View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For Release on Delivery
(Approximately 2:15 p.m.,
Pacific Standard Time,
April 5, 1956.)

MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICIES
WHAT THEY CAN AND CANNOT DO
Address of C. Canby Balderston,
Vice Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,




Before the Seventeenth Annual
Pacific Northwest Conference on Banking,
State College of Washington,
Pullman, l/ashington,
on Thursday, April 5, 1956.

MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICIES WHAT THEY CAN AND CANNOT DO
My purpose is to examine governmental financial policies as to their
strengths and limitations.

As a basis for such appraisal, it may be helpful to

mention without discussion the objectives of monetary and fiscal policies, the
tools available, and the agencies charged with responsibility over them. My
background discussion will, therefore, merely recite objectives, tools, and
responsible partners.
The objectives sought are two-foldi
(1) To foster orderly economic growth and sustain employment at
the highest feasible level,
(2) To maintain the financial equilibrium of the economy, both
internal, by protecting the purchasing power of the monetary
unit, and external, by keeping international payments in
balance.

The last of these is currently of much concern to

Britishers.
The tools used for general monetary controls (and I will not be dis­
cussing selective or direct controls such as those over stock market margins
and consumer credit) are the well-known three:
rediscount rates, and reserve requirements.

open market operations,

I have listed them in the order

of their refinement, the first two having the delicate touch of the chisel;
the last, the cruder power of the broad axe. The tools embraced by the term
"fiscal policy" are debt management, taxation, and governmental expenditure.
In this country, those who carry the responsibility for the use or
misuse of the monetary tools are the Federal Open Market Committee for open
market operations; the Federal Reserve Bank directors, with review and deter­
mination by the Board of Governors, for rediscount rates; and the Board of




-

2

-

Governors of the Federal Reserve System for reserve requirements.

These bodies

all exist as a result of a delegation by the Congress of authority over money.
Debt management is the primary obligation of the U, S, Treasury,
itfhereas changes in the form and rate of taxation are the ultimate responsi­
bility of the Congress, as is the power to appropriate government flands.
Although the executive branch initiates most changes in revenue and expenditure,
and determines the rate at which appropriations will actually be used, Congress
has the real responsibility as to the rates of taxing and spending by the
Federal government,

Of course, the amount of tax revenue actually collected

moves up and down with the economic tides, and the latter also influence cer­
tain types of governmental spending such as crop supports and unemployment
insurance.
Congress may also direct the use of Federal spending or of guarantees
to stimulate particular portions of the economy. An example is the boost given
to residential construction by encouraging the growth of mortgage credit, which
has been mounting at a monthly rate of over $1 billion.

So much for a recital

of the governmental guns that may be trained on the two objectives, and those
responsible for aiming and firing them,
How successful they will be in achieving economic growth and stability
(the two objectives) turns upon the coordination and timing of their use by the
team of partners who carry the several responsibilities, and by the psychological
climate in which they are employed. My observations as to their strengths and
weaknesses will be focussed, therefore, upon problems of coordination, timing,
and group psychology.




-

3

-

Coordination in the use of credit and fiscal tools is complicated byconflicts inherent in the objectives sought. 1/ In Great Britain, brimful
employment has been achieved, with job opportunities far exceeding the number
of job seekers; but excessive domestic demand is diverting goods from exports
as well as inflating imports, and wage and price increases, unless stopped in
time, may well threaten the country's ability to compete in foreign markets.
In consequence, the country is faced with serious difficulties in her efforts
to keep her foreign accounts in balance.
The tools themselves need to be coordinated, A well-publicized
example was the impact of the "pegging" of government bond prices, however
needful to finance T/orld War II, upon the functioning of monetary controls
after the War had ended. In the language of former Chairman Eccles, it was
a "built-in engine of inflation".
large governmental surpluses.

