View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL CREDIT PROGRAMS — THE ISSUES THEY RAISE

Remarks by
BRUCE K. MacLAURY
President
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

at the
Bald Peak Conference
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston

Bald Peak Colony Club
Melvin Village, New Hampshire
June 29, 1973

CREDIT PROGRAMS — THE ISSUES THEY RAISE

Federal Agency Securities — What are they?
Even in the relatively narrow context of a discussion
on federal debt management, the term "federal agencies" covers
a broad and diverse range of debt instruments.

At one end of

the spectrum one finds the direct obligations of Government-owned
agencies such as the Export/Import Bank, TVA, and the Postal
Service -- obligations that are virtually indistinguishable in
credit standing from direct obligations of the U.S. Government
itself.

At the other end are the notes of private issuers, such

as SBIC's that are guaranteed by a government agency, in this case
the Small Business Administration.

In between fall every sort and

description of instrument, distinguished by differing degrees of
access to the Treasury in case of default, of insurance coverage
as to interest and principal, of marketability based on size of
issue, minimum denomination, etc., and differing degrees of
explicitness in the extent to which the obligations are guaranteed,
if at all.
Despite this great diversity, most market people think of
the term "federal agencies" as encompassing primarily the obliga­
tions of the so-called federally-sponsored agencies that are
privately owned and that operate outside the budget:

the Federal
i
National Mortgage Association, the Farm Credit System, and the
Federal Home Loan Bank System.

This narrower use of the term

reflects both the size and the activity of these particular
borrowers in the credit markets, and the fact that their obli­
gations are sold in the open market and traded actively.



Other

- 2 -

agency issues are generally smaller, less actively traded, or
tailored to specific types of investors.
To focus on agency issues as such, by whatever definition,
however, is to miss the broader context of the federal govern­
ment's involvement in the credit markets more generally.

Before

,y

the off-budget agencies became so large, the federal government
through regular budget agencies had long been in the business of
extending direct loans in support of a wide variety of programs.
In addition, of course, the government had long been in the
business of guaranteeing the debt of private parties, most nota­
bly through the mortgage insurance programs of the FHA and VA.
Thus, while for some purposes it is sufficient to look at the
role anti implications of government agency securities, defined
as bond-type instruments sold and traded in the open market, for
other purposes it is more relevant to look at the broader aspects
of the government's function as a credit granting and credit
guaranteeing entity.
Expansion of Federal Credit Programs
Starting from the broader perspective of the government's
role in credit markets generally, it's not hard to document the
very rapid rates of growth in federally-assisted credit in recent
years, both in absolute terms and in relation to credit flows in
the capital markets.

The accompanying chart, taken from Special

Analysis E of the 1974 Budget, depicts graphically the acceler­
ating trend in amounts of federal and federally-assisted credit
outstanding over the last decade.




As shown in the chart, total




- 2A -

Federal and Federally Assisted Credit Outstanding
$ Billions

320 ----

240 -

T60

p B l! II1 1 §1“
i i

i ri ^ ^

.Direct Loans

1963
Fiscal Y«ar»

’64

’65

'66

’67

‘68

'69

’70

*7!

’72

'73

74

EsHmat*

69

- 3 -

borrowing under federal auspices is expected to reach $287
billion in 1974, a two-year increase of $55 billion and 24% over
the 1972 level.
Another indication of the growing importance of federal
credit assistance is the increased proportion of funds raised
in the credit markets that benefit from some form of federal
assi stance:
FEDERALLY ASSISTED BORROWING*
(Billions of $ or %)
Percent

Amount
FY 1962

FY 1972e.

FY 1962

FY 1972e.

Federally Guaranteed

5

25

8

18

Sponsored Agency

1

4

2

__ 3_

$6

$29

Total
*

10%

21%

Change in amount outstanding

Source:

Adapted from Treasury material accompanying submission
of bill to establish a Federal Financing Bank, Dec. 9, 1971.

As a proportion of funds raised, the federally assisted portion
has doubled to about 20 percent over the last decade.

Nor do

these figures include the impact on credit markets of the increase
in direct government debt issued to finance budget deficits.
i
As is obvious from the chart, the entire growth in
federally-assisted credit in recent years has taken the form of
guarantees and loans by government-sponsored agencies.

In fact,

the volume of outstanding direct loans extended by budget depart­
ments has not increased at all on balance since 1967.



- 4 -

The expansion of federally-assisted credit has occurred
not only in aggregate amounts outstanding, but also in the pro­
liferation of departments, programs, and off-budget agencies
making use of this sort of assistance.

