy is
also pressing.




ooooo