Inflation continued, incidentally, despite

An example from abroad is Great Britain's reli­

ance in 1955 upon monetary controls without adequate support from the budget.
Despite two sharp increases in bank rate, despite moral suasion directed at
banks to restrict advances, and despite the imposition of direct controls on
consumer credit, inflationary pressures did not abate sufficiently to avoid
further monetary and fiscal actions this year.
In Australia, after a lengthy period of frustrated attempts to com­
bat inflation without coordinating fiscal and credit policies, combined action
embodying important restrictions in both fields had to be taken recently.
Further examples of the need for coordination are provided by the Scandinavian
countries.

V

In Sweden and Norway restrictive monetary policies have been adopted

See article by Karl Bopp on "The Rediscovery of Monetary Policy— Some
Problems of Application," in the Business Review of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia, August 1955«




-

4

—

to supplement fiscal restrictions in sorae sectors, and to offset the stimu­
lation of continued governmental assistance in other sectors, such as housing.
In Denmark, restrictive monetary policies proved insufficient until supple­
mented by restrictive fiscal policies.
Examples are not lacking, however, of coordination that has succeeded.
In India, a planned budget deficit was offset by appropriate monetary policies.
In Japan, inflationary developments were stopped in 1949-50 and again in

1954-55 by the combined application of both fiscal and monetary measures.
The same result was accomplished in Austria in 1952.

Of particular interest

is the case of West Germany. The German "basic law" requires the Government
to present a balanced budget.

Nevertheless, the Finance Minister has accumu­

lated large unspent funds, which are being kept idle on deposit with the central
banking system,

This circumstance has assisted the monetary authorities to

avoid inflationary developments in the face of an unprecedented boom.
Our own country seems, in the absence of a shooting war, to be about
to reap the benefits of fortunate support of monetary policy by fiscal policy.
A Federal cash surplus in each of the fiscal years 195& a^d 1957, if sizeable,
would help to combat the inflationary impact of a prospective large expansion
of industrial and other private investment. Moreover, a large number of
Congressmen as well as administrative officials appear to view a boom period
as one in which reductions in tax rates would be inappropriate.
But coordination is not easy. Take the problem posed for both the
Treasury and the Federal Reserve at the time the discount rate was raised in
November of last year.

For some months, business confidence had been mounting.

It Xtfas evidenced by the rise of industrial orders and of loans, by rising stock




-

5

-

prices, by business plant expansion, by a scarcity of steel, cement, and glass,
and by increasing prices of many important industrial materials and products.
The discount action that such a situation might have indicated was delayed by
the economic uncertainties stemming from President Eisenhower’s illness in late
September, That these uncertainties dissolved in the sober reflections of
businessmen seemed to be indicated when the McGraw-Hill survey of capital
additions forecast an overall increase of 1956 plans over 1955 of 13 per cent.
The return of ebullience plus high seasonal demand for loans caused the Federal
Reserve Banks, with the approval of the Board of Governors, to raise their
rediscount rates in November even though the Treasury faced a refunding in
December of over $12 billion. The Federal Reserve action, necessary as it
was, made a more difficult problem for the Treasury in refinancing its maturing
obligations in December.

The action had to be taken at an unpropitious time

despite some risk of unsettling the market for Government and private securities.
The "funding” of short-term debt tends to have anti-inflationary
effect through reducing the liquidity of holders.

Examples of its successful

use are to be found in the United Kingdom (1951) and the Netherlands (since
1953)« As already indicated, however, "funding" is frequently hampered by a
reluctance to burden the Treasury with higher interest rates as seems to have
been the case in Scandinavian countries before they ended their "cheap-money"
policies in 1953-54*

If "funding" cannot be employed at these times, then the

other tools must be relied upon more heavily, as British authorities are dis­
covering,

Unfortunately, "funding" is most appropriate for the economy in times

of inflationary danger when interest rates tend to be high, but to be most
attractive to the fiscal authorities in times of deflation when interest rates
tend to be low and the economic effect of the operation undesirable.




-

6

-

A problem illustrating one of the obstacles to coordination would
appear to be in the making in Great Britain.

The rigorous restraint now imposed

by the Bank of England and by the Government would be strengthened, one would
suppose, if governmental borrowing were on a long-term rather than a short-term
basis.