A list of federal,

federally-guaranteed, and federally-sponsored agencies borrowing
from the public was attached to the Treasury's proposal in
December 1971 to create a federal financing bank (to be discussed
below), and is reproduced here.

Section IV of the list shows

proposals for new borrowing agencies and new guarantee programs
before Congress at that time.

Since then, the guaranteed

Washington METRO Bonds have been authorized and issued, the
Farmers Home Administration has been granted broad new authority
to finance rural development credit, and the Environmental Finan­
cing Authority and the National Student Loan Association have been
enacted and will probably be in operation by next year.

Just since

1969 when I started my assignment at the Treasury, various other
new agencies and programs have come into existence, including:
the Rural Telephone Bank, the U.S. Postal Service, GNMA mortgagebacked securities, new communities debentures, Amtrak, Pefco,
Overseas Private Investment Corporation.

Indeed, it would be

rather surprising if the pressure to provide credit assistance
outside the budget did not result in a wave of new programs and
i
financing vehicles, each with its own constituency and special
characteri sti c s .
Another dimension to the growth in federal credit assistance
is the tendency to "upgrade" the form of instrument issued or
guaranteed so that it will be more readily marketable and presumably



FEDERAL,

I.

FEDERALLY-GUARANTEED, AND FEDERALLY
SPONSORED AGENCY SORROWING
F R O M T H E P U B L I C 1/

F e d e r a l a g e n c i e s r e g u l a r l y i s s u i n g in the s e c u r i t i e s m a r k e t
d i r e c t o b l i g a t i o n s of a type w h i c h w i l l be e l i g i b l e for s a l e
to the F e d e r a l F i n a n c i n g Bank:
Credit a g e n c i e s :
Export-Import Bank
s
'
Federal Housing Administration
Rural Telephone Bank
Other a g e n c i e s :
Tennessee Valley Authority
U. S. P o s t a l S e r v i c e

II.

F e d e r a l a g e n c i e s i s s u i n g g u a r a n t e e s of a type f o r w h i c h the
s u b m i s s i o n o f b u d g e t p l a n s w i l l be r e q u i r e d by the F e d e r a l
F i n a n c i n g B a n k Act:

A. G u a r a n t e e d o b l i g a t i o n s r e g u l a r l y f i n a n c e d in the
securities market:

2/

Agriculture:
Farmers Home Administration
Commercex
Maritime Administration

(a ss et sa le s )

(merchant marine bonds)

H e a l t h , E d u c a t i o n , and W e l f a r e :
A c a d e m i c f a c i l i t y b o n d s (debt s e r v i c e s u b s i d i e s )
H o s p i t a l f a c i l i t i e s ( asset s a le s)
H o u s i n g and Urban Development
C o l l e g e h o u s i n g b o n d s (debt s e r v i c e s u b s i d i e s )
G N M A m o r t g a g e - b a c k e d s e c u r i t i e s 3/
New community debentures
P u b l i c h o u s i n g b o n d s a n d n o t e s (debt s e r v i c e s u b s i d i e s )
U r b a n r e n e w a l n o t e s (debt s e r v i c e s u b s i d i e s )
Transportation:
R a i l r o a d ( A m t r a k , etc?.)
Export-Import Bank

(PEFCO, etc,)

General Services Administration
Small Business Administration

(a s s e t sale s)

( SB I C d e b e n t u r e s )

F u n d s a p p r o p r i a t e d to the P r e s i d e n t :
International security assistance
International development assistance
Overseas Private Investment Corporation

I

^/-^Excludes m i n o r p r o g r a m s and p r o g r a m s in l i q u i d a t i o n .
£ / G u a r a n t e e d b o r r o w i n g i n c l u d e s s a l e s of F e d e r a l l o a n a s s e t s on a
g u a r a n t e e d b a s i s and b o r r o w i n g s p a r t l y g u a r a n t e e d by m e a n s of
debt service subsidies,
j}/ I n c l u d e s G N M A g u a r a n t e e s of m o r t- ga ge -b ac ke d b o n d s i s s u e d by F N M A
”
 and F H L M C .


- 4B B. O c h e r g u a r a n t e e d o b l i g a t i o n s :
Commerce:
Economic Development Administration
Trade adjustment assistance
Defense :
Defense

production

H e a l t h , E d u c a t i o n , and Welfare:
Health manpower training facilities
Nurse training facilities
Stu d e n t loans
H o u s i n g and Urban Development:
Federal Housing Administration
Export-Import

Bank

Small Business
Veterans
III.

