View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Po e I
Talk given at the
Montana Bankers Association Convention
at Glacier Park
June 19, 1959

by

Frederick L. Deming, President
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

WHAT PRICE GROWTH
Under the heading, "You, Too, Can Play With Numbers,11 McGraw-Hill
economists have worked out a convenient reference table (published in
Business Week for May 23), from which you can pick at your pleasure one of
78 different, legitimate growth rates for the postwar U. S. economy.

With one

of these handy-sized tables in your wallet you can quickly summon such figures
as may be needed to down a would-be opponent in argument with evidence that
(a) our country h a s n ’t grown as well under your opponent1s political party as
under yours, or (b) our country's growth rate is slipping behind that of the
U.S.S.R, and something ought to be done about it.
While we can all enjoy the fun in which these data are presented,
they also have merit in that they illustrate some very important things about
growth that we must keep in mind.
Perhaps the two most important things to note about economic growth
records are these.

First, the very long-term picture shows an average rate

of growth in this country of about 3 per cent per year compounded.
is equivalent to doubling real output every 25 years.

That rate

Second, this is an aver­

age rate of growth, and growth in any one-, two- or several-year period may be
substantially higher or lower than average.
many growth rates.

This is why the table can show so

Thus we showed a growth rate of about 8 per cent in 1951,

and of about 4 per cent in each of the next two years, a minus 2 per cent in
1954, and a plus 8 per cent in 1955*

Growth in both 1956 and 1957 was below

average, while in 1958 output actually declined.
well above average.

Now these are a lot of figures to cite,

emphasize this second major point.
shows jumps, slips, and levels.



The expected rise in 1959 is
I give them to

Growth does not occur smoothly; its course

-

2

-

L e t fs look at this question from another angle.

Growth involves

both the capacity to produce and the capacity to consume.

We get physical

output of goods and services by applying human brains and muscle to natural
resources.

As we improve the efficiency of this human energy through better

technology and equipment, we increase productivity.

To develop the technology

and equipment, we have to sacrifice through saving - deferring consumption
today so as to have more tomorrow.

This process is not a smooth one.

We seem to get our technological

improvements in waves; we get changes in the rate of saving and of capital
formation; we even get changes in the rate of population growth.

We can make

some adjustments to compensate for the strong ups and downs of these factors
but we cannot now, nor do I think we ever will, smooth out the growth curve com­
pletely.
Productivity, or output per man hour, is the combined result of im­
proved technology and more and better capital goods.
2 1/2 per cent per year, compounded, in this century.

It has increased by about
Like the output curve,

the course of productivity shows jumps, slips, and levels as we would expect.
But the striking point to observe about this factor of productivity is that,
given today1s technology, we could be producing far more than we are if we wanted
to work as hard and as long as we did 50 years ago.

What has happened is that

we have taken about half of our productivity gains in the form of increased
leisure and about half in the form of more output.
And this brings me to the other side of the growth picture - the con­
sumption side.
individuals.

In our form of economy we produce primarily for people - for
Individuals have preferred to take some of the gains in productivity

in the form of shorter hours and some in the form of increased supply of goods
and services.




We are now taking far more in the form of publicly provided

-

3

-

services than we used to - in large part in the form of a large defense
establishment but also in many other forms.
One further point about growth needs to be made, and it is an important
point.

The standard of living concept embraces more than mere physical goods

and services; it also embraces the concept of enjoyment of those goods and
services.

This is why we have taken some of the fruits of productivity in

the form of increased leisure. And this is why it is difficult to compare growth
rates as between countries or over periods of time.

The percentage gain in

physical output is in this respect a rather hollow measure of growth.

In this

country growth only makes sense in terms of the kinds of goods people want and
under a maximum of liberty for the individual in choosing the goods he wishes
to consume.
I wish now to present the proposition that price stability is an
essential requirement for effective and sustained growth, and price inflation
hinders it.

Price stability does not mean price rigidity nor does it mean

that individual prices should stay constant.
however, should stay relatively stable.

The general level of prices,

It can register moderate ups and

downs over reasonable periods of time without detracting too much from the
general benefits of stability.

The key point is that prices should not move

rapidly or constantly in either direction.
One reason why so-called creeping inflation of, say, 3 per cent per
year is undesirable is its adverse effect on savings.

