View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

GROWTH AMD DEVELOPMENT IN MINNESOTA
WHERE DO WE GO FROM HERE?

Remarks by
BRUCE K. MacLAURY
President
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

at the

Seminar on Minnesota's Future
KTCA-TV Studios
St. Paul, Minnesota

February 10, 1973

GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT IN MINNESOTA —

WHERE DO ME GO FROM HERE?

In his book Design with Nature, Ian McHarg describes the jarring
juxtaposition of vast riches, a delightful heritage, and the sad hodge-podge
of unplanned commercialism that is the dilemma of modern America.

"There are

still great realms of empty ocean," he writes, "deserts reaching to the cur­
vature of the earth, silent, ancient forests and rocky coasts, glaciers and
volcanoes, but what will we do with them?

There are rich contented farms,

and idyllic villages, strong barns and white-steepled churches, tree-lined
streets and covered bridges, but these are residues of another time."

There

is also "the hamburger stand, gas station, diner, the ubiquitous billboards,
sagging wires, the parking lot, car cemetery, and that most complete con­
junction of land rapacity and human disillusion, the subdivision."
the cry today is plan!
of growth do we want?

Map out the future!

Control growth!

And so

But what kind

Where do we go from here?

To map out the future, we must first know where we are, and from
whence we came.

There is no consensus today as to what exactly should be

called "growth", but by most traditional measures Minnesota has grown, and
grown pretty well.
For example:
. . . population grew by 11%% between 1960 and 1970, an increase
of some 400 thousand people.
. . . median family income also rose by more than 75%, a rate
faster than the national average.
. . . employment, despite a marked decline in agriculture, rose
by some 20%, substantially faster than the population increase, and unemploy­
ment during the 60's was consistently below the national average.




- 2 -

. . . and I can't resist mentioning the latest Fortune magazine
that cites both the IDS Tower and our own Federal Reserve Bank as examples
of a renaissance in creative architecture, another evidence of "growth".
Now it's obvious that these changes and others have occurred with­
out benefit of any master plan for the state as a whole.

Indeed there has

been little comprehensive planning at any level of government.

To say this

is hardly an indictment of Minnesota, for in many ways we are ahead of our
neighbors in planning efforts.

I need mention only the State Planning Agency,

the Metropolitan Council, or the Environmental Quality Council as examples of
attempts to come to grips with various needs for planning.

But the fact

remains that the distinguishing characteristic of most planning efforts to
date is their fragmented approach:
recommend specific solutions.

they deal with particular problems or

It seems to me that we are now forced to

recognize the intricate interrelationships between these various problems.
We are being forced to look for an overall and integrated approach to our
policies for growth.
Having said this, I'd be the first to admit that even without such
comprehensive guides, Minnesota finds itself in good shape.

Even outside

observers put us right at the top in terms of "quality of life."

So if we

can do this well with "no hands," why try to devise some grand scheme?
There are at least two good reasons.

First, it's true that the

quality of life in Minnesota is attributable in part to judicious state
policies —

policies in education, health, pollution control, urban develop­

ment, etc.

But we also have to admit that we are the fortunate heirs of

a rich inheritance —

one we have not yet dissipated.

I'm thinking, of

course, of our boundless lakes, woods and streams, and our generally low




- 3 -

density of population.

We must not take this good fortune as an excuse to

postpone planning for the future; rather it should be a spur to start while
we still have a largely unspoiled environment —

start while the problems

are still manageable.
And second, we must remember that not all areas of the state have
shared equally in the growth and development that has taken place up to now.
It would be foolish to assume, of course, that any plan, no matter how com­
prehensive, could assure equal growth to all sections of the state.

But we

must at least give conscious consideration to policy choices that determine
where and how growth takes place.
So where do we seem to be headed?

A recent study by John Borchert

and Donald Carroll entitled Minnesota Settlement and Land Use 1985 lays out
a variety of projections of where we might find ourselves in ten to fifteen
years.

Starting with a state population in 1970 of approximately 3.8 million

people, the study projects population increases by 1985 of somewhere between
150 and 850 thousand.

This range is admittedly wide; the outcome depends in

large measure on national growth policies in the intervening years.
say perhaps an increase of half a million souls as most likely.

So let's

Where will

this growth tend to take place?
As in the past, the projections in this study show a tendency for
the bulk of this population growth to take place within the seven-county
metropolitan area.

But in contrast with the decade of the 1960's, when

60% of the counties in the state lost population, the projections indicate
that out-state counties as a group are not likely to show absolute population
declines in the next ten years or so.




The authors also expect the trend toward fewer but larger farms to

- 4 -

continue.

By 1985, the number of farms may have declined by between 20

and 50 percent.