Administration

Administration

Federal sponsored
e l i g i b l e for sale

agencies whose
to the F e d e r a l

o b l i g a t i o n s w i l l n o t be
Financing Bank:

Farm credit agencies:
B a n k s for c o o p e r a t i v e s
Fe d eral intermediate credit banks
Federal land banks
Federal Home

Loan Banks

Federal Home

Loan Mortgage

Corporation

Federal National Mortgage Association
IV.

Major

proposals

before

Congress:

A. N e w b o r r o w i n g a g e n c i e s :
Environmental Financing Authority
National Student Loan Association
B. S. I n t e r n a t i o n a l D e v e l o p m e n t C o r p o r a t i o n
N atio n a l Development Bank
Urban Development Bank
National Credit Union Bank
Rural Development Bank

B. N e w g u a r a n t e e d b o r r o w i n g s :

|

Farmers Home Ad m i n i s t r a t i o n farm operating loans
(asset sales)
T r a n s p o r t a t i o n D e p a r t m e n t equ i p m e n t trust c e r t i f i c a t e s
Washington Metropolitan Area Transit Authority
D i s t r i c t of C o l u m b i a g o v e r n m e n t b o r r o w i n g
(debt service subsidies)
T a x a b l e m u n i c i p a l bond s for rural d e v e l o p m e n t
(debt s e r v i c e subsi d i e s )
Office



of t h e S e c r e t a r y of the T r e a s u r y
O f f i c e of D e b t A n a l y s i s

December

10,

1971

- 5 -

carry a lower interest cost.

This upgrading can be seen most

easily in the transformation of guaranteed mortgages into guaranteed bonds through issuance of GNMA mortgage-backed securities.
It is also evident in the efforts to "perfect" the guarantees on
various types of securities, e.g., SBIC debentures and Merchant
Marine bonds, to obtain a cleaner and faster tap on the Treasury
in case of default, to increase the ratio of guarantee from
90% to 100% etc.
While there is nothing inherently wrong in trying to
devise characteristics for securities that will make them more
marketable, the rub comes when the ultimate objective is to
create securities that are indistinguishable from direct govern­
ment debt, and yet still preserve some rationale for not counting
the issues as a means of financing budget deficits or against the
federal debt ceiling -- a clear case of trying to have one's cake
and eat it too.
Why the Growth in Federal Credit Programs and Agency Securities?
If the fact of rapid expansion in federal credit programs
is self-evident, the factors stimulating this growth are more
complex.

The most basic question to be asked, I suppose, is

why the federal government should be involved in credit programs
at all.

1/




There are a variety of answers.

From none in 1970, such securities jumped to $6.8 billion
outstanding in 1972, and are expected to reach $15.6 billion
in 1974.

1/

- 6 -

First, credit assistance, just like expenditures on goods
and services and transfer payments, may be used to alter 1n a
socially desirable way (it is assumed) the allocation of resources
in the economy.

And indeed, it is a fact that programatic

objectives can be achieved either through cash grants or credit
assistance within a considerable range of overlap.
Second, a case is made for federal involvement in the
credit markets (e.g., through guarantees) as a means of overcoming
market imperfections.

This is perhaps the purest case, where

assistance is "temporary", i.e., until the market itself fills
in the gaps.

In practice, many of the federally-assisted credit

programs contain a proviso requiring the lending agency to find
that private financing is not available on reasonable terms.
But the Congress has gone well beyond the "market imper­
fections" rationale, to provide very substantial elements of
subsidy in the form of debt service grants, below market interest
rates, etc.

not on a temporary but on a continuing basis.

The

intent, of course, is again to influence the allocation of
resources, but to do so in a way that leverages the federal budget
dollar.

It can be argued, for example, that many worthwhile

(I.e., benefits > costs) projects in the private sector would
not be undertaken if the full cost of the investment had to be
/
financed out of the investor's stream of current income.
By
analogy, there are presumably many worthwhile investments that
could be made by the federal government (forgetting that in an
accounting sense the government has no capital budget as such)
either in bricks and mortar (e.g., waste treatment plants) or



- 7 -

education (college tuition assistance) that would not be made
if the full cost had to be funded through current tax receipts
whereas the stream of benefits will accrue over a long period
of years.
But this argument simply makes the case for borrowing
to finance a certain type of federally desired outlay.

It says

nothing about who should borrow, the government itself or the
party(ies) to be assisted.

As the growth in credit programs

outside the budget shows, however, this is a more theoretical
than a practical question.

