View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For Release:
P.M.'s
Möndav, December 8, 1969




NEW STANDARDS FOR CREDIT AND MONETARY POLICY
by
George W. Mitchell, Member
Board of Governors
Federal Reserve System

Delivered Before
The Business Week Conference
on Money and the Corporation
sponsored'by
Business Week and
McGraw-Hill Publications Company

New Standards for Credit and Monetary Policy
Innovations in commercial banking in recent years have
been numerous and significant.

Many of the changes were overdue

or inevitable in light of the Nation's economic development.
Several have implications for monetary and credit policy because
the banking system is the primary transmission link for the
Federal Reserve's monetary and credit actions.
At least three such facets of postwar banking develop­
ments emerging in the Sixties appear to foretell significant trends
in the Seventies.

These are: (1) changes in commercial banking

structure and function; (2) the introduction of new and varied
intermediation instruments of both a deposit and non-deposit
character; (3) the progress toward computerizing monetary trans­
actions.
My comments on new standards for credit and monetary
policy are organized around these unfolding developments in
commercial banking because they will condition to a considerable
degree the efficiency and effectiveness of alternative monetary
techniques and devices.
Banking Structure and Function
It was becoming more and more apparent in the Fifties
and early Sixties that banking's growth was being constrained by
geographical confinement of major conventional types of banking
activity.




Stunting the growth potential has been accomplished by

-2limiting the economies of scale realizable in a modern corporate
organization.

For banking these economies and efficiencies are

significant in such diverse areas as data processing, capital
adequacy, resource allocation, management succession, portfolio
management and planning.
Banking organizations today ordinarily compete in the
provision of most traditional money, saving, and loan services
only in areas around their banking office locations.
exceptions, of course.

There are

Banks are continuously active in the impersonal

money and capital markets.

They also provide services to remote

corporate and individual customers whose balances are large enough
to justify a competitive effort.

But, by and large, most banks grow

in the number of customers services either by extending their service
areas or as the communities around their existing locations grow.
And a community might, in these terms, be a neighborhood, a city,
a county or a group of counties.

If growth in a community is slow

relative to that in the Nation, its banks are also faced with relative
sluggish growth prospects.

As the higher rates of population and

industrial growth in the past 20 years have been in the South and
West, banks in those regions have had the greater growth potentials.
The established financial institutions in the East and mid-West,
on the other hand, have had to develop new activities, markets,
and sources of funds in order to show significant rates of growth.




-3-

Aggressive banking organizations of sufficient size to
exploit economies of scale have extended their operations and
competitive positions in many ways.

Some results of their efforts

are manifest in the accelerated growth of holding companies with
one or more banks, in relaxed branching restrictions and quickened
merger activity in a few States; in the development of new lending
and borrowing services; and in the expansion, mainly through sub­
sidiaries and affiliates, into related and financial services such
as equipment leasing, mortgage servicing, data processing, insurance,
factoring, international finance, and mutual funds.
Some of the thrust of these developments can be seen in
the comparative statistics over the past decade.

There has been

a decline in unit banking, a drastic shift in the balance in the
dual banking system and an erosive change in the influence of
correspondent banking connections.

The main fact though is that

bankings' structural horizons are changing in ways that will be more
apparent in the statistics of the Seventies.
For the banks that are participating, the extension in
markets has been both geographical and in broadened services.

In

general, the competitive effects of these trends on both bank and
non-bank competition has been salutory although there is much
apprehension evident in the congressional deliberations on the
one-bank holding company bill that larger banks will, by these
means, become too dominant in too many markets.







-4The implications for credit policy are that as banking
organizations become more diversified in form, function, and
geographical extent they become more resourceful in coping with
regulatory constraints and more protean in their resistive
capacities.

Shaping the resource-gathering and credit-granting

activities of banking conglomerates through interest rate ceilings,
reserve requirements and other regulatory restraints might be
likened to punching a bag of sand into an erect position.

