View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

MONEY

M A T T E R S

Talk given by
Frederick L. Dealing
President, Federal Reserve
of Minneapolis

Bank

At
Conference
of
Production Credit Association
Directors, SecretaryTreasurers
and Field Representatives

Louisville, Kentucky
April 15, 1957

MONEY MATTERS

I am supposed to talk to you this afternoon about money matters.
This kind of title gives me a lot of latitude and I intend to use it and
talk about the impact of money and credit policy upon the economy, particularly
about the impact upon interest rates and their effect upon economic life.
This is of importance to you people because currently about 11 percent
of the total capital in agriculture is borrowed capital or debt.

A little more

than half of this $18 billion in farm debt is secured by farm real estate •slightly less than half is secured by other farm assets or is loaned without
security.
In dollar volume, the trend of farm debts has been rather steadily
upward.

Real estate obligations of farmers increased an estimated 9 percent

during 1956 —

non-real-estate debts by a more moderate increase.

The rate

of increase is non-real-estate farm debts seems to have slowed measurably
during recent months.
It seems to me that it might be well to begin by trying to define
what money and credit policy is supposed to do and why.

Expressed in very

simple terms, monetary and credit policy is simply an effort to answer the
question:

How much money should the country have?

In this use, "money"

means both bank deposits and currency; together these form the money supply
of the nation.

By far the larger portion of the money supply is "checkbook

money" or bank deposits*
The broad objective of monetary policy then is to keep the supply
of money in reasonable balance with the supply of goods and services in the
economy.

Again in simple terms, too much money tends to drive prices up, too

little tends to inhibit economic growth and development.

There have been

periods in our lifetime when the economy experienced unnecessarily severe



** 2 -

setbacks for lack of money, and other times when many people were injured
because there was too much money chasing a supply of goods and services that
could not be expanded quickly, the classic inflationary situation.
The job of trying to determine how much money and credit should
be supplied to the economy is tough and difficult.
much or too little money are both bad.
little is a "right" amount.

As I noted earlier, too

Somewhere between too much and too

The difficulty comes because there is no magic

formula to tell how much is "right".

Decisions have to be based on compre-

hensive and continuing analysis of the whole complex economy.

This means

that a lot of information has to be studied, analyzed and digested.

And in

the final analysis, the very important factor of judgment comes in.

Someone

once said that central banking is an art and not a science.

It is based on

the judgment of men who are supposed to know enough to know that economic
relationships change, that economics is concerned with people who are not
very predictable, and that good central banking never tries to consult itself
for long periods in the future but is a continuous process.
Having given the what and part of the why of monetary policy, it
may be well to add this note, also partly the answer to why.

We have to have

monetary and credit policy to keep the supply of money in balance with the
needs of the economy, because if we did not the balance probably would be
lacking most of the time.

A famous British economist said, almost a hundred

years ago, "Money will not manage itself".

At one time, far in the past,

when money consisted mostly of gold and silver and when economic affairs were
fairly simple, regulation of the money supply was not so important —
even then it got out of balance every once in a while.

although

In the past two hundred

years, however, we have had a series of industrial revolutions and the economy
today is a very complex thing.

Modern finance also is pretty complicated and

we now have a money system with great flexibility to contract or expand upon




- 3 -

demand.

Thus the phrase "Money will not manage itself" is even more applicable

today than it was when first stated.
You might think of the situation in this way.

Back in the horse and

buggy days, when there was not much traffic, you could in a pinch let the
horse find his way home without guidance and be reasonably sure of getting
there.

Today, even with power steering and automatic transmissions, it would

hardly be regarded as good driving to try to let the modern auto do that.
And, actually the simile would be more pertinent if we compared the horse and
buggy to the jet airplane.
Well, so much for the first aspects of "what" and "why".

Now, let's

look into the question of "how” money and credit policy tends to work.
approaching that question it seems desirable to provide a setting.

And in

Both because

the basic trand since World War XX has been inflation and because the story of
"how" can be illustrated best against an inflationary background, I take the
familiar Inflationary spiral as the backdrop to the discussion.
Once in operation, an inflationary spiral has strong tendencies to
feed upon itself.