In practice, a budget dollar has a

much greater scarcity value to Congress and the Administration
than a dollar borrowed from the private sector -- borrowed with
federal assistance maybe, but no direct federal debt!
Indeed, there's little doubt that the single most
important factor that explains the growth and proliferation of
federal credit assistance is the desire to see programs funded
with a minimum use of scarce budget dollars.

An early example

of the effort to conserve budget dollars yet carry on programs
was the ingenious development of the so-called Participation
Certificate in 1966.

By carefully_ tailoring the provisions of

this instrument, the Administration sought to issue "partici­
pations" in a pool of financial assets (the claims arising out
of previous direct loans) and count the transactions a s s a l e s
of assets (i.e., negative expenditures) rather than as a means
of financing the deficit.

This particular device gave rise to

heated political debate, and the accounting practices were
changed to preclude (or at least make more difficult) such



- 8 -

practices thereafter.

But the budget pressures that spawned

initiatives of this sort continued, and so did the efforts to
escape the budget constraints with new and different credit
programs.
In 1967, the Report of the President's Commission on
Budget Concepts said that "one of the most difficult questions
the Commission has faced is how federal loan outlays should be
reflected appropriately in the budget."

In the end, the

Commission recommended, and the Administration agreed, to
include direct loans within a unified budget (rather than
deleting direct loan transactions from the budget as proposed by
some).

Prophetically, the Commission said:

"Highlighting of direct loan programs -- and strict
control of almost all of them within the budget -could create incentives to redirect federal loan
programs to some extent into government guarantee or
insurance of private loans.

These may have much the

same effect on resource allocation and on economic
impact as direct loans, even though federal funds
are not directly involved, and even though such
guarantee and insurance programs are not reflected
in the budget except for administrative expenses
i
-and defaul t s , and occasional provision of secondary
market support."
The Commission also recommended that government-sponsored enter­
prises, such as FNMA, the Federal Land Banks and the Federal Home
Loan Banks, which had previously been omitted from the (adminis­



- 9 -

trative) budget even though they were owned in part by the govern­
ment, be omitted from the (unified) budget accounts when such
enterprises were completely privately owned.

1/

As we have seen, since direct loans were not removed from
the unified budget, they stopped growing entirely, and all of the
growth in federally-assisted credit took the form of loan guar­
antees, or loans by sponsored agencies which are practically
invisible in the budget documents.

In addition, the trend toward

"debudgeting" of credit agencies accelerated.

Not only were the

Banks for Cooperatives and the Federal Intermediate Credit Banks
"privatized" (i.e., government capital replaced by private
capital, thus qualifying them as "100% privately owned" and by
this criterion out of the budget), but the Federal National
Mortgage Association also joined the parade.
At about the same time, and partly in consequence, the
functions of the housing oriented agencies -- FNMA, and FHLB -expanded from so-called secondary market operation (or in the
case of FHLB, rediscounting) designed to assure liquidity to
mortgages and mortgage lenders over the business cycle, to the
provision of funds for the housing~sector on a more or less
continuing basis.

Obviously, this change in purpose implied

a continued tapping of the bond markets to provide the funds.
/
Mere recently, we have seen a less subtle example of
debudgetization.

Since there was little hope of turning the

Export-Import Bank into a "private" institution, Congress took

]_/

Though the volume of outstanding loans of such excluded
enterprises should be shown as a prominent memorandum item.




- 10 -

the bull by the horns and simply declared in legislation that
Ex-Im's lending would be excluded from the budget totals be­
ginning August 17, 1971.

It's not just coincidental that

Ex-Im's lending is expected to jump from $250 million in FY '72
to $1.6 billion in FY '74.
Having set this precedent, one should not be surprised
at the May 1973 enactment of a bill that likewise removed the REA
2% loans from the budget, and at the same time provided REA with
broad new guarantee authority.

A similar bill is now pending to

debudget the AID 2-3% development loan program.
In essence, the growth and proliferation of credit
programs has been a consequence of the increasing scarcity of
budget^vs. non-budget dollars, and the vagaries of the defi­
nitions of what's included and excluded from the budget totals.
Related to the scarcity of budget dollars were the massive
capital expenditure programs that the federal government sought
to stimulate (if not fund) in the areas of urban renewal,
public housing, mass transit, waste treatment, etc. -- programs
that in the private sector would indeed be funded by borrowing
rather than financed out of current income.
Another spur to the expansion of federal credit assistance
has been the two bouts of very tight credit conditions that have
/
occurred in recent years, the credit crunch of 1966, and its even
tougher successor in 1969-70.