As identified earlier,

one critical element in growth is the introduction of improved technology
through capital investment.

Savings must remain sufficiently attractive to

induce people to withhold enough of their income from consumption today to
finance the plant and equipment that will enable us to produce the kinds of
goods we will want tomorrow and at prices we are willing and able to pay.
Long continued erosion of the dollar’
s purchasing power becomes a strong
deterrent to saving.



-

4

-

Let me turn now to discuss briefly a point on which there seems to
be a great deal of misunderstanding - interest rates and their role in a free
economy.

The subject has come in for considerable attention recently as the

President has asked the Congress to remove the present 4 1/4 per cent ceiling
on Treasury bond rates and the 3.26 per cent ceiling on Savings bond rates.
He also has asked for an upward revision in the Federal debt ceiling and c er­
tain technical changes which would facilitate debt management, but these r e ­
quests are better understood and less controversial.
Speaking broadly, the interest rate is nothing more or less than
price, namely the price of borrowed money.

As a price, the rate reacts to the

same sort of influences as other prices in a free market economy - influences
that operate through the demand for and the supply of funds available in credit
ma r k e t s .
On the demand side the principal impact on interest rates in this
country reflects the actions of four groups of borrowers: individuals, corpora­
tions, state and local governmental units, and the Federal government.

The

total debt of these borrowers has about doubled in the past twelve years, from
approximately $446 billion to about $880 billion.

Of this increase in the

last twelve years most of it has come from individuals, corporations, and state
and local governments.

Individual borrowings have jumped from $60 billion to

$240 billion; corporate borrowings from $110 billion to $298 billion; state
and local governments from $16 billion to $59 billion.

The Federal government

debt rose only $23 billion, from $260 billion to $283 billion in that same
period.
On the supply side funds come from two sources: savings or money
creation.

From the borrower1s point of view it doesn't make any difference

from which source he gets his funds, but the difference between the sources
is of crucial importance from the standpoint of achieving price stability and
sustainable economic growth.



I 111 say more about that in a minute.

-

5

-

Now there has been a lot of argument among economists about the
factors that determine interest rates.
the demand-supply relationship.

But no economist really argues against

The arguments are over what causes the demand

factors and the supply factors to change.
and borrowers like low rates.

Certainly lenders like high rates

The real point is what their actions and their

expectations do to the demand for and the supply of funds.
Historically, high level economic activity - prosperity - increases
the demand for funds.

High income and good rates of return stimulate savings.

Thus we associate high prosperity and high interest rates.

In recession

demand is low and even though savings may be large the demand-supply relation­
ship shifts to oversupply and rates tend to be low.

Given the high level of

demand for funds that has doubled total debt, it is no wonder that rates have
moved up in the last twelve years.

Given the high level of Federal Government

demand to finance a deficit, there is no wonder that rates on Governments have
moved higher in the last year.
You will recall that I spoke of two sources of supply - savings and
bank credit.

The former comes from income and does not increase the supply of

money - merely the supply of funds available to lend.
a dollar not spent.

A dollar saved is obviously

The demand for current output of goods and services is not

increased in the total.
This is not the case with new bank credit for it does increase the
money supply and thus add to the total amount of funds.

It is in this area that

the Federal Reserve works - its policies lead to more or less new bank credit new money - additions to the total supply of funds.
Now the Federal Reserve does not favor high rates or low rates.
favors rates low enough to
adequate saving.

It

promote adequate borrowing and high enough to promote

These rates change with changing conditions in a free market.

Unless they change, they cannot measure and equate demand and supply.

So the

Federal Reserve does not strive for any given level of rates but merely for a



-

6

-

level of bank credit which leads to a given pattern of rates determined by
the market.
In a situation like the present, if the Federal Reserve were to p r o ­
mote more bank credit, the supply of funds would increase,
rates might fall.
price increases.

For a short time

But the money supply would build up and would lead to
This would raise total demand for funds and rates would rise.

Again more bank credit would be created, again fund supply would rise, again
prices would rise, and again demand for funds would raise rates^
familiar inflation spiral.

This is the

The point is, of course, that you can never catch up.

Now, one last point on interest rates and I will have finished this
discussion.

Who gets the benefit of higher rates - how much does it raise costs

and how much does it add to financial institution revenues and take away from
individuals and government.
Well, interest rates are a minor factor in costs.