Because prices are generally expected to rise, the incentive

to save is diminished and the incentive to spend is increased.

With the economy

operating at relatively full capacity, further increases in spending simply
cannot result in quick corresponding increases in production, but instead are
expressed in mounting prices, wages and costs.

These developments tend to

undermine the very foundations of balanced industrial growth.

They lead to

imbalances of productive capacity and of credit and may set the stage for hard
problems of readjustment later on.
It is important to recognize, however, that the inflationary spiral
can never go very far without additions to the money supply, because as prices,
wages and costs rise more and more money is needed to finance transactions.
More intensive use can be made of existing money, but there seem to be limits




-4 -

to this expedient.

Fundamentally, without an increasing money supply the

feed*back, spiral effect of inflation cannot go very far.
Now, you know that the money supply increases mainly as a result
of increases in bank loans and investments.
loans and investments in this country
reserves.

In turn, any increase in bank

has to be based on increases in bank

The primary job of the Federal Reserve is to regulate the supply,

cost and availability of bank reserves and thereby to influence the volume
of money and credit in the economy. Money and credit policy thus works through
its effects on the availability, cost and supply of credit and thus affects
lenders and borrowers. It goes beyond this and affects
money and credit.

the total supply of

And finally, its effects are reflected in spending and

saving decisions of individuals and businesses.
Right here I think we can say something about interest rates.

To

get some perspective on this point let's go back a few years in time for our
comparisons and look at a few representative rate figures.

You will recall

that back in March 1951 the Federal Reserve-Treasury accord resulted in Federal
stopping its support operations in the government security market.

At that

time Treasury bills sold at about 1.4 percent, long-term governments were just
under 2 1/2 percent, triple A corporates were about 2 3/4 percent, and the
big city bank prime rate was 2 1/2 percent.
While there have been changes both up and down since that date, the
current rate picture is about as follows:

Treasury bills over 3 percent, long­

term governments about 3 1/4 percent, triple A corporates just under 3 3/4 percent,
and the prime rate 4 percent.
Now, I want to make just three points about these changes.

First,

Federal Reserve policy has not aimed at any given level of interest rates.
The current rate pattern is a result of policy and not pplicy itself.

I'll say

a little more about this later, but the point here is that the rate increase



- 5 -

reflects demand and supply relationships in the money markets.

Supply has

risen but demand has risen faster and rates have moved up.
Second, higher interest rates do deter some potential borrowers from
borrowing.

These are the marginal cases, of course.

While interest cost is

generally a small cost factor on short-term loans, it is a bigger factor on
long-term borrowings and some businesses and individuals find that their
marginal projects are simply not profitable under higher interest costs.
These are relatively few, as they should be.
Third, lenders are affected strongly by rising interest costs because
such rate changes affect the values of existing securities.
prices move opposite to yields.

You all know that

Thus when rates rise because credit demand

increases, lenders have to make some decisions about selling portfolio securities
to meet new loan demand or buy different securities.

What they do depends on

the relative position, of course, but they don't automatically ditch portfolio
at a loss just to make new loans or investments at higher rates.

They look at

the whole picture and may decide to hold back on new loans and investments - in
other words, they begin to screen credits.
A general tightening or easing of credit affects lenders in all
sectors of the credit market, from short-term to long-term.

The major suppliers

of short and intermediate term funds are the commercial banks whose loan and
investment expansion or contraction tends to expand or contract the volume of
money.

The supply of bank credit varies with bank reserve positions which are

influenced by monetary policy.

Other lenders also exist, however, in this

sector of the money and investment market and supply funds from their cash
balances.

The volume of such investment varies with the attractiveness of the

interest return.

The total supply of short-term credit thus is very flexible,

responsive to interest rate return and to actions affecting bank reserves.




- 6

the supply of long-term funds is closely related to the volume of
saving.

Individuals, insurance companies, savings banks, savings and loan

associations, etc., operate in long-term funds.

So do cmramercial banks

through their purchases of real estate loans and long-term securities.

The

supply of investment funds is relatively fixed, however, and does not respond
quickly to changes in demand.

When demand runs high, therefore, there tends

to be some spillover into the short-term credit market.