Congressional concern with the

impact of these periods of credit tightness on particular sectors
of the economy, most notably housing, stimulated a search for ways
to mitigate the impact through preferential credit facilities.



- 11 -

Out of this search, for example, came the development of mortgagebacked securities, together with a much more active role for the
housing agencies.
Increased budget pressures have thus given rise to
something like a typical life cycle in which outright grants,
say for construction, were replaced by direct loans, on grounds
that the government was only providing temporary financing that
would eventually be repaid -- a budget saving not in the short
run, but certainly in the long run.

The second step was to

transform the direct loans into guarantees of private credits,
thus costing the budget only a fraction of the total outlay and
effecting the saving immediately.

To be sure that the projects

in fact got the necessary funding without the government having
to put up much of the money, Congress authorized varying amounts
of subsidies to accompany the guarantee programs, e.g., payment
of all but 1% of interest on Section 235-236 guaranteed loans for
low income housing.
Similarly, in the area of higher education, the government
previously had made 3% direct loans to colleges for the con­
struction of academic facilities and college housing.

In 1970,

this program was phased out and instead the government agreed to
provide to private lenders interest subsidy payments of all
/
interest above 3% so that the cost to the colleges would not be
i ncreased.
-Implications of Expanded Federal Credit Programs
The more or less unfettered expansion of federal credit
programs and the accompanying deluge of agency direct and guar­



- 12 -

anteed securities to be financed in the credit markets has
undoubtedly permitted Congress and the Administration to claim
that wonder of wonders -- something for nothing, or almost
nothing.

But as with all such sleight-of-hand feats, the truth

is somewhat different.
The fact is that the growth and proliferation of federal
credit programs has created, or at least exacerbated, problems
on a number of fronts.

Some of these problems are of interest

primarily to managers of the public debt.

Others have ramifi­

cations well beyond that limited concern, touching on:
1) the control of federal expenditures generally,
2) the ability to measure the impact on the economy
of ,
:the budget"
3) the functioning of credit markets as allocators
of resources.
The uncomfortable truth is that there is very little agreement
on the net impact on resource allocation of the government's
1/
growing role in the credit markets.
To take the debt management concerns first, the basic
point is that the growth in federally-assisted debt in recent
years has significantly outpaced the growth in direct federal
debt.

Simply in terms of size of issues, frequency of financings

and anticipating cash flow problems, the task of "managing"
/
individual agency financing now requires the same expertise that
has been built up in the Treasury to manage the national debt.
Even if that expertise can be acquired -- as it has been in a

]_/

See note by John Kareken and Neil Wallace in Appendix.




- 13 -

number of instances -- 1t involves an inefficient duplication
of talent and extra administrative costs.
Similarly, there are extra costs associated with
1) introducing new agencies to the market, 2) selling issues
that are smaller than some minimum efficiently tradeable size,
3) selling securities that only in varying degree approximate
the characteristics of direct government debt in terms of
perfection of guarantee, flexibility of timing and maturities,
"cleanness" of instrument, etc.

As a result of such consider­

ations, the market normally charges a premium over the interest
cost on direct government debt of comparable maturity ranging
from 1/4 percent on the well-known federally-sponsored agencies
such as~FNMA, to more than 1/2 percent on such exotics as S3IC
debentures, New Community Bonds, etc.

In some cases (e.g., SBA

guarantees of loans to small businesses) this premium reflects
actual services rendered by the private sector, such as origina­
tion and/or servicing of loans, co-insurance, credit appraisal,
etc.

More often, however, the premium on guaranteed obligations

far more than compensates for such services.

In general, if cost

of financing were the only consideration, it would be most effi­
cient to have the Treasury itself provide the financing for direct
loans by issuing government debt in the market.*




Efficiency, however, is not the only criterion. To put all
the credit programs back in "the budget" without distinguish­
ing more clearly than at present between an "income account"
(i.e., the stream of expenditures) and "balance sheet trans­
actions" (i.e., exchanges of assets/liabilities) might exac­
erbate the problems of interpreting the economic impact of
"the budget", as discussed below.

- 14 -

Efficiency of financing is not the only debt management
cost of the proliferation of agency issues.

Since the market

views the various kinds of agency and guaranteed issues as falling
generally in a single category -- federal debt -- it makes little
sense to have one agency preparing an issue right on top of
another, or the Treasury itself.

