View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FINANCING SOUTHERN A G R I C U L T U R E
Speech by Darryl R. Francis, President,
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, at
Annual Stockholders Meeting,
Federal Land Bank of New Orleans,
Biloxi, Mississippi, July 30, 1963
Agriculture has played a major part in the nation's
economic growth in recent decades. Farm employment has
declined substantially, releasing a large number of workers to
other sectors. Farm output has continued, however, to expand
rapidly. New capital inputs per farm have been a major
contributor to rising agricultural efficiency. Capital inputs
increasingly have been made through the use of credit in recentyears.
Credit costs and the efficiency of credit flows into
agriculture are thus important factors contributing to progress in
both the farm and nonfarm sector. It is to these costs and flows
that this discussion is directed.
Nationally, farm employment declined from 10.3 million
workers in 1930 to less than 4 million in 1967. The decline,which
averaged 2.6 per cent per year during the 37 year period,

accelerated

to 4.6 per cent after 1960. Reflecting both sizable gains in
total employment and reduced farm employment, farm as a per
cent of total declined from 22.7 per cent in 1930 to 5.2 per cent
in 1967.




-2In contrast to reduced labor inputs, the physical volume
of farm output has increased sharply. Production rose from 60
per cent of the 1957-59 average in 1930 to 118 per cent in 1967.
Thus, in 1967 the nation's farms produced almost double the 1930
level. In current dollars, farm products marketed more than
quadrupled during the period, rising from $90 billion to $42.5
billion. The retail value of farm products rose at a still higher
rate, with food, beverage, and tobacco sales increasing from $19.4
billion in 1930 to $115.4 billion in 1966, a sixfold gain.
As a result of these gains in productivity, a relatively
small per cent of the nation's labor force is used to meet farm
product demands. Of the major industrial nations for which
data are provided by the Organization for Economic Cooperation
and Development, the United States has the lowest per cent of
workers directly employed in agriculture. Farm employment in
the 1960's ranged from 6.1 per cent of the labor force in the U.S.
to 74.5 per cent in Turkey.
In Western Europe, one of the most highly developed
areas outside the U. S., about 20 per cent was engaged in agriculture. Nevertheless, output still failed to meet the area's
demand for food and fiber. A sizable portion of farm products




-3consumed had to be imported. In the relatively underdeveloped
areas such as Africa, India, and Latin America, which combined
account for about three fourths of the world's population, more
than half the work force is usually engaged in producing food.
Thus, while people in the United States are living in a land of
abundance, much of the world is still subject to the Malthusian
laws of scarcity.
Contributing to our efficiency gains in agriculture have
been numerous scientific developments that have provided new
technology on a wide front. Mechanization technology has made
possible large multirow cultivating and harvesting equipment
and other labor-saving machines which have greatly expanded
the optimal size of farms. Improved methods of plant and animal
breeding have increased the productivity of crops and livestock.
New chemicals, including insecticides, fungicides, herbicides,
and fertilizers have enabled producers to greatly increase output
per acre and reduce labor per unit of production.
These gains involved major changes in the structure of
agriculture. In addition to the sharp decline in farm employment,
corresponding decreases occurred in the number of farms. On
the other hand, capital inputs have increased sharply. The value
of all farm assets rose from $52.9 billion in 1940 to $269.4 billion
in 1967. Although part of the increase represents price inflation,




-4sizable new capital inputs have been made. Acres in farms rose 7
per cent and capitalization of land, through soil improvement,
drainage and other means, has increased substantially. The
number of cattle on farms rose from 68 million in 1940 to 108
-million in 1967. Tractors, including garden tractors, rose from
1.5 to 5.6 million during the period.
Although farm technology has contributed to the rising
capitalization of the industry, it has had a greater impact on
capital readjustments within agriculture. In 1940 farm assets
represented an average of $8,331 invested in each of the 6.3
million farms. By 1967 the number of farms had been
halved, while capital per farm had increased tenfold to $85,654.
These capital adjustments within the industry, coupled with new
capital inputs, have greatly increased farm demands for outside
funds.
Outside credit has never played a major role in financing
agriculture, as most farms have largely been financed internally.
Much of the physical capital such as land clearing, drainage,
fencing, and building was produced on the farm by the farm family.
Only in the past few decades has a large portion of farm capital
been acquired through off-farm purchases, and many of such
costs were covered by family savings.