Many

doubt it is possible, necessary or even desirable to do so.
Most sectors of the U.S. financial structure are less
hampered by regulation affecting credit conditions than banks,
but the banking sector has been so pervasive in its influence on
other financial institutions and market participants that it has
had the capacity to pass on or "lay off" restraint.

This action

is not costless so far as the bank and its customers are concerned.
But a bank can, for a market determined price, sell assets, borrow
money or attract deposits and use these resources to meet its loan
and investment commitments.

This ability to transmit restraint to

the market and other intermediaries has meant there has been no
real difficulty in making public credit and monetary policies work
even though many institutions and their customers are not directly
touched by Federal Reserve policies.
Recent trends toward conglomerate corporate complexity
indicate the possibility of stripping some activities and functions
away from the banks proper and lodging them in subsidiaries,

-5affiliates, joint ventures or trusteed stock arrangements.

These

moves would, at least temporarily, frustrate regulatory constraints
and might serve other corporate objectives but they would, if
thought to be running counter to the overall public interest, invite
further regulatory complications.

As long as financial conglomeration

is really peripheral to a banking system which retains credit market
shares in the neighborhood of those realized in the late 1960's there
seems to me to be little cause for concern on the score of credit and
monetary control in the functional and structural developments under
way today.
Time Deposits and Liability Management
A drastic decline in the major component of money— demand
deposits— has occurred in the Fifties and Sixties.

Such deposits

have long been regarded as the life blood of commercial banking;
they have also been the source of predictable stability in loanable
resources.

In mid-1947 the net contribution of such deposits to

commercial banking's resources was equivalent to 37 per cent of the
then current GNP; in mid-1957 to 25 per cent; in mid-1969 to 17 per
cent.
Banking had a response to the 50 per cent decline relative
to GNP in check book or non-interest bearing bank money.

It was the

development and promotion of a variety of interest-bearing deposits
and other liability instruments.

The long-established passbook

accounts were glamorized and their rates made more competitive.




-

6-

Negotiable and non-negotiable certificates of deposit were tailored
in size, maturity, rate and name.

In a variety of forms they have

been suited to the needs and convenience of the banks' regular
customers as well as customers of other intermediaries.

These

certificates have also appealed to large numbers of money market
participants.
In the aggregate these measures worked to extend banking's
share of credit markets from roughly 20 per cent in the late Fifties
to around 40 per cent in the late Sixties.

Within banking, the

relative roles of demand and time deposits in providing loanable
resources have shifted from a 2.4 to 1.0 relationship in 1947 to
a .8 to 1.0 relationship in 1969.
Experience with monetary restraint in 1966 showed banks
how regulatory ceilings on rates of interest for deposits might
become a threat to their capacity to retain contact with the sources
for funds they had developed in the early Sixties.

In consequence,

new channels of communication with markets were developed in the
form of non-deposit liabilities which were subject neither to
interest rate ceilings nor reserve requirements.

Among the devices

used, Euro-dollar borrowings, repurchase agreements, and commercial
paper sales by holding company affiliates and banking subsidiaries
have been the most important or promising.
As banks extended in scope and magnitude their access to
money and credit markets earlier this year, apprehension that such




-7techniques would undermine the force of monetary restraint grew
despite the magnitude of the decline in deposit flows.
On July 24 the Board of Governors restricted the use of
repurchase agreements by commercial banks.

This was done by making

the bank liabilities on such agreements deposit liabilities provided
the agreements had been entered into with nonbanks and on assets
other than Treasury securities and agency issues.

The purpose of

the regulation was to prevent banks from borrowing on their port­
folios of loans, mortgages, and municipal securities and thus obtaining
funds for other lending and investment or to meet liquidity needs.

The

constraint of Regulation Q ceilings applied to such transactions as it
would to time deposits generally.
This action had the effect not only of limiting the banking
system's access to money and credit markets but also of downgrading
mortgages and municipal securities as liquidity assets relative to
Treasury and agency issues.
On August 13 marginal reserve requirements were imposed on
Euro-dollar borrowings and the sale of outstanding loans to foreign
branches.

A regulation imposing interest rate ceilings on commercial

paper sold by banking affiliates has been proposed by the Board.
Without doubt regulatory policies have been aimed at insulating
the banking system from money and credit markets.

