View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release at 2 p.m.
Eastern Daylight Time
Tuesday, May 1, 1962




Economic Growth and the Banking Structure

Remarks of George W. Mitchell
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Annual Convention of the
Independent Bankers Association
Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania
May 1, 1962

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND THE BANKING STRUCTURE

Throughout most of our nation1s history, economic growth, like
youth, has been taken for granted.

But unlike the aging man who can only

fail to regain his youth, the social-economic organism can be conditioned
for growth, stagnation, or decline with appropriate political policies.
Whether economic growth became a national goal and policy aim
because it was something that could no longer be taken for granted or for
some other reason is a topic we might speculate about for the full time you
have allotted me.

I take it to be the fact, in any case, and content myself

with observing that growth is not really the thing sought but is a derivative
from other goals.

It is derived from the argument that rapid economic growth

facilitates the achievement of widely sought social and personal goals such
as: increasing leisure, a basis for our "aspirations to consume,11 employment
for a growing labor force, and the projection of the image of a free society
to the world.

We might add that with these goals goes the accompanying hope

that growth will somehow improve the quality of society and not induce a
malaise from too much devotion to

la dolce vita.

Within the economy, growth is no less desired by private business
firms, the components of our capitalist engine.

They, too, have in mind

specific objectives associated with corporate growth; rising prestige,
diversification of products and markets, long life, if not immortality
stability of profits, and sheer power.

Indeed the modern U.S. corporation

might best be thought of not as a unit designed in the image of a product
or service but rather as an abstract capacity to produce.

Managers and

owners of these firms are alert to direct and expand this capacity wherever
profit opportunities, generated by growth and change in the economy, appear.




-2They are highly flexible; their genius is in the ability to organize
production and exploit markets.
Banks in some respects share their attributes.

As lenders they

are par excellence "units of capacity to produce11; their great flexibility
of decision is apparent in the variety of alternative loans and investments
available to them.

Like their counterparts in business firms, bankers

shift and expand their capacity wherever profit opportunities, created by
growth and change, present themselves.

But it must not be overlooked that

in amassing the resources to lend and invest banks may be unable to break
away from their physical locations.

The freedom of adaptation they enjoy

in their lending activity is unmatched by freedom to follow depositors and
savers when they move from the city to the suburbs or from the farm to an
urban area.
As our economy has grown, specialized and incorporated technological
change in production and distribution, the banking system has come under
increasing pressure to adapt.

Rather than attempt to list all the forces

at work that seem relevant— and are readily translatable into entrepreneurial
incentives of prestige, profit and power— I shall deal with three: population
growth and movement, evolution in data processing technology, and the increasing
importance of nonbank financial institutions.

After examining the nature of

these changes, I will turn to some of the implications for public policy of
alternative changes in banking structure.
Looking backward, the most pervasive economic influence on banking
structure has been the differential nature of population growth and movement.
Beginning with World War II, population changes have had an enormous impact
on banking structure.




-3-

For example, in this period farm population shrank at least onethird, the population of the core cities in many of our metropolitan areas
declined and the growth in population in the West and certain Southern
states was 2 to 4 times what it was in the East and North Central states.
These changes differentially affected banking structure.

In many rural

areas growth and profit prospects dimmed and the banking structure became
static.

The banks in the core cities without the legal sanction to branch

and follow their customers into the suburban periphery saw their positions
shrink relative to banks in states where branching was permitted.
If we examine the banking statistics by states, we find that in the
31 jurisdictions where the population increase during the decade was less than
average for the United States (18 per cent), there were 20 widely scattered
states in which the number of banks changed hardly at all. (I am not here
speaking of banking offices)

In 9 of the 31 states there were reductions of

20 to 35 per cent in the number of banks as a result of substantial consolida­
tion activity.

In only two of the 31 states were there increases; one of 8 and

one of 10 per cent.
In the 20 states where population increased more than the U.S.
average there was only one state in which the change in number of banks was
nominal.

In six of the faster growing states there were increases in number

of banks of 8, 11, 14, 22, 33, and 49 per cent.

In 13 states there were

declines of 8 to 45 per cent as branching, mergers and consolidations
offset the impact of the expanding population on bank numbers.
These data indicate that the population movements of the past two
decades have had a major impact on banking structure.

They expose the

vulnerability of locally-based financial institutions to population migration.




-4-

Unable to follow individual depositors and savers to their new locations
and substantially handicapped in servicing nonlocal business customers
the unit bank or any other local financial institution is more or less
chained to the future of its home community.

How damaging this may be

to their economic welfare depends quite obviously on the community in
question and the confinement enforced by state law.
Another more recent change which augurs adaptation by the banking
system is the revolution now taking place in business communication and data
processing.

Much thought and study is currently being given to the implica­

tion of such techniques on bank costs and services to customers.

On the face

of it, it would appear that electronics is the genii of the large bank and
cannot be put to work with as great an advantage for the moderate sized or
small bank.