An even more rapid drop might occur were it not expected

that especially in the northern and metropolitan areas, more than half the
farms will be operated on a part-time basis, with operators supplementing
their income through jobs in towns.
Now, one may applaud, or be distressed by, these glimpses of
Minnesota's future.
And the point is:

But more important, we need to be aware of the trends.
do we like these trends?

Is this where we want to go?

And just as important, what can we do about it?

The Borchert study, for

example, concludes that these broad trends in major land use and population
changes during the period ahead are probably inexorable.

Forces pushing

development in a particular direction at any point in time do indeed tend
to be strong.

They encompass not only economic incentives, but legal and

political frameworks, and even social outlooks of a population.
cumulative momentum of the past is not something easily diverted.

This
Such

forces are not only strong, but often subtle and therefore difficult to
come to grips with.
Nevertheless, we don't need to accept any given course of events
as inevitable:

the question is really one of benefits versus costs:

much are we willing to pay to shape our future.
there may be little cost at all.

how

In certain situations,

Most of us can think of laws or regula­

tions that are still on the books long after their original purpose has
passed from the scene.

Such anachronisms stand in the way of efficient

progress, and their removal can in fact mean savings.




I'm thinking of

- 5 -

building codes, for example, or local government boundaries that no longer
make sense.
Another way to improve our environment at less cost than might
appear is through the use of public policy to compensate for the failure
of the market pricing system to incorporate afn_ costs of a particular
product or service.

By now, many laymen are familiar with the concept

that economists call "external diseconomies", that is, the costs of cleaning
up the air or the rivers, of barring noise around airports or congestion in
the city, of paying cleaning bills around factories, costs that fall on some­
one other than the polluter.

When public policies require those who pollute

to bear these costs, we are simply redistributing the costs In a more
equitable fashion, not increasing them for society as a whole.
But not all attempts to guide our own destiny will be inexpensive.
For example, we may decide that it pays to subsidize the output of certain
industries or crops, or advocate an economically inefficient location for a
particular plant simply because we believe the social benefits outweigh the
additional cost.

As a generalization, I think we must assume that the greater

the change required to divert the natural unplanned course of events, the
higher the price we are going to have to pay to bring about the change.
For example, I would guess that to divert population growth from metropolitan
areas to out-state districts in meaningful numbers will require costly
disincentives for locating in the metropolitan area, together with costly
incentives to settle elsewhere.
our out-state communities.

In saying this, I mean no disrespect for

I simply mean that past population trends, and

projections for the future, reflect a concentration of population in and
around metropolitan areas; to change this trend in any meaningful way would




- 6 -

probably require costly countermeasures.
In effect, we need not accept any particular trend as given
and inexorable.

But we must understand that in most cases, the greater

the change desired, the greater will be the cost.

At the same time we

must try to match such costs against the potential costs of doing nothing.
Another basic question, of course, is whether we want to grow
at all.

Growth after all is now a challenged concept.

We've had forcibly

brought home to us the fact that growth uses up resources, creates pollution,
inflicts costs on the environment, and can erode human values.

This is

not to say that our ancestors were wrong in taking from the land all they
could get.

The pioneers, the builders of railroads, the great industrial­

ists, built for us a great nation by operating under the principle of growth
at any cost.

But times change and we must now take a long hard look at the

side effects of untrammeled growth.
For my part, I see no need for the state to take a view on the
rate of overall population increase in Minnesota.
issues where this state needs to take a stand.

There are more Important

Moreover, we seem to be

moving toward a low, if not zero population growth in any case.

Second,

I am unimpressed with the arguments for limits on growth in per capita
income.

Like most of my economist colleagues, I believe the issue is not

how to adapt ourselves to a no growth world, but rather how to pattern our
growth so that we avoid or minimize undesirable side effects of growth.
At this broad level of generalization, I would argue that the
state should concern itself with three issues:

1) the distributional

patterns of population changes, 2) a more equitable distribution of gains
from growth among the state's present population, and 3) insure that increases




- 7 -

in living standards today are not at the expense of quality of life
tomorrow.

These are easy principles to enunciate, but harder to specify

and even harder to implement.
So back to the question:
from here?

where specifically do we want to go

We ask the question only to meet with new frustration.

We

know lots of things we don't want -- pollution, central city or rural
decay, and so on.

We even have some ideas in certain specific areas of

what we do want —

in transportation facilities, housing, health care,

education, and so on.

Granted they are often conflicting ideas, but at

least debate is going on.

What we mainly lack is sufficient effort to

integrate views on each one of these particular areas into an overall
framework to guide the state's development.

Buckminster Fuller is fond

of saying "whenever I draw a circle, I immediately want to step outside
of it."

We too must step outside the small circles we draw around our

special spheres of interest and attempt to see the whole picture, with
all its many interrelationships.