-5Since 1943 credit used by farmers has not exceeded 17
per cent of total farm assets, and in the 6 years prior to 1954 was
less than 10 per cent of total farm assets. In comparison, credit
used by manufacturing establishment, on the basis of book value,
never fell below 28 per cent of total assets. Furthermore, in 1967
debt exceeded 40 per cent of the assets of these firms.
Although the spread in debt-to-asset ratios of farms and
manufacturing firms remains quite wide, it has declined steadily
since 1948, when debts totaling 33.2 per cent of assets in manufacturing were 4.3 times the per cent of debts to assets in agriculture. Since then,debt-to-assetratios in both industries have
risen steadily. However, the ratio in agriculture rose at a greater
rate than in manufacturing, and in 1967 the debt-to-asset ratio
in manufacturing was only 2.4 times that in agriculture. Thus,
internal financing of agriculture has declined substantially relative
to total capital since 1948, and credit has played an increasing role
in capital accumulation.
Sources of Farm Credit
With the rising volume of debt, farm credit sources have also
changed. The change, however, has been gradual rather than
revolutionary. It is when we view changes over the past half
century that major contrasts appear. Significant changes have




-6occurred in both the number of competitor groups in the business
and the relative portion of credit supplied by each.
Mortgage Lenders
Prior to the 1900's most farm mortgage credit was supplied
by individuals and other noninstitutional sources. Since the turn
of the century, a relative decline has occurred in farm mortgage
credit supplied by noninstitutional lenders. Conversely, the per
cent supplied by institutional lenders has consistently increased.
For example, in 1910 institutional lenders supplied only 25 per cent
of the nation's outstanding farm mortgage credit, while in 1967 the
proportion supplied by financial institutions had increased to 60
per cent. Despite the increased use of land contracts, which tend
to increase seller-financed farm transfers, the per cent of such
debt held by institutions has remained stable since 1960.
Only to major institutional lender groups, commercial
and savings banks, and life insurance companies, were in the
farm mortgage credit business in 1910. With the creation of
the Federal Land Banks in 1916 a third major credit supplier
entered the field. And in the 1930's the farmers Home Administration (Farm Security Administration) was created to finance
high-risk farm mortgages with government assistance. The
land bank system and the Farmers' Home Administration provided
farmers with additional pipelines to the nation's financial centers.




-7Over the years, the financial institutions have supplied
an increasing proportion of the total farm mortgage credit. The
Federal Land Banks and life insurance companies, with better pipelines to financial markets, have supplied relatively larger portions than
commercial banks which rely primarily on local funds and are often short
of funds for, or reluctant to commit funds to, long-term mortgage loans.
The share held by the land banks rose steadily from the
date of their organization through the 1920's. With substantial
government assistance they undertook emergency mortgage financing in the mid-1930's, and their share rose rapidly. After the
liquidation of these loans in the 1940's and early 1950's, the land
banks' share again increased and accounted for 21 per cent of the
total in 1967. The share held by life insurance companies rose
from 12 per cent in 1910 to 22 per cent in 1967, and that held by
commercial and savings banks rose from 13 to 14 per cent of the
total during the period.
Non-Mortgage Lenders
Non-real estate farm credit supply groups have also increased
since 1910. Even to a greater extent than mortgage lenders, this
group was dominated by local suppliers well into this century. Local
banks, dealers, merchants, and other local sources were almost the
only suppliers of such credit prior to the beginning of credit extension