We saw some of that

in 195&, particularly.
Now, let us become a little more specific about monetary and credit
policy and its influence on the economy and on sources of loan funds over the
past year.

Against the background of high level economic activity, sparked

by a tremendous boom in capital expenditures for new plant and equipment, the
demand for credit and capital became increasingly heavy.

The volume of savings

in the economy, while quite high, proved to be smaller than the demand for such
savings and some of that demand spilled over into the short-term credit field,
particularly into bank credit.

At the same time the demand for general short­

term credit also was very heavy.
The monetary authorities thus have been faced with the problem of
either supplying sufficient reserves to create a credit base, which plus
savings, would be adequate to meet all credit demand, or supplying something
less than that amount.

To supply all reserves wanted to meet all demand would

have meant that the boom could have its head, probably at the price of a
headache later.

To supply less meant that credit would tighten.

The policy followed, designed to moderate the boom, forced the credit
grantors to become somewhat more selective in their loans and investments.
Interest rates rose and the values of existing assets, particularly financial
assets, declined somewhat.

This latter development brought about some reluctance

to shift out of existing assets to obtain funds for new loans and investments,



which in turn reacted on the availability and price of credit and capital.
This process tended to result in screening out less economically desirable
demand in order to satisfy more economically desirable demand.
I want to underline the point that this screening process is the
method under which our form of market economy determines the economic worth
of ventures requiring capital and credit.
direct and indirect.

The process of screening is both

It is direct in that certain loans are rejected out­

right} these are the marginal eases.

It is indirect in that most loans and

investments tend to cost the borrower more which causes him to re-evaluate
his projects and in some cases to defer or abandon them.
It is sometimes asserted that this process Involves hurting people;
that all borrowers should find some source to meet all credit demand.

It

seems to me that this point of view overlooks completely one basic fact.

The

resources of this economy are not unlimited} the very nature of economic re­
sources is that they are relatively scarce.

Actually, an important part of

the field of economics Involves study of the efficient use of scarce resources
so as to "economize" in their use.

If money, which commands resources, were

unlimited in amount, in theory anyone could command resources.

But to put it

in another and more pertinent way, if money were unlimited it would really
command no resources because it would be worth little or nothing.

Let me come back to what I think Is an important point here.

Credit

tightness is simply a result of the availability or supply of credit being
reduced relative to the demand for it.

It comes about either because credit

supply is reduced or because it does not grow as fast as demand grows.
boom this second development is typical.

In a

Credit conditions tend to tighten

even when there is an increase in the supply of credit, as there has been,
simply because the inorease is less than the increase in demand.
is the one characteristic of the past year and a half.



This situation

If credit did not tighten

during a boom, it would mean that monetary policy was not doing Its job and
was letting supply expand as fast as demand set by b o m was expanding.

In

other words, it would mean that the boom itself was setting the pace, regardless
of the inflationary or other unsound developments that might be occurring.
When interest rates rise, as they have risen during the past year.
In a context of (1) high-level employment, (2) output pressing on limits of
capacity, (3) rising costs and prices, (4-) increased velocity of money, and
(5) deterioration of bank liquidity and corporate working capital ratios, and
when all of these developments occur at a time of continued stability and some
growth la the money supply, the only real explanation is that plans for invest­
ment in the aggregate are in excess of current savings*

It follows, also, in

this context that money cannot cease to be tight and equilibrium be restored
unless either savings Increase sufficiently to meet investment demands, or
investment plans are scaled down to toe availability of savings, or that a
balance is achieved by a combination of both.
If the Federal Reserve System should disregard its mandate and
release more reserves to toe member banks, this would not relieve toe situation.
Bather, it would accentuate it, for toe cosraercial banks would then lend more
to potential borrowers seeking loans.

These borrowers, with money in hand,

would enter the markets to add their bids for scarce goods and scarce services
to bids already there.

The effect would be to spark an inflationary spiral

and to accelerate toe rise in prices, wages and costs.
more money would be needed to finance transactions.

As a consequence, even

When the circle had worked

itself out, money still would be tight because the basic economic requirements
had not been met, i.e., saving had not come into equilibrium with demands for
investment.