In 1957, for

example, interest costs of all manufacturing corporations amounted to .4 of
one per cent of sales or $4 on every $1,000 of selling price.
much.

That is not very

Most people do not stop borrowing because rates move up; they stop b e ­

cause the supply of credit is curtailed.
In 1946 our total Federal interest payments were $4.7 billion.
year they were $7.6 billion or about $3 billion more,

Last

Who got this increase?

Well, half of it went to Government investment accounts (Social Security, etc.)
or to the Federal Reserve which has a very large portfolio.
it went directly to Government and to the people.

In the former case

In the latter case 9/10 went

to Government since Federal turns back 90 per cent of its earnings to the Treasury.
A quarter of the difference - $700 million - went to individuals,
mostly to holders of Savings bonds.

Almost all of the remainder - $800 million -

went to businesses, local or state governments, or miscellaneous investors.
Commercial banks collected just $100 million more; mutual savings banks
no more, and insurance companies $200 million less.



In 1946 these financial

7

-

-

institutions got 45 per cent of Federal interest payments; last year they got
26 per cent.
Well, what was to be a minor digression has turned out to be a major
speech.

It is important to recognize some of the real facts about interest

rates, however.

The President1s request is not a capricious one - no borrower

wants to pay more than he has to.
with other borrowers.

The Government has to compete for funds

It gets rates lower than most borrowers - it always has

and probably always will because its credit is good.

But it cannot get rates

lower than people are willing to lend money.
To get back to my main line, is there any benefit to growth in infla­
tion?

A look at the statistical record will, I believe, show no necessary

connection between inflation on the one hand and economic growth or high e m ­
ployment on the other.

If we take the quarter century 1934 through 1958, we

find that wholesale prices have advanced 145 per cent and consumer prices 116
per cent over that period.

This same period saw real output, without price

change, expand by 186 per cent.

About nine-tenths of this wholesale price

rise and almost four-fifths of the consumer price rise occurred between 1939
and 1951.

This, of course, is the period that saw the defense build-up, World

War II and its aftermath, and Korea.

Or to turn the example around, only one-

tenth of the wholesale price rise and one-fifth of the consumer price rise took
place in peacetime, classing the present cold war period as peacetime.

In

contrast to this, 40 per cent of the gain in real output occurred in the
"peacetime11 period and just 60 per cent in the years 1939-1951.
It seems to me that there is little if anything in this longer term
record to indicate any causal connection between inflation and growth.

Of

course, general economic theory and history both lead to the conclusion that
inflation tends to work against rather than for growth, and the record is con­
sistent with that conclusion.




-

8

-

As if these were not compelling enough reasons for promoting price
stability, a new factor has begun to appear recently on the international scene.
Recent reports suggest that U. S. goods are losing out more and more
in world markets as a result of price factors - even in western hemisphere m a r ­
kets which were for so long considered untouchable by European or Orient
competition.

While evidence on this point is fragmentary, there is some indi­

cation that prices of manufactured goods from the U. S. have gone up more rapidly
over the past several years than those of such competitors as United Kingdom,
Germany, Italy, and Japan.

It seems clear that price competition is becoming

much more important today and by all signs can be expected to continue to in­
tensify in the future.
Already, because of our growing deficit balance and the new configura­
tion of competitive factors that is emerging, it is becoming clear that we must
move toward balance in trade as a national policy.

We should not approach such

a balance by reducing our imports - we cannot win that game.

So, we must as a

national objective move toward increasing our exports by all practical means.
It becomes a matter of critical concern to prevent the gradual creep of infla­
tion from deteriorating our competitive position in free world markets if we
are not to hamper our economic growth through a declining share in world trade.
To take a rather sharp change of pace in this talk for just a
moment, we might consider the different sort of interest that we as bankers
have in growth viewed on a regional scale.

Favorable climate for growth on

the national scene is, of course, a desirable prerequisite to healthy state and
regional growth.

When we get down to examining growth in our region, however,

an entirely different set of factors enters and a whole new focus is brought
about.

Our experience, to be sure, has been one of sharing in the growth of

our national economy.

Yet when we examine it we also see that our particular

region has somewhat different problems from many other regions and as a conse­
quence has not shared equally in the expansion.



-

9

-

Our experience stems largely from two facts.