But a bank rate of 5-1/2 per cent discourages a long-term commitment

to pay a high rate on borrowed funds and tempts the use of short-term borrov/ing
in the hope that cheaper money may be available in later years. The debt
managers, it must be recognized, are expected to pay attention to borrowing
cost as well as to the best policy to pursue in terms of stabilization goals.
This fact serves to underscore the essential complexity of the problem of
attaining stable growth without inflation.
So far we have discussed coordination in terms of concerted action
through maximizing the mutual assistance of monetary and fiscal policies.
turn now to another aspect of coordination:

We

proper timing. Timing difficulties

tend to hamper the effectiveness of fiscal measures as stabilizing tools more
than that of monetary measures.

Fiscal policies have a less direct and imme­

diate influence than do monetary policies upon such causes of disequilibrium
as inventory accumulation and the excessive use of mortgage or consumer credit.
It is not that changes in fiscal policy are less potent; they are just less
responsive and flexible.

Fiscal decisions, since they are necessarily long

in the making, may come at just the wrong time to improve business stability.
During recession, it is usually not difficult to have tax cuts
enacted. It is more difficult to have tax increases enacted in times of boom.
However, such measures have been passed in Belgium (1955), Denmark (1954-55)>
the Netherlands (1955)> Norway (1955)> Sweden (1955), and the United Kingdom




-

7

-

(autumn 1955)* The Netherlands has enacted a provision compelling corporations
to prepay their taxes in order to reduce the excessive liquidity of the
economy (1955). Tax changes for cyclical purposes have frequently taken the
form of changes in tax-privileged investment allowances for business firms.
Such allowances have been increased to combat recession, and decreased or
abolished to combat boom conditions in the Netherlands, Scandinavian countries,
and the United Kingdom.
The political difficulty of taking unpopular fiscal measures has led
to the adoption of "built-in stabilizers" that would automatically offset
inflationary or deflationary developments.

However, these offsets are invari­

ably incomplete even though they operate in the right direction.

To cite a

single example, a reduction of corporate profits in this country is offset
only in part by a proportionate decline in the 52 per cent of profits that
must be paid out as income taxes,
A further deterrent to the use of tax rate changes as cyclical
remedies is the lag between the announcement of a new rate and its effect
upon business decisions.

Because of the practice of accruing taxes, rate

changes that become effective at some time other than the start of a company's
fiscal year may not exert their full impact upon executives' thinking as to
price setting and expansion until they prepare the budget for the ensuing year.
Not only do time lags detract from the effectiveness of fiscal measures, but
they may cause a given measure to take effect at the very moment when the
opposite type of measure is needed. For example, the Netherlands, in spite
of efforts to adjust its fiscal policy to the cyclical situation, had large
deficits in 1954 and 1955 when the country was experiencing an unprecedented
boom.

But in the far less prosperous year of 1952 the country did have a

surplus.




-

8

-

Fiscal policy, however, tends to have a more direct effect than
monetary policy on total disposable income, especially in the case of changes
in taxes and public expenditures.

It tends therefore to be subject to more

pressure by special interest groups. Tax cuts have frequently been enacted
and public expenditures increased at times when economic stability is threatened
by inflationary pressures.

Recent cases occurred in the United Kingdom, spring

1955? the Netherlands, 1954; Sweden, 1954; and Australia, 1954*
The structure of tax changes does contribute to growth« As a social
objective, we seek a tax structure that is equitable and nonrepressive in its
influence on normal economic incentives.

Both corporate and individual taxes

have a powerful impact upon the incentives to venture, to experiment, to expand,
and to generate the economic forces so necessary to high employment and a rising
scale of living, A recent example is the apparent stimulus to plant expansion
afforded by provision for accelerated depreciation during and after World War II,
The more we can contrive forms of taxation that enhance entrepreneurial incen­
tives and diminish decentives, the more closely will financial authorities
manage to achieve stabilization.