The role of traffic cop in

terms of timing and maturity distribution of potentially competing
Issues is important to the government in minimizing costs, and
important to the smooth functioning of the debt market itself.
The Treasury has long played this role, in some cases by legis­
lative mandate, in other cases by custom.

But it's not hard to

understand that the problem of coordination has become more com­
plex as^the number of issuing entities has increased along with
the size of their issues, and as they have asserted a greater
degree of "independence" commensurate with their status "outside
the budget".

Paul Volcker, Undersecretary of the Treasury for

Monetary Affairs, made the point effectively in a 1971 talk when
he said:

"We are already at the point where some federal financing

1s coming to market at least three out of every five business days."
Off-budget financing of a growing number of federal programs
through use of federally-assisted credit has almost certainly
weakened administrative control over these programs in the Congress
/
and in the Administration. While it would be hard to prove this
point, common sense and personal experience argue strongly in its
favor.

Since contingent liabilities under guarantees are inevitably

obscured in the complexities of the budget documents and departmental
presentations, only administrative costs of such programs, and
provision for defaults, are at all prominent in the review of



- 15 -

departmental programs involving guarantees.
a fortiori for the sponsored agencies.

The same is true

As a result, there is

little awareness of, or interest in, the growth, in some cases
explosive growth, of such programs.

Nor is there any interest in

the additional costs to the government over the longer run of
financing loans via guarantees of private debt rather than through
Treasury issues.
In welcome contrast, some members of Congress have become
concerned about the cost of subsidies buried obscurely in a wide
range of federal programs, credit programs among them.

As a result,

I assume, Special Analysis E in the budget now presents a dis­
cussion of the subsidy element in federal credit programs, both
d i r e c t j o a n s and guarantees.

On commitments undertaken in FY 1972,

the annual interest subsidy (i.e., the difference between the
Tending rate and assumed borrowing cost of 8 percent) worked out
to about $880 million.

The present value of this subsidy over the

average life of the loans, also discounted at 8 percent, was some
$7 billion.

Because the President suspended new commitments under

a number of the HUD programs, e.g., for urban renewal, low-rent
public housing, subsidized mortgage insurance, etc., the budget
shows declining subsidies over the next two years in the credit
program area, measured in terms of new commitments.

No attempt

was made to value the subsidy element in outstanding loans!
Perhaps, just perhaps, one of the reasons for the re-evaluation of
some of these credit programs was because their true cost came to
M g h t for the first time.

In general, however, I'd wager that

credit programs with their leveraged budget dollars will continue
to escape the close scrutiny accorded direct budget outlays.



- 16 -

Another sort of potential "economic cost" that stems
from the growth and proliferation of federal credit programs is
the homogenization of debt coming into financial markets.

One

function that credit markets are supposed to perform is that of
distinguishing differing credit risks and assigning appropriate
risk premia.

For all of the criticisms leveled against the tech­

niques and practices of the bond rating agencies and investment
bankers, no one denies the usefulness -- to the markets and to
the economy -- of evaluating the relative economic viability of
different financial undertakings, and pricing issues accordingly.
Indeed, this is the essence of the ultimate resource allocation
function of credit markets.
- A s an increasing proportion of issues coming to the
credit markets bears the guarantee of Uncle Sam, the scope for
the market to differentiate credit risks inevitably diminishes.
With the big federal umbrella covering a growing portion of funds
moving through the credit markets, these markets become simply
vehicles for mobilizing private savings, and their role in
assessing credit risks is displaced or forgotten.

Theoretically,

the federal agencies issuing or guaranteeing debt could perform
this role, charging as costs of the programs differing rates of
insurance premia.

In practice, all of the pressures are against
/
such differential pricing of risks, even if the technical
expertise were available.

As a result, the potential exists for

reduced efficiency in resource allocation in the economy, as
federal credit programs spread.




- 17 -

Admittedly, It's impossible to measure the actual costs
of this potential resource misallocation.

Moreover, against

any such costs must be set the possibility that financial markets,
left to their own devises (i.e., without the federal programs),
do an even worse job than the government in channelling funds to
borrowers with the highest social priorities.

The net effect of

this "homogenization" argument therefore is unfortunately in doubt.
But the expansion of credit programs in particular areas should
at least take explicit account of these offsetting social and
economic costs.

(Or more accurately, differing degrees of

externalities.)
Finally, the most difficult economic question raised by
the growth of federal credit programs is the extent to which they
distort assessments of the economic impact of the federal budget
on the economy.

On the one hand, financial transactions are for

the most part excluded from the National Income Accounts budget
on grounds that such transactions simply represent exchanges of
assets/liabilities and do not themselves generate income/expend­
itures.