It's not an easy thing to do, especially

for a people who historically have resisted planning in the name of too
much government, who pride themselves on personal freedom and independence.
But again times change, and interdependence in all aspects of life is now
at least as important an organizing principle as independence was to our
forebears.
Since we don't have a ready-made blueprint for growth, where do
we look for models to guide our thinking.

First, I think we can learn

something from our European neighbors, who have been living in closer
proximity for a longer time than we have.

Last summer, a Congressional

study group on urban growth policies surveyed six European countries* to

♦United Kingdom, France, Sweden, Finland, Poland, Hungary




- 8 -

determine what lessons might be transferred from the European experience
to our own.

I cannot take time here to describe the policy measures adopted

by these various governments —
ronment in any case —

many would not be transferable to our envi­

but we should not overlook the relevant experiences

of our overseas friends.
Looking closer to home, our own federal government has been trying
to come to grips with a national growth policy for at least the last three
years.

I frankly feel these efforts have not yet borne much fruit.

Indeed,

I've begun to question whether it is desirable, or even possible, to specify
a single growth policy at the national level, given our size and diversity.
For this very reason, I have the impression that Congress will soon pass
legislation that will provide strong inducements for states to develop
their own land use policies.
Federal land use bills, as they stood when the last Congress
adjourned, would require states to prepare an inventory of land and natural
resources, project land use needs, provide for public hearings and partic­
ipation in the planning process.

The bills would require the state to

identify and exercise state authority over the use and development of land
1) for "key facilities", such as airports, major highway interchanges, recre­
ational facilities, and power plants; 2) for "large-scale development" that
presents issues of more than local significance; and 3) for the use and
development of land in "areas of critical environmental concern", such
as shorelands and flood plains, etc.

There are other provisions in the

bills, such as providing for regulation of large-scale subdivisions, that
clearly indicate that the Congress is serious about land use planning.




The fact is, of course, that many states have not waited for

- 9 -

federal leadership.

Within the last few years, we have seen a number of

states take large strides on their own 1n the direction of land use
planning.

In 1969, Oregon and Maine joined Hawaii 1n establishing state­

wide zoning.

A number of states have taken steps to control development

in environmentally sensitive areas like wetlands, ocean fronts, lakeshores,
and so on.

Vermont in 1970 enacted a new land use law which authorized the

state to control development at areas above 2500 feet elevation, and to
control all large-scale development.
By far the most detailed and comprehensive plan I'm aware of
was compiled by a group of private citizens in California.
"The California Tomorrow Plan".

It is called

It 1s a well organized discussion, laying

out the problems as they exist, the likely shape of the future if these
problems continue to be attacked on a piecemeal basis, and an alternative
future predicated on a comprehensively planned attack on what are con­
sidered to be the root causes of the problems.

Twenty-one problem areas

are cited, such as energy resources, water quality, transportation, housing,
employment, and security, to name just a few.
three broad headings:

They are grouped under

those arising from depletion or pollution of land,

air, or water; those arising from breakdowns or shortages of physical
structures; and those associated with Individual waste or social failure
in the use of human resources.
are Identified:

Four underlying causes for these problems

lack of individual political strength, lack of individual

economic strength, damaging distribution of population, and damaging
patterns of resource consumption.

And finally, the responsibilities of

various governmental levels within the state to coordinate attacks on
these "causes of disruption" are spelled out in detail.




- 10 -

Not everyone, of course, would agree with the recommendations in
the California plan.

But it is an impressive effort, and it stands as a

challenge to others to come forward with equally well-thought-out plans of
their own.

Nor is this simply a p1e-in-the-sky pipe dream; a conscientious

attempt is made to price out alternative costs of attacking the problems
piecemeal as compared with a comprehensive approach.
Finally, we can look in our own backyard for guidelines.

There

have been various recommendations by the Citizens League, including a
suggestion last summer that there be established a Minnesota Governmental
Policy Institute to determine the consequences of current policies, to
analyze alternative courses of action, and to anticipate future problems.
The Borchert study from which I quoted earlier represented a useful attempt
to peer into the future.

Just recently I came across the report of a sub­

committee of the Environmental Quality Council that took a very broad-guage
look at our present policies and problems in the state, with thoughtful
recommendations in each area that impacts the environment.

Finally, and by

no means least, I applaud the work of the State Planning Agency and today's
recommendation by the Governor for a commission on Minnesota's future.
So if we don't yet know where we want to go, there are a variety
of models at which we can look, and a good deal of interest and activity
aimed at coming up with some comprehensive planning capabilities.
I urge that we continue efforts in these directions and would like
to close with a few thoughts of my own on where we ought to be headed.

First

though, I must confess that I come with very few credentials as planner or
futurist.

My Interest 1n this subject has simply grown out of my profes­

sional responsibilities.