This has been done

with rate ceilings, regulations curbing banks' ability to substitute
other liabilities for deposits, and restrictions on contingent sales




-8of assets.

In total, these measures have limited the banking

system's ability to lend to its customers, a fact that is abundantly
clear from the magnitude of the decline in market shares of funds
going to banks in 1966 and 1969.

The same rate ceilings have hampered

the savings and loans and the mutual savings banks in serving their
customers, too, although their plight in 1969 has been ameliorated
by the operations of FNMA, and the lending policies of the FHLB Board.
The policy of reinforcing monetary restraint by constraining
banking's access to money and credit markets may be more controversial
than its practical significance in the present situation warrants.
But for the long run it clearly raises important issues relating to
financial structure and the role of credit policy.
As seen by their proponents today, regulatory constraints
have forced a sharp contraction in the rate of bank and other inter­
mediary lending and investment.

The rational for this approach is

that Q ceilings, by limiting bank access to funds, have led to greater
restraint on business loans than would otherwise have occurred— a
desirable distributional effect on credit availability in view of
the role of business investment in generating excess demand and
inflation.

Furthermore, since intermediaries are more efficient

in their credit allocative function than direct lenders and markets,
the reduction of intermediation is seen as the quickest and surest
way to slow and restrict the availability of credit and thus to
bring about the modification of spending and investment decisions.




-

9-

All of those borrowers who are exclusively dependent on inter­
mediaries encounter credit restraint even though they may be
preferred customers.
The main argument against sealing off the intermediaries
from markets is that the effectiveness of restraint is not signifi­
cantly diluted as a result of its being shifted by a bank inter­
mediary to the market or another intermediary, however different
the incidence.

As banks disperse monetary restraint, and they

cannot disperse all of it, they force borrowers other than their
customers to pay higher prices for credit and to face uncertain
availability.

Their action in selling assets, raising interest

rates paid for funds, entering into repurchase agreements of assets
and the like, does not result in much diminution of over-all restraint.
Even if intermediaries were given unlimited access to money and credit
markets they would themselves be increasingly restrained by the market
environment they would be creating.

The argument continues that the

channeling and confinement of restraint to intermediaries and their
customers results in the unnecessary dislocation of credit patterns,
in inequities in the distribution of credit and inefficiencies in the
operation of the financial system.
The differential effect of forcing intermediaries to
contract their lending operations has the most certain and serious
effect on smaller customers who do not have significant access to
capital and credit markets.

Shutting off or restricting the flow

of bank credit to large corporate borrowers only means they become




-10more dependent on markets.

And since such borrowers are better

able than most others to obtain funds in the market using such
non-depository credit instruments as commercial paper, some have
argued that corporate borrowers were more favorably situated with
respect to credit availability as a result of bank disintermediation.
While I am persuaded that intermediaries should have had
more ready access to markets, the contrary position is not without
merit from a pragmatic short-run standpoint.

However, I believe

the real problem is not one of making monetary and credit restraint
effective in some given interval but the longer run effect of such
tactics on the process of intermediation and the institutions
providing this service.
A significant change in the financial environment during
the Sixties has been the greatly expanded role for intermediation.
Liquidity services have been shifted on a large scale to intermediaries
or specialized intermediary devices.

There has been a resulting

relative decline in demand deposits and non-intermediary holdings
of non-intermediary debts.

If long-run policies are adopted to cut

off their access to markets intermediaries will be greatly handi­
capped fulfilling their liquidity function.

In this view, they are

more in need, from a public policy standpoint, of being assisted in
dispersing restraint than being constrained from doing so.
Looking beyond the current period and its requirement
of monetary restraint, therefore, I believe the view that banks




-11should be barred from access to financial markets by regulations
of one type or another presents neither a stable solution to the
problem nor one that is in our long-run interest.

It is unstable

in the sense that the banking system can develop quite an array
of alternative techniques for maintaining contact with sources
of funds and users.