And the National Income Budget is generally taken to be

the most useful set of accounts for analyzing the economic impact
of the federal government.
On the other hand, there are a lot of Congressmen who
i
have been seriously deluding themselves and their constituents
if the substitution of credit program assistance for outright
grants, and the subsequent expansion of these credit programs,
has not in fact meant increasing federally-assisted claims on
real resources.



- 18 -

Apart from this fundamental conundrum, there is the
further complication of changing definitions.

It would be

difficult enough if we were dealing simply with changing magni­
tudes relative to the economy and to each other -- of loans and
expenditures in a consistently defined "budget".

But as we've

seen, major credit agencies have been "debudgeted" in recent
years, so that whatever the economic impact of their programs
(which can certainly be taken as greater than zero), this impact
has been lost sight of by those analyzing "the budget".

The same

"disappearance" applies to programs that were once funded through
direct loans but are now funded by guarantees of private credit.
If these changes were small, they could be ignored.

But in practice

they amount to several billions of dollars from one year to the next.
There is by now a fair literature on the economic impact
of federal credit programs -- most notably in the Staff Papers of
the President's Commission on Budget Concepts -- but still very
little agreement on theoretical grounds and almost no valid policy
guides, such as we have with the full employment budget.

Credit

programs, in essence, continue to fall between the cracks -confronted directly neither by the-fiscal policy advocates nor
the monetarists.
T h e o retically, the monetarists could argue that there's
I
very little to be debated here.
If the monetary authorities
simply stuck to their knitting and provided a steady increase
in the monetary base (or some other magnitude), there would be
allocation effects as the government-assisted borrowers bid
away financial resources from the rest of the market, but there
would be no risk of excessive credit creation overall, since



- 19 -

this is ruled out by definition.

In practice, I find this

"solution" no solution at all, because the real world doesn't
work 1n the way postulated.
A point of current interest -- much attention is focused
at the moment on Congress' efforts to impose on itself a more
rational mechanism for controlling aggregate federal expenditures.
This is one of the more hopeful initiatives taken by that body.
It would be too bad if the opportunity is missed to incorporate
at the same time an overall review of federally-assisted credit
programs into the new budget review process.
In summary, the costs of uncontrolled expansion of federal
credit programs, and related federal agency issues, may be thought
of as falling into two categories:

debt management costs and

economic costs, with some overlap.

In the first category may

be listed:
1) duplication of financial expertise at various agencies
2) higher costs o f -marketing agency issues than for direct
federal debt, because of
a) unfamiliarity of issues to buyers
b) small size of individual issues
c) varying degrees of "guarantee"
d) inflexibility of maturities and other terms
3) greater risk of market congestion from uncoordinated
issuing dates and terms.
The economic costs include:




1) less close scrutiny by Congress and the Administration
of loan and guarantee programs than expenditures outlays

- 20 -

2) great possibilities for hidden subsidies
3) dilution of resource allocation function of credit
markets by homogenization of credit risks
4) difficulty of measuring economic impact of growing
federal credit programs.
THE FEDERAL FINANCING BANK -- A PROPOSAL TO MITIGATE SOME OF THESE
_____________________________ PROBLEMS______________________________________
The problems cited above are not new.

But the continued

rapid growth of federal credit programs and agency issues makes
the search for some solutions more pressing.
In December 1971, the Treasury on behalf of the Adminis­
tration submitted a bill to Congress to establish a Federal Finan­
cing Bank.

Recognizing that it was not realistic, and perhaps not

even desirable, to try to turn back the clock and route a greater
portion of federally-assisted credit through direct loans financed
out of current receipts or direct government borrowing*, the
Treasury proposed the cr-eation of what is essentially a financing
shell.

The "bank" would be authorized to buy any obligation

"Issued, sold, or guaranteed" by a federal agency, and in turn
finance such purchases through sale of its own securities, which
will be obligations of the U.S.

This financing arrangement is

obviously designed to consolidate under one roof the issues of
many different agencies.

It would achieve hopefully economies

*E.g., for unsubsidized guaranteed issues, it may in fact be
preferable to have the borrower pay the higher cost associated
with partially guaranteed agency issues than get the "subsidy"
of the government's own credit costs.



- 21 -

of scale, better coordination of issues, and lower program costs
for the agencies concerned.
Apart from the potential benefits the bank might effect
as a debt management device, another provision of the bill is
designed to encourage better coordination of credit programs
through more rigorous control.