First, agriculture

is in the midst of a long-standing technological revolution.

In the short

period since 1940, crop yields per acre have increased 40 per cent, produc­
tivity per animal breeding unit has increased 30 per cent and output per farm
worker has more than doubled with the resultant release of population from
farm areas to other sectors of the economy.

Second, we are the most

A g r i c u l t u r a l 1' of all the Federal Reserve districts.

About 25 per cent of

our people still live on farms and ranches - twice the national average.
This means w e fve got a much larger than average source of supply of people
wanting to move from farm to town, and indeed if we were to accommodate all
these people within our region, we would have to offer a correspondingly
larger-than-average increase in employment opportunities in the non-agricultural
sector of our economy.
Yet, in fact, the over-all expansion of markets and manufacturing
in the Ninth district has tended to be not larger, but rather somewhat smaller
than the national average during the postwar period.

Let me illustrate:

between the two Censuses of Manufactures of the years 1947 and 1954, the
dollar value added by manufacture increased for all industries in the U. S.
by 56 per cent, whereas the corresponding increase in the Ninth district was
only 48 per cent.

Even the district's number one industry, food processing,

increased only 28 per cent compared with a national average increase of
32 per cent.
The net result is that the Ninth district as a region has shown a
declining share of the nation's population.
all the people in this country.

In 1910, we had 5.7 per cent of

Today we have 3.8 per cent.

We have grown

in total numbers, but the rest of the country has grown more.
Business and public leaders alike have from time to time expressed
concern over one aspect or another of this situation.

Might not the establish­

ment of a reputation as a slow-growth region unduly jeopardize our chances to



-

10

-

share in the expansion plans of, say, the larger national corporations?
Then, too, questions haye been raised about the significance of
lower per capita income here.

In 1956, for example, per capita income for

the four full district states was $1661, compared to a $1940 national average
(the Montana figure was $1862).

Are we actually less well off then other

sections of the country?
Others pointed to an unwanted side effect of population movements.
Because of the greater mobility of younger workers, (those, say, in their
2 0 ?s and 3 0 rs) the age distribution of our region1s population has been
modified over recent years to give us an increasing proportion of the very
young and the very old relative to the national distribution.

This tendency

for young people, in particular, to migrate out of the district raises various
questions.

For example, can our states afford to provide higher education for

many who will later migrate to other areas?

How may economic opportunities

in this area be expanded so as to reverse this trend?

Further, is such e x ­

pansion not impeded by the loss of younger, more aggressive members of the
labor force?
Community development and area development are concepts that have
been given great play in recent years.

Considering the problem now from a

region-wide standpoint, is there something that might be done by regional
study and action to improve our growth picture relative to the rest of the
nation?

This is a question for which we have no really good answer available

at the present time.

I would like to point out here that a comprehensive

regional study is now getting underway to investigate just that question.
While this is not the occasion to go into the details of the program, you
will be interested to know that this program, to be carried out under the
direction of the non-profit Upper Midwest Research and Development Council,
will be of unprecedented sc ope, involving ultimately several hundred thousand




-

11

-

dollars in research effort and will represent something of a pioneering
effort in regional cooperative studies.
As leaders in your respective communities, and as practitioners of
the profession of banking, I think you are all concerned with the question
of growth as it has been here discussed - both on a national scale, with all
the serious overtones this carries, and on a regional scale, with its sharply
contrasting set of considerations.
Yet these two phases of growth share common bonds.

Establishment

of proper policies and action with respect to each involves an intelligent
evaluation of our goals; it involves an understanding of the nature and
function of growth in our economy; and certainly, as my opening illustration
would point out, an understanding of the errors and pitfalls in accurately
measuring growth.

Further, it is clear that "growth for growth1s sake11 has

no place in either the regional or the national picture.

While we recognize

the desirability of growth, and in fact, its necessity if we are to preserve
the ways we cherish, we must never lose sight of our basic framework of freedom;
it is individual choice working through the market that is the basic mechanism
for effecting the right kind and amount of growth in our society.
The price of growth is not creeping inflation.

The price of growth,

of real and substantial growth - if it has a "price11 - is a proper acceptance
of the adjustments that freedom of choice and changing technology inject into
our economy and of the restraints that are from ti e to time necessary to
prevent self-fueling excesses from acting to the detriment of enduring growth
over the long run.