View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Bruce K. MacLaury
President
Federal Reserve Bank
of Minneapolis
G U A R A N T E E D

E M P L O Y M E N T ?

It was thirty years ago that Congress passed an employment act
that committed the nation to seek "maximum employment, production,
and purchasing power."
since the 1930s.

Yet today, we have the highest rate of unemployment

Small wonder that there's a credibility gap, and clamor

for redoubled efforts to find solutions to this most troublesome and
intractable aspect of the American economy.
There are many things that can and should be said by way of
"explanation" of the current problem:

that other industrialized countries

have been experiencing much the same difficulties; that centrally planned
economies achieve the appearance of "full employment" only at the cost of
state-regulated job assignments and the inefficiency of hidden unemployment;
that the economic cost of unemployment in this country has been substantially
cushioned by extended unemployment benefits; that even with our present high
levels of measured unemployment, the proportion of the population employed
is nearly as high as at any time in the past; that the federal government
will spend close to $3 billion this year to support some 320,000 public
service jobs; that we have experimented with job training and retraining
programs with only limited success; and so on.
It's not, in other words, that there has been a callous disregard
of the problems of the unemployed.

On the contrary, the record indicates

that in our efforts to alleviate the problem of unemployment, we have at
times created problems of a different sort.




I have particularly in mind

-

2

-

the inflationary pressures generated by stimulative monetary and budgetary
policies designed to reduce unemployment during periods of recession, but
which, in retrospect, turn out to have been excessive.

Thus, while there

is clearly a role for countercyclical policies by the government and the
Federal Reserve, I believe it is also clear that such policies alone, aimed
as they are at boosting total demand in the economy, cannot guarantee "full
employment" as most people understand it, without causing destabilizing
rates of inflation.
Is there no hope, then, that we can look forward to better days
ahead?

I think we cannot only hope, but expect, a much better performance

from our economy over the months and years immediately ahead than we experi­
enced during the period we have just been through.

The first half of the

1970s saw our nation exposed to a greater number of shocks than anyone
could have expected, or are likely to recur:

the devaluation of the

dollar, the unwinding of the Vietnam war, Watergate, major bankruptcies
and near bankruptcies, world boom, foreign crop failures, oil price cartels,
double digit inflation, etc.

We are already well on our way to recovering

from the deep recession that followed the distortions and trauma of these
shocks.

Employment is up by 3.3 million people from its recession low in

March 1975.

And prospects are for the recovery to continue, provided we

don't try once again to buy our way out with a "quick fix" of excessive
money growth or deficits.
But recovery is not enough.

Major structural problems will

remain even after the recession as such is behind us.

Even in periods of

high employment, the rate of unemployment among minorities is double the




-

3

-

national average — and among teenagers, triple the national average (e.g.,
19.2% in April).

Certainly, we must continue to search for training

programs that offer promise, possibly by subsidizing periods of apprentice­
ship with employers in the private sector.

At the same time, we must

recognize that some people will simply not be able to catch up with the
job demands of an increasingly technological society.

There is no way,

under such circumstances, that the government can guarantee "meaningful"
or well paying jobs for all.

Indeed, the rising minimum wage, however

well intended, virtually guarantees that a portion of unskilled workers
will not be able to find employment in the private sector where they
could, in effect, finance their own investment in job skills.
On this basis, a strong argument can be made for a youth
minimum wage, lower than the general minimum.

This proposal is not new, but

has been controversial, partly on grounds that it potentially allows
exploitation of teenagers.

But a far greater inequity arises, it seems

to me, when employers, who might otherwise provide jobs for young people
without many skills, are precluded from doing so by the barrier of the
minimum wage.
While the government cannot afford to provide public service jobs
at going wage rates for all who might like them — one estimate is that it
might cost $30 billion per year to try to do so — there is a much stronger
argument for the government to be the "employer of last resort" for
teenagers, and perhaps others, who cannot find employment in the private
sector.

The model of the Civilian Conservation Corps is frequently cited

in this connection.

Pay should be low — in fact, below the minimum wage

in private industry — but with incentives for training and assistance in
finding better jobs elsewhere.
beyond our reach.




In this sense, full employment is not