While it may be true that commercial banking

"cannot fight city hall" very effectively in the short run, given
time it can develop flexible instruments and durable relationships
to break down most of the barriers regulators can think up.

And

if it cannot and the belief prevails that banking must in the
public interest be isolated from financial markets, many of com­
mercial banking's present-day functions will be scattered to
other intermediaries and financial agencies.
But, it seems to me, this, in addition to being undesirable,
is entirely unnecessary to the objective of monetary restraint.

If,

in fact, it should be determined that monetary restraint ought to be
aimed at selected types of institutions or specific uses of credit,
it would be better to impose differential reserve requirements on
all such institutions and assets.

While I believe we need not shrink

from being concerned with the social objectives served by the economy's
use of credit, I question whether this period of monetary restraint
is one in which to launch such a policy explicitly or by indirection.
We would improve the effectiveness of the linkages by
which monetary restraint is transmitted if we could develop techniques




-12for bringing commitments to lend under pressure more promptly.
No reasonable application of monetary restraint is intended to
bring about "fails" on prior commitments.

The process is aimed

rather at prospective spending and investing decisions.

The tardy

response to monetary restraint in 1969 can be traced to the weak­
ness of its initial impact on commitment policy of lending institutions.
Computerizing and Scheduling Monetary Transactions
I noted earlier the decline over the past twenty years,
in relative terms, of the demand deposit component of the money stock.
A similar decline has occurred in currency.

Coin usage, on the other

hand, has stepped up about 25 per cent in the same period, primarily
as a result of requirements for meter hoards.
Money serves two basic functions: as a transaction tool
and a source of liquidity.

Technological changes in the past decade

have greatly extended money's efficiency as a transactor and greatly
reduced its relative attractiveness as a liquidity source.
The relative decline in currency can be linked to the
expansion in consumer checking accounts, charge accounts, and credit
cards.

Non-cash sales make up over two-thirds of the transactions

of many of our largest retailers.

Convenience credit is widely

available via vendors' credit facilities and, more recently,
through bank, oil company, and travel and entertainment cards.
It has been estimated that by late 1970 at least 50 million bank




-13credit cards will have been issued.

There are 75 million charge

accounts in use today.
The most striking decline in holdings of demand deposits
has occurred in business accounts.
they were in the early Fifties.

These are no higher today than

Actually corporate demand balances

today probably reflect more than anything else compensating balance
requirements for check processing, loan and other banking services.
Theoretically, a skilled money-managing, computer-equipped treasurer,
unhampered by compensating balance requirements, could manage his
firm's checking account so that toward each day's end he would know if
he had a balance large enough to cover the transaction costs for an
overnight investment.

And if he had, his resultant late-day invest­

ment action might, under certain circumstances, indirectly turn out
in effect to be lending that residual in his account to his own bank.
Electronic facilities for check processing will make possible much
closer management of cash positions, particularly if scheduled
credit transfers become commonplace.
The best information we have on the ownership of the demand
deposit component of the money supply indicates that households own
about $70-75 billion, nonfinancial businesses $45 billion, financial
business $15 billion, and State and local goverment $13 billion.
About $4 billion is in foreign accounts.

It is safe to say

that

all professionally-managed accounts are at or near minima established
by banking rules or practices.




-14Households are managing their money position more
closely, too— many use a fee-no-minimum balance-type account.
Individuals have become increasingly sensitive to interest costs
and interest yields.

Their response to the promotional efforts

on the advantages of time and savings accounts has been to
progressively reduce demand balances to the minimum levels
consistent with the timing of income receipts.

Such attitudes

are evident in the average holdings in household checking accounts.
According to mid-1968 data, the latest we have, there were 79+
million demand deposit accounts.

Most of these were for house­

holds but businesses, governments and nonprofit organizations
were included.

Sixty-four million accounts had balances of less

than $1,000 and the average holding was $240.'

Not much leeway there.

Computer facilities becoming available will enable house­
holds to schedule regular periodic payments through pre-authorization
arrangements even more precisely in relation to the timing of their
salary and wage credits.