-8by the Federal Intermediate Credit Banks and the emergency
crop and feed loans in the mid-1920's. In the mid-1930's
the Production Credit System entered the short-term farm
credit market and have since become a major source of such loans.
Like the land bank system, the PCA's are tied to the nation's
financial markets.
It is generally believed that merchants, dealers, and other
noninstltutional lenders held at least 50 per cent of all non-real
estate farm credit prior to the 1940's. Since early 1940, however,
the position of this group has declined, and by early 1967 it accounted
for only 41 percent.
This relative decline in merchant and dealer credit occurred
despite greater access to financial markets. Merchants and dealers
who extend credit to farmers must, in turn, be financed. Prior to
the development of large agribusiness industries, most of this
financing was probably done at local banks. In recent years,
however, manufacturers who sell machinery, fertilizer, and other
products to farmers through merchants,and dealers have provided
a sizable portion of this financing. These manufacturers in turn
obtain funds through retained earnings, by selling debt and equity
instruments to the public and by borrowing directly from large city
banks. Merchants and dealers thus provide farmers with another
pipeline to financial markets.




-9Commercial banks have been the largest single institutional
supplier of non-real estate farm credit throughout the period since
1910. It is generally believed that banks supplied about 50 per cent
of such credit until the 1930's when the PCA's began operations.
Following this additional competition, the per cent held by both banks
and nonreporting creditors declined. The banks' per cent fell
-sharply in \he 1930's, picked up somewhat in the 1940's, held about
steady in the 1950's, and has declined somewhat since 1960. They
now hold 40 per cent of the total and PCA's hold 14 per cent.
Total Credit
A combination of mortgage and non-real estate farm credit
further points up the changes in farm credit supplies. On the basis
of estimates for merchant and dealer credit, which probably understate the amount of such credit in the earlier years, noninstitutional credit to farmers has declined relative to the total — from
63.7 per cent in 1910 to 40.9 per cent in 1967. This relative decline
has been fairly consistent, except for a few years immediately
following World War II when the public had an abundance of
liquid assets, and since 1960, a period of rapid expansion in the
contract selling of real estate which tends to enhance seller
financing.




-10Farm credit in the southern states has generally increased
more rapidly than in the nation. In eight states centered in the
southern Mississippi Valley,- total farm debt has increased fivefold
since 1940, slightly above the national rate of gain. The move
toward financial institutions as sources of farm credit has also
been faster in the South than for the nation as a whole. Financial
agencies probably supplied about the same per cent of non-real
estate farm credit in the area as in the nation last year. However,
financial agencies supplied a somewhat larger per cent of ail real
estate farm credit here than nationally. Insurance companies
have made especially large gains in the South since 1940. From
15 per cent of the total farm real estate debt held at that time,
their share rose to 23.4 per cent in 1967. This was 6 per cent
above the share of farm real estate debt held nationally by insurance
companies.
Impact of Market Changes on Efficiency
The impact on credit costs of changes in the market
structure of farm credit agencies is difficult to measure. Also,
the question remains unanswered of whether farmers obtain
credit on a parity with the nonfarm economy. Direct measures of

1/ Includes: Alabama, Arkansas, Florida, Georgia, Louisiana,
Mississippi, Tennessee, and Texas.




-11interest rales are not conclusive because of wide variations in
risks, and lending and collection costs. Nevertheless, actual
rate comparisons are not unfavorable to farmers. Farm credit
outstanding by banks in mid-1966 was at lower average rates
than 1966 yields on all bank loans. Also, Federal Land Bank
rates on farm mortgages were below most nonfarm rates.
Rising Efficiency in Channeling Funds
The large increase in farm credit and the relatively
small advance in interest rates point to rising efficiency in
gathering and channeling funds into agriculture. Since 1945
total farm credit outstanding has increased almost sixfold,
rising from $7.6 billion to $44.5 billion. Interest rates, rates
charged farmers, rose at a relatively slow pace. For example,
prime commercial loan rates rose from 1.5 per cent in 1947 to
5.7 per cent in 1966, an increase of 275 per cent. Average rates
on ail bank loans rose about 90 per cent during the period, and
on FHA new home mortgages, 50 per cent. In comparison,
farm mortgage rates by FLB's rose only 46 per cent, and PCA
rates advanced only 28 per cent. Commercial bank rates on
non-real estate loans to farmers increased 12 per cent, while
bank rates on farm real estate loans rose 29 per cent.