But it is too soon to conclude that EDP cannot be adapted or

made available to smaller institutions or that competitive costs cannot be
substantially met by other accounting techniques.
A third change forcing adaptation by the banking system has been
the rapid growth of nonbank financial institutions in the past two decades.
Their growth has changed the competitive environment in which banks operate
and is an increasing challenge to the primacy of banks as suppliers of credit
to many sectors of the American economy.

Not all savings accumulators are as

geographically confined as are commercial banks.

Sales and commercial finance

companies go to the capital markets for funds and lend nationally.

Insurance

companies also gather funds across state lines and over metropolitan areas.
Savings and loan associations and mutual savings banks tend to be confined
by the same geographical limits as the commercial banks and are similarly
handicapped by lack of local growth




or out-migration.

Whether the inertia

-5-

of age and status or the confines of banking statutes, augmented by hobbling
regulation, has made banks a pushover for a growing array of competitors has
not been established.

Indeed, it has not even been established that they are,

in fact, a pushover.
In the framework of entrepreneurial incentives and statutory
constraints bankers themselves must be adapting the structure of their
industry to make it more profitable and more responsive to opportunities
for growth.

Public policy confronted with these efforts at adaptation must

take into account the underlying and often complex changes in the economy
that surround the industry.

While it does not initiate changes, through the

granting or withholding of approval for changes sought by the industry, it
has a part in shaping the financial apparatus that serves the American economy.
The role of public policy, properly conceived, is the task of main­
taining competition, of ensuring its strength and at the same time achieving
maximum efficiency and productivity for the banking system and doing all of
this without central direction of decision.

This task is not a static one.

If the deep and complex changes in the economy and the industry that are
taking place are ignored or misunderstood, or if an attempt is made to apply
concepts appropriate only to the past, public policy decisions will delay and
deter evolutionary processes.
Maintaining competition comes up in many guises but consider as
an example how banking facilities should be established in response to
shifting deposit densities and changes in the structure of the demand for
credit.

Should it occur through building anew or by purchase of existing

facilities in the growing area?

If it is by merger, affiliation or common

ownership, market control may be the dominate consideration.




One bank sees

-6-

that it can get a very high return on its investment by buying its competitors
and having the market for itself.

But merger can also occur as the cheapest

form of expansion or adjustment to change.

Banks may find that choosing the

merger route to expansion, relocation or portfolio
procedure.

adjustment is a sensible

It may be cheaper to buy than to build a trained staff and a

developed deposit and loan business, even at a premium price.

Moreover, an

individiaul bank may be worth more as a component unit to, say, a holding
company or a branching organization than to its present owners.

Under these

circumstances, a premium price is likely to persuade present owners to sell
rather than depend on an uncertain return on their investment once a new
bank or new banks enter the area.
What should the stance of public policy be in instances like these?
Should it look to and attempt to sort out motives, rejecting those acquisitions
aimed at market control?

I think not, since it is seldom possible to distinguish

and weigh motives that are intertwined and sometimes concealed.

Then, too, there

is no guarantee that the innocent motive today may not be the predatory motive of
tomorrow.
It may be that the best course for public policy is a passive one,
to accept mutations as being natural.

If the trend is to size, perhaps the

best course is to accept the inevitable and to encourage the choice of the
cheapest and fastest way to achieve size.

The rationale of this passive role

would be that there are significant economies of size that arise in specializa­
tion of function and automation of processes.

If, in fact, economies of size

are present to a high degree in banking, attempts to stifle the growth of
banks into affiliated and branch organizations may be as ill-conceived as the
legislative attempts to stifle the growth of chain stores in the 20's and 30*s.




-7-

Chain units could enjoy larger profits by volume distribution at low margins.
Consumers of the products could get more for the same money or the same
amount for a smaller proportion of their incomes.

Both sellers and buyers

were made better off.
Raising the question of the relation of the size of the bank to
its efficiency in gathering up savings, servicing depositors and allocating
credit to its most productive uses, forces us to raise the most difficult
problem of all: understanding the relationship between the structure of
markets and the level and movement of prices.
It is an illusion to associate the force of competition with the
number of competitors.

A market may possess a goodly number of seemingly

independent sellers who do not compete because they all follow a leader.
On the other hand, a market with only a few sellers may be one in which
there is aggressive competitive downward revision of sales terms, and the
passing on of productivity gains to customers.
The enormously difficult problems of finding out how big a bank
has to be to be efficient enough, and how many banks are needed to maintair
competition enough, are not problems that can be solved by armchair logic.
I do not raise these problems to suggest that I have ready answers but
rather to suggest that the authority charged with tussling with them will
get more help by digging into empirical fact than in engaging in speculation.
Now, does all this add up to the demise of independent unit banks,
an end to their usefulness as components of our banking system?

Probably not.

There is little in our present imperfect state of knowledge suggesting that
economies of size are so pervasive that if all legal constraint were
suddenly relaxed we would end up tomorrow or next year with something like




-8-

Canada's eleven commercial banks, Australia's seven, the United Kingdomfs
big five, France*s big six, or Italy's big eight.
Main Street National may not be a growth firm but it may be entirely
adequate to the community it serves.