This will bring within their reach still

more of the money economies that corporate treasurers present enjoy.
The reduced relative attractiveness of money— currency or
demand deposits— as a source of liquidity arises chiefly from the
competition of near monies— mainly savings and time deposits in
commercial and mutual savings banks and savings and loan associa­
tions, but including short dated Government debt and money market
paper.




Since these interest-bearing deposits or paper have instant

liquidity or conveniently scheduled maturities they can serve
as both liquidity reserves and earning assets.
The relevance of these facts on deposit trends and
prospects is to the controversy over the use of money supply
as a guide for monetary policy makers or as an indicator of their
actions.

In recent years rates of change in various financial

aggregates have been increasingly recognized for their analytical
value in both of these roles.
The Federal Open Market Committee has, since 1966 and
regularly beginning in 1968, used an aggregate called the "bank
credit proxy" to quantify intervention limits on expansion or
contraction arising out of a directive couched in terms of money
market conditions and interest rates.
The primary instructions to the Manager are for "no change,
"firmer," or "easier" posture supplemented by specified ranges in
marginal reserve measures and short-term interest rates.

This

pattern is internally consistent, so far as can be foretold, with
a projected range for the "credit proxy."

But if the proxy begins

to move outside of its range this fact begins to modify the
Manager's reserve supplying actions.
Our experience using aggregative measures as supplementary
operating guides has not been spectacularly successful but it has
been good enough to encourage further development and use.

Since

the only measurable monetary action the Committee can take is to
alter the amount of reserves supplied to the banking system, it is




-16necessary to estimate how quickly a change in reserve injection
will affect changes in various aggregative measures.

The relation­

ships are far from stable and the results have been necessarily
approximate and subject to significant errors.
The Joint Economic Committee of the Congress in recent
years has urged greater attention to a particular monetary aggregate-M]_, the narrowly defined money supply.

In its 1969 report is said:

"Over the long run, the increase in the money supply
should be roughly at the same rate as the growth of U.S.
productive capacity. As indicated by this committee in
its report, the expansion of the money supply should be
somewhat above the long-run real growth rate during periods
of high unemployment and excess capacity. On the other
hand, monetary expansion should be below real growth in
periods of inflation. We recommended a rate of increase
ranging from 2 percent to 6 percent. The principle of
harmony between the rate of growth of the money supply
and the rate of growth of the economy has been recommended
by the committee for many years.... "
"As long as inflation continues at a high rate, the
pace of expansion in the money supply should remain near
the lower end of the range suggested; that is, near 2 per­
cent per annum."
By the Committee's standards the Federal Reserve may
or may not be in the ball park.

For 1969 as a whole (up to

December) money supply rose at a 2.8 per cent rate but the growth
in the first half was 4.3 per cent and in the past five months
was 1.1 per cent.




-17There is no doubt, in my opinion, that financial
aggregates will steadily become more useful in guiding policy
makers and the judgments of those who are searching for clues
to policy changes.

But I believe we are a long way from being

able to specify a particular aggregate as a "North Star" for
monetary navigation.

Nor would I expect that in our researches

we will be able to find for our constantly changing environment
a single aggregate— monetary or credit— of predictable durability
and reliability.
On the other hand, if the analytical insights that can
be gained from the study of the Flow of Funds were available on
a more current basis our reliance on changes in credit aggregates
would be significantly extended.
The most popular of all the aggregates— Mi— seems,
given present technological and institutional trends to have the
shortest life expectancy.

Its significance for policy is being

chipped away, on the one hand, by steadily increasing variety and
attractiveness of near monies and, on the other, by the long
continued and prospective further rise in velocity made possible
by computer and communications technology.

Turnover (velocity)

in demand deposits has been increasing steadily: it more than
doubled in the 1960's and has increased 7 per cent so far this
year.




-18Tfae technological obsolescing of M^ does not mean that
money supply is dead or only alive in St. Louis.

If it were to

be rid of its transaction component and become primarily a
liquidity measure its meaning and interpretation would be in
the tradition of M 2 and M 3 , and, in my judgment, this would add
significantly to its stature as an important financial aggregate.