But the tax structure problem is a separate

one from the problem of whether a given fiscal policy is inflationary, neutral,
or deflationary. The latter problem has mainly to do with the relationship
of total tax revenues to total governmental expenditures.
Of the monetary tools, open market operations are responsive in the
extreme. Buying and selling can be modified from day to day, and even from
hour to hour, to adapt to fluctuations in the tightness of the money markets,
and still work in the direction of economic stability. Open market operations,
flowing from the instructions of the Open Market Committee, have the sensitivity
of an automobile accelerator.




_

9

-

Discount operations are also responsive and sensitive, even though
discount rate changes are only made from time to time to adjust to changes in
levels of market rates.

Discount rate changes signalize a recognition on the

part of the Reserve System that a fundamental change has occurred in supplydemand conditions in the credit market.

Open market and discount operations

are closely related functionally— so closely relatad, in fact, that they are
basically supplemental tools.

Each affects the otner and each reenforces the

other.
For monetary authorities, the most fundamental problem of timing is
to forecast changes in the business climate in order to take compensatory
action before the figures actually prove its necessity.

Promptness of action

is imperative if the anticipated results are not to be reduced unduly by the
time lag between changes in monetary policy and their effect on business activity
If the authorities wait until the figures demonstrate beyond question that
further credit restraint or stimulation is needed, the action may lose its
effectiveness, in whole or in part.

But the perils of action based on judgments

in advance of confirmatory information are obviousi
A year or so ago a widely-read daily newspaper congratulated the
Federal Reserve for taking appropriate monetary action six months in advance
of the time that such action was obviously called for by economic facts. Much
as we appreciate such kind words, we ought not to be credited with quite that
much foresight. When we are that good, we are lucky, extremely lucky, rather
than endowed with omniscience. Nevertheless, we do try as best we can to keep
on top of the developing business and financial situation and to take action as
quickly as possible.




-

10

-

Events of the Spring of 1953 serve to illustrate the powerful
psychological forces that play upon business decisions and that must be taken
into account if monetary and fiscal policies are to be useful.

That Spring,

ebullience was high, plant expansion was rapid, inventory accumulation was
large, and credit demands were strong with prospects for large Treasury borrow­
ing ahead.

The monetary authorities countered by increasing restraint on bank

credit expansion. Suddenly, in a matter of days, money became so tight as to
endanger the smooth conduct of business, and the restraints were eased.

In

retrospect, it appears that the subsequent decline in activity is to be at­
tributed largely to curtailment of governmental defense expenditures,— a cur­
tailment that had not been scheduled when the monetary restraints were imposed.
The financial policy of 1907 that led to the founding of the Federal
Reserve System six years later, the inventory panic with its crashing prices of
1920 and 1921, and the collapsing stock market of 1929 and 1930 all preach
their respective sermons. One lesson of the depression of the 1930's would
seem to be that if equity values suffer from too great destruction, those
executives who should venture if the economy is to revive are too distraught
and fearful to do so; or if they have the requisite courage and daring, they
may no longer be considered credit-worthy by lenders.
On the other side is the psychology of ebullience and of unwarranted
optimism.

Financial history records boom after boom that burst because men

"chased the fast buck" at the sacrifice of prudence.

Two observations may be

in order. One is that speculative fervor may not, the next time it injures
the economy, take the form of stock market speculation like that of 1929 when
margin requirements were low and the rewards of the call-money market were




-

11

-

enticing. Speculation has many forms of dress and even of disguise. The second
observation is that neither monetary control nor fiscal policy, nor the two in
concert, can maintain economic stability if group psychology runs rampant.
They cannot revive business from depression in the face of general despair;
nor can they prevent inflation if business decisions lack the quality of pru­
dence .
The apparent successes scored in recent years by the team of monetary
policies, fiscal policies and business prudence are a cause of deep satisfaction
to those who must worry about the future of our domestic and world economies.
Though the record of failures in achieving sustainable economic growth coupled
with stability is imbedded in the memories of those who suffered, the record
of recent successes is such as to command attention and respect.

Clearly the

hope of the future lies in so managing ourselves and our affairs as to stress
the coordination and timing of monetary and fiscal actions.

Recent experience

suggests that intelligence and moral fortitude can yield a better life, just
as history records the tragic outcomes of man’s failure to understand what is
required and to act accordingly.