It may itself be too small to bear the

charges of automating its accounts.

But Main Street and 10 or 20 others like

it may be able to do in service bureaus or in association what they cannot
do alone.
Another reason why we should not expect to see the independent unit
bank washed away on the crest of technology is that the major changes we have
spoken of are highly structured geographically.

In vast regions of the nation

the local unit bank continues to provide services and facilities on terms and
in locations that affiliates of city

banks are not prepared to challenge*

Even in urbanized areas and where branching systems proliferate the unit
banker can, with a touch of ingenuity and the judgment he is known for,
often more than hold his own.
It is sometimes alleged that the typical unit bank cannot compete
with large branching systems because it cannot offer the same range of services.
The failure to recognize that a bank will only offer those services
it pays it to offer lies behind what we might call "the fallacy of extension
of services."

The fallacy has several variations but its most common form

goes something like this: public policy ought to accommodate mergers between
a large and small bank because the large bank can offer the residents in
the small bank's location a wider range of banking services.

A little

thought tells us that this is equivalent to arguing that the medical societies
ought to rescind the licenses of general practitioners because they can't be
specialists in every branch of medicine.




Both the neighborhood banker and the

-9-

family doctor recognize instances beyond their skill, seeking either specialized
advice or referring the case when it is necessary.
To extend the illustration a bit, no one would argue that a manu­
facturer of paper clips ought to go out of business because he does not
produce staples or rubber bands.

Almost everyone would say that this

manufacturer probably concentrates on paper clips rather than produce all
three products because he finds it profitable to do so.

It seems just as

reasonable to assume that the neighborhood banker does not offer a very wide
range of special services because the demand for them is too infrequent to
pay him to acquire the staff competent to administer them.

A neighborhood

bank does neighborhood business, changing the ownership of the bank— the
name over its door--wonft change the nature of its business.
I have attempted to indicate that the task of maintaining
competition is of sobering difficulty in concept and implementation.

It

would be much simpler to adopt a policy of maintaining competitors since
this would offer a much clearer guideline and certainly is not out of keeping
with the "theory of hostility to concentration of power in the hands of a few"
expressed by our Founding Fathers.

But the hazard in a policy of maintaining

competitors is that it might literally become just that— and nothing more.
In lieu of competitive performance we would be substituting havens which the
rigors of competitive action could not penetrate.
There is every reason why public policy ought to be concerned with
avoiding undue concentration of economic power.

Where efficiency and

dilution of economic power conflict, gains from efficiency even though clear
and of significant proportions cannot be overriding.




The important caveat

-10-

to enter here is that we accept the price involved in a structure of
priorities where economic democracy has a higher rank than economic
efficiency, just as we recognize and accept— indeed, insist upon accepting—
the price of maintaining our sometimes "inefficient11 democratic form of
government.




CHANGES IN NUMBER OF BANKS, 1951 - i960
RELATED 070 CHANGES IN POPULATION, 1950 - i960
Population increased by less than 10$ and
number of banks increased or decreased by —
+ o r -5%
-5i> or more
+5io or more
%
Change
$
>
Change
io Change
State
State
State
Bank 1Pop.
Bank ÌPop.
Bank 1Pop.
Arkansas
Georgia
Iowa
Kansas
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Nebraska
New Hampshire
North Dakota
Oklahoma
South Carolina
South Dakota
Tennessee
Wisconsin
W. Virginia

+3.O

+4.5
+1.5
- 3.3
+1.3
•4 .5
+4.5
+2.4
-1.3
+4.o
+1.0
-2.7
+3 .O
-0 .3
+1.1
40.6

- 6
Ik
5
Ik
ih
0
9
6
13
2

4

Kentucky
Massachusetts
Dist. of Col.
Idaho
Maine
New York
N. Carolina
Oregon
Pennsylvania
Rhode Island
Vermont

- 7.3
- 5.0
-36.8
-23.8
-25.4
-35.1
-18.7
-27.1
- 26.8
-35.7
-18.8

3
9
- if
13
6
13
12

Alabama
Illinois
Wyoming
Montana

+ 5-3 6
+ 7-9 15
+ 5.8 13
+10.0 14

16

7
8
3

12
k
8
15
-T

Population increased by l&f> or more and
number of banks increased or decreased by —
+5$ or more
+ or - 5* _____________
-5$ or more
%
Change
%
Change
% Change
State
State
State
Bank | Pop.
Bank | Pop,
Bank | Pop.
Virginia




-3.2

+19

Alaska
Arizona
California
Connecticut
Delaware
Indiana
Maryland
Michigan
Nevada
New Jersey
Ohio
Utah
Washington

- 35.O
-23.1
-41.8
-37.5
-kk.k
- 7.9
- 16.9
- 12.6
-12.5
-20.4
- 10.8
- 7.4
- 25.6

75
73
48
26
ho
18
32
22
78
25
22
29
19

New Mexico
Colorado
Florida
Hawaii
Louisiana
Texas

+ 7.8
+22.3
+48.6
+33.3
+14.5
+10.6

39
32
78
26
21
2k