-12Return on Assets
Another measure of the efficiency of credit flows into
agriculture is the rate of return on farm assets. A creditstarved agriculture would suggest high returns and low market
prices on productive assets.
Returns on current market value of productive assets in
-agriculture, however, are relatively low, and market prices of
assets relatively high. Since 1959 the rate of return on farm assets
has averaged only about 5 per cent. This is less than the average
return on book value of assets in any of the 61 major industries
listed in Standard and Poor's Industry Surveys.
Productivity Measures
Another measure of the efficiency of credit flows into
agriculture is the efficiency of the industry itself. Inefficient
resource flows into agriculture would tend to reduce the performance
-of the industry. In terms of productivity over time and productivity
relative to that in other nations, hoy/ever, farming is quite efficient.
The farm credit market may be summarized as follows:
1. Farm credit, like farming itself, is becoming more commercial and less dependent on relative, friend, neighbor, and
merchant relationships. Financial institutions currently supply
more than 69 per cent of the total, and their portion has generally




-13increased over the years, with the exception of a short period
following World War II when the noninstitutional group had
excessive quantities of loanable funds.
2. With the entry of more financial institutions into the
farm credit business and the relative decline of nonfinancial
institution lending, farm credit suppliers have become less
personal. This tends toward greater efficiency in the industry.
Credit and credit purchased resources tend to flow to the more
efficient users as determined by the impersonal officials of the
financial agencies. Those users, in turn provide the greatest
returns to capital and can more readily repay debts.
3. The closer ties of farm credit to financial markets, as
represented by life insurance companies, the Farm Credit
Administration, large agribusiness corporations supplying credit
through dealers, and to a lesser extent commercial banks, through
the correspondent banking system, assures a more reliable supply
of farm credit. With such ties, credit at some price will probably
be available to any farmer in the absence of legal restrictions,
provided he meets the lender's usual credit requirements. The
same sources of funds, however, reflect relatively wide interest
rate fluctuations, and credit agencies which rely on them must
ultimately reflect such rate changes in loans to farmers.




-144. With the increase in competition for farm credit
business, credit flows to agriculture are apparently quite efficient.
Rates charged farmers have not increased since 1947 as much as other
rales. The return on farm assets is relatively low, suggesting an
adequate supply of credit for capita! purchases. Farm production in
the U. S. is efficient compared with farm production in other
countries. This would indicate relatively efficient flows of all
resources into farming, including credit, an important factor in
the organization of efficient farm units. Despite the increased
efficiency of credit flows to agriculture, rates charged farmers
have risen with generally rising rates in other sectors of the economy.
Now that farm credit is closely tied to the nation's financial
markets, factors which determine the cost of loan funds nationally
also determine the cost of credit to farmers. Such factors work in
about the same manner as those which determine the price of any
other commodity or service. They affect both the supply and demand
for credit. On the supply side we have the savings of individuals
and corporations and credit creation through monetary actions by
the central bank. On the demand side we have the credit demands
of business, consumers, and government.
The supply and demand for credit caused sharp rises in
interest rates during recent years. Since mid-1965 rates on most
securities have increased about 1.5 percentage points. Rates paid




-15by the Farm Credit Banks on bond and debenture sales have
followed this genera! upward trend. Rates paid by commercial
banks on time deposits have likewise increased. These agencies
must in turn charge higher rates to their customers. Some of
the increase has been absorbed by smaller margins. Most of the
financial agencies, however, have operated over the years quite
efficiently, and such absorptions can only be continued for a
limited time and for limited amounts. All borrowers must
eventually feel the impact of the higher cost of funds.
We are all interested in the cause of this sharp rise in
the cost of funds to financial agencies during the past three
years. In explanation, I shall again look at the supply and demand
forces relative to loan funds. Supplies of funds flowing into the
market continued to increase at a high rate during the period.
Savings expanded both in absolute amount and relative to total
personal income. Credit created through monetary action rose
at a higher rate than in the three prior years 1962-65 when rates
were relatively stable. Apparently the reason for the rapid increase
is the very high rate of gain in demand for credit.
Indicative of some of the major increases in demand for
loan funds are the following data:
1. During the three years ending in 1967 business loans
at banks rose $9.3 billion per year. In comparison, such loans