As a regional institution, the Federal Reserve

- 11 -

Bank is very much interested in the economic development of the entire Ninth
District, which stretches from Montana to Upper Michigan.

For what they

are worth then, here are a few rather disjointed thoughts.
First, I wholeheartly endorse the idea of some form of public
policy institute for Minnesota.

Its function would be to offer us choices

of alternative futures, together with their costs and consequences.

I am

not clear in my own mind whether this "institute" ought to be publicly or
privately funded, or some combination of the two.

And decisions would

have to be made as to the emphasis put on original research, drawing
together and presenting the ideas of others, and proselytizing on behalf
of its own preferred policies.

I also question whether we need to start

from scratch -- there are a number of groups such as the Citizens League,
the Upper Midwest Council, Northstar Research, and the new Spring Hill
Foundation, to name a few, that have been actively working in this general
area.

Possibly their talents could be combined with resources from the

Environmental Quality Council and the University, as a nucleus for the
proposed institute.
Second, I'm convinced that we need an inventory of land and
resource uses in the state.

Related to this is a need to establish a

state-wide zoning authority with power to designate certain areas for
particular kinds of development.
Third, I see little merit in using pub!ic funds to divert popu­
lation growth from metropolitan areas.

Instead, such funds as are available

should be used to preserve, and enhance, the urban environment to meet
human needs.




Fourth, I believe that efforts to induce industry to move to the

- 12 -

out-state areas and particularly to the smaller towns are likely to be
self-defeating.

I believe we will achieve more by concentrating our efforts

on specified growth centers in various regions of the state.

The chances

for self-sustained growth increase, and greater benefits accrue to the
surrounding rural areas, if we concentrate our efforts and dollars on
selected cities rather than scatter our resources in an effort to bring all
along together.
Fifth, the Minnesota Experimental City, as its name implies,
could serve as a model from which we could learn how better to structure
our existing cities.

It would be a costly model, however, and it's

advocates do not contend that new cities can absorb any significant
part of the increase in our population.

Thus, I think it makes sense

only if substantial federal funding can be obtained to help finance it.
Sixth, I believe it would be desirable to expand public land
ownership in the state, particularly in urban areas.

Early acquisition

of land by public authorities, as is now done through the use of land
banks in France and Sweden, would permit greater control over metropolitan
growth.

Similarly, by making public land available for private development

on a long-term lease basis, such land would revert to the community for
reevaluation of use once every, say, 50 years, without having to pay from
the public treasury the cost of land values which rose in the intervening
period.
Seventh, two suggestions in the California Tomorrow Study are
intriguing, and deserve further study.

To protect open land from speculative

pressures for development and encourage appropriate development in urban
areas, land could be taxed according to its zoning category, and not




- 13 -

according to its potential for development.

Related to this, buyers of raw

land would no longer be permitted to take capital gains tax rates on their
profits when they sold.
Eighth, I applaud Minnesota's initiatives in the area of equal­
izing property tax burdens.

The strong start toward equalization of edu­

cation tax burdens on property in the 1971 Tax Law was an important step
in this direction, as was the Fiscal Disparities Law which was unfortu­
nately declared unconstitutional by the district court.

While these laws

may have had their genesis in efforts to equalize tax burdens, they also
have beneficial impacts on development patterns within the state.
Ninth, I believe it's important to make progress on restruc­
turing local governments.

The state's Regional Development Act of 1969

provided the framework for the establishment of regional development
commissions.
underway.

I am pleased to see that recently one more commission got

At the same time, it's necessary to work toward a consolidation

of local governments.

I was impressed with the progress that seems to

have been made in Sweden on this score.

From a total of 2,500 municipal

units in 1952, the number has been reduced to 464 in 1971, and the final
figure is slated to be 270 in 1974.

The assumption was that effective

administration of municipal services would require a population level
of 8,000 as a minimum.

Similarly, within our own state, the number of

school districts has been reduced from some 7,600 in 1946 to only 450 today.
With changes in population distribution and new technologies for effective
distribution of municipal services, municipal boundary lines that made sense
50 years ago or more are bound to be irrelevant today.




I deeply appreciate this opportunity to contribute to the

- 14 -

discussion of Minnesota's future.

If my thoughts seem uninformed, or

unnecessarily offend local sensibilities, I hope you will put it down to
the fact that I'm a relative newcomer among you.
advantages too.

But being a newcomer has

I perhaps see with fresh eyes the great heritage that has

been bestowed upon us in Minnesota, the opportunities that exist to
contribute to the quality of life for future generations, that great
sense of hopefulness that this state offers in serving as a model for
the future of what can be done before we get bogged down in a mire of
despair.

We will all see these opportunities differently, of course,

and we will all have different solutions to offer, but it is not too
soon to get debate underway.