, 9 Now, the Federal Reserve System has, in fact, mitigated the rise
of interest rates during the past year in the sense that it has increased
somewhat the volume of reserves made available to its member banks, and, to
Use extent that increased loans and increased spending were made possible by
these releases, the System shares in some part responsibility for the price
advances that have occurred.

It did not release reserves in sufficient volume,

however, to neutralize the economic force© that were the fundamental cause of
the rise in interest rates.

Throughout the past year, as a result, commercial

banks have operated within a general environment of restraint that helped to
temper the exuberance of the boom.
Most mortgage lenders have been influenced to some extent by tight
money conditions.

Most have made upward adjustments in their interest charges

on farm mortgage loans, and in many cases the terms and selectivity in lending
have further reinforced this trend.
Tight money conditions appear not to have affected the availability
or cost of non-real-estate loans to farmers as much as in the ease of farm
mortgage loans.

Most farm lenders appear to be meeting the credit needs of

their regular farm customers for operating purposes.

Those lending agencies

which obtain their funds directly from the money market have probably been
more sensitive to over-all changes in credit availability than lenders who
obtained the bulk of their funds from local or regional sources.
Present conditions can hardly be characterised as boom conditions,
of course.

The economy seems to be moving generally sidewise at a very high

level, a situation that is all to the good.

There are some soft spots but

these are, on balance, offset by strength in other areas.
to be reasonably bright —

The outlook seems

a bigger year than 1956 but not much bigger.

is a little easier which reflects a relative shift in demand and supply.
has increased a little from savings.



Honey
Supply

- 10 -

Monetary policy, I believe, can take some credit in bringing
about this high level stability*

Obviously it cannot take all of the credit

for other factors have been at work.
Perhaps X had better put one qualification into the picture at
this point*

You, of course, know it already but I cite it for the record.

Money policy, by itself, cannot restrain inflation nor stop deflation.

It

can create the proper conditions but it eaxmot do the whole job*
This is particularly evident when we consider the "cost-push" type
of inflation, for example, the familiar cycle of wage pressures, higher costs
and higher prices.
monetary policy.

And this kind of development poses a major dilemma for
Should it "underwrite" higher cost-prloe structures by

releasing more reserves to form the base for a larger money supply?

Or

should it hold down growth in the money supply unless paralleled by growth
in real output in the face of a possible rise in unemployment because resource
use cannot be shifted quickly?
Monetary policy during the past year has avoided both horns of this
dilemma only in part.

It has underwritten some of the higher cost-prlce structure

but not all of it by any means.

And it has avoided rising unemployment.

In fact, it has been able to do this because we have experienced what
is called rolling adjustment.

This is the situation in which first one kind

of demand and then another acts as the driving force in the econooy while the
other demands fall off, thus keeping total demand more or less equal to total
capacity.

The mutual interdependence of the various kinds of demand so far

have not led to any cumulative downturn when one kind fell off*

Thus when

auto demand dropped last year, it did not set off a chain reaction*
plant construction demand picked up the slack.




Instead,

- 11 -

Gan this kind of rolling adjustment continue to lead us on toward
economic growth with stability?
to that question.

I don’t know, of course, the absolute answer

I hope that some of the desand that has been deferred will

pop up again if other demand falters.

Tight credit Itself has helped defer

some demand} easier credit, should it prove necessary, could translate that
deferred demand into current demand, particularly state and local government
construction and possibly residential construction,
I am convinced that money and credit policy should not “underwrite*
the full amount of higher cost-price structure by supplying sufficient bank
credit to meet all demand, both strong and weak.
inflation with all its evil®.

That way leads to outright

Bather we should move toward making free

markets work as best they can by removing institutional rigidities such as
legal limitations on interest rates payable on mortgages or school bonds,
etc.

These keep people who want schools or homes from competing for funds

in free markets.
Hie alternative to free markets is sheltered markets - sheltered
by subsidy, guarantee, or tax benefits.

But again I note that resources at

any given time are limited and making sheltered markets for resources limits
supply for unsheltered markets.

In a free society not everyone can be

sheltered} if everyone is, the society is not free.