-16rose only $4.1 billion per year during the prior three years.
2. New security issues for financing business rose
$3.6 billion per year, more than ten times the rate during the
earlier period.
3. Net Government debt rose $7.4 billion per year
compared with an increase of $5.8 billion per year in the
earlier period.
4. Consumer loans rose at a rate of $3.5 billion compared
with an earlier increase of $2.8 billion per year.
5. Farm credit rose at a rate of $3.6 billion compared
with an earlier rate of $2.9 billion.
All of these credit increases were made despite the sharp
increase in interest rates, thus pointing to a sharp increase in
demand for credit.
As indicated, this sharp rise in demand for loan funds
developed in both the Government and private sectors. The rise
in Government demand is based primarily on political decisions
rather than market forces. Through the political process we
decided to increase expenditures both for military and welfare
purposes at faster rates than tax intake rose.
In the private sector, however, the rising demand for
loan funds reflects the excessive demand for goods and services




-17which has been generated by overly expansive monetary and fiscal
policies.
Fiscal policy became somewhat expansive in the first half
of the 1969 decade and more expansive as the decade progressed.
Over the period 1961 to 1965, prior to the Vietnam buildup, these
expenditures increased at an average 8.5 per cent annual rale.
Greater spending since 1966 has caused the Treasury to borrow a
larger volume of funds from the public. The Government's highemployment budget, a measure of fiscal stimulation, has been in
deficit at an annual rate of about $11 billion in the last three
quarters, compared with an average surplus of $8.2 billion in the
pre-Vietnam, 1961-65 period.
Monetary policy has tended to follow the course of
fiscal policy, becoming more expansive over the course of the
1960's. Between 1961 and 1965 the nation's money stock grew
at an average annual rate of 3.2 per cent. In marked contrast,
since January of 1967 the monetary stock has risen at a 7 per
cent rate, the fastest growth over any 18-month period since
World War I I .




-18Paralleling these expansive government influences has been
a growth in total demand for goods and services far exceeding the rate
of output and resulting in substantial price inflation. Since the
second quarter of last year expenditures on goods and services
have risen at the annual rate of 9 per cent. In contrast, output
has increased at a 5 per cent rate, and prices measured by the
GHP price deflator have risen at a 4 per cent rate.
This sharp increase in spending has been accompanied
by a rise in private demand for credit. Business and individual
demands for credit reflect both the expanding levels of economic
activity and inflationary expectations. An expanding economy
requires credit for larger inventories, greater plant capacity, and
equipment. Expectations of further price inflation point to the
possibility that debts created currently can be repaid with cheaper
dollars at some future date. Thus individual investors and business
can see opportunities for both rising returns and capital gains with
the use of borrowed funds.
Expected price increases also have an impact on savings
which flow through financial agencies into loans. With prices
rising 4 per cent per year, savers must get more than 4 per cent
interest to have the same purchasing power at the end of the year
as at the beginning, after payment of income tax. 1 am convinced
that most savers attempt to get a real return on their savings.




-19Thus if stated rates do not reflect a real rate of interest above the
zero level, part of the funds which normally flow through financial
agencies are likely to be diverted into other assets such as equities,
land, or bonds.
A solution to the problem of high interest rates thus
lies in greater price stability which involves less expansive fiscal
-and monetary policies. We need policies which will reduce total
demand for goods and services. Once we have obtained reduced price
expectations, lower interest rates should follow. Until price stability
is in view, however, I would expect savers to demand a rate which
will provide a real return on their savings. I would also anticipate
the demands for funds by borrowers to reflect the expectation of
higher nominal earnings, capital gains and the opportunity of paying back loans with cheaper dollars.
Apparently the Federal budget is moving toward a less
expansive posture. That should be an improvement. A less
expansive monetary policy would be another step in the right
direction.