Specifically, agencies issuing

or guaranteeing securities in the market would be required to
submit financing plans in advance to the Treasury. (A second,
and potentially more important control, i.e., that no federal
agency would be permitted to guarantee issues "except in accord­
ance with a budget program submitted to the President," was
deleted from the 1973 version of the bill.)
- T h p consolidation of issues should focus attention more
widely on the scope and growth of credit programs and agency
issues, and hopefully permit the informed public to relate
anticipated demands of federally-assisted credit on the flows
of funds available -- just as is now done in relating federal
expenditures to resource availability in the economy.




A P P E N D I X

TO:

Bruce K. MacLaury, President
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

FROM:

John Kareken and Neil Wallace

SUBJECT:

Federal Credit Programs and Desired Investment

DATE:

June 4, 1973

1.

You indicated that you wanted us to take up the question "What are
!
the macroeconomic effects of Federal credit programs?" But as you
probably know, this is not a question to which one can turn to the
economics literature for a satisfactory answer.
up our own.

It is by no means complete.

We have had to make

It holds only for wealth-

maximizing economic units -- for firms and households, that is, but
probably not for nonprofit institutions such as universities and
colleges.

Moreover, it may be wrong.

That is a possibility you will

want to keep in mind when drafting your talk.
2.

There being various Federal credit programs, our answer is in
several parts:




(a)

Financial intermediation by the Federal government
has a macroeconomic effect.

More particularly, an

increase in the Federal government's portfolio of
private loans or equities, financed by an increase
in, say, the stock of Treasury securities outstanding,
1s expansionary.
results.

An increase in desired investment

-2(b)

Direct lending by the Federal government has a macroeconomic effect.

And there is an effect when the

government guarantees private-sector debts.
these effects are is not clear.

But what

A priori, 1t 1s

impossible to say what happens to desired investment
(or, therefore, aggregate demand) when the stock of
direct Federal loans or Federally-guaranteed debt
is increased.
(c)

There are various possible Federal Interest-subsidy
programs and they are not all the same in their macroeconomic effects.

If the Federal government subsidizes

firms by giving them sums of money that are proportional
to their respective outstanding debts, then desired
investment increases.

If the subsidy rate is the

difference between the market rate of interest and some
stated rate (perhaps the Federal government's own rate),
then desired investment changes.

But depending on

circumstances, it may increase or decrease.
FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION
3.

It 1s not difficult to show, using the type of analysis developed
by Professor Tobin, that financial intermediation by the Federal
government is expansionary.-^

1.




And why is easily explained.

The

See the recent paper by Craig Swan, "A General Equilibrium Model of
FNMA and FHLB Actions" (Federal Home Loan Bank Board, February 1973).

-3Federal government increases the supply of Treasury securities and,
2/

by the same amount, its demand for private-sector loans.—

Inducing

the private sector to shift from loans to Treasury securities requires
a higher rate on Treasury securities, however, and a lower rate on
private loans.

Consequently, the equilibrium rate on private-sector

loans decreases and the equilibrium rate on Treasury securities in­
creases.

And, what is most important, the equilibrium "supply price

of capital" — as Tobin has defined it, the ratio of the price of a
unit of existing physical capital to the price (reproduction cost) of
3/
a unit of new capital -- also increases.- But an increase in the
supply price cf capital is expansionary, for the higher it is the
greater is the incentive to produce new capital.
4.

There are some of us, however, who are not overly fond of explana­
tions that involve the supply price of capital (or models in which
this variable appears).

For one thing, if there is a market-determined

supply price, then presumably there is a market in which existing capital
can be bought and sold.

How does the supply price change, except by

being bid up or down in a market?

But it is surely inappropriate to

assume that there are markets for all kinds of existing capital.

2.

Professor Swan considers an increase in the supply of agency securities,
matched by an increase in the demand for private-sector loans, but that
is because he is specifically interested in the macroeconomic effects of
the operation of particular institutions. Whichever supply is increased,
whether the supply of Treasury securities or the supply of agency
securities, the result is (qualitatively) the same.

3.

The increase in the supply price of capital is not, strictly speaking,
necessary. But if a certain reasonable condition (what would seem to
be a stability condition) is satisfied, then Tobin's supply price does
increase.




-45.

Fortunately, it is possible to tell a story about financial inter­
mediation by the Federal government without mentioning the supply
price of capital.

To make it short, we assume that what the govern­

ment does is buy equities.

It finances its purchases by increasing

the supply of Treasury securities.

With a government purchase of

equities, the supply available to the private sector decreases.

And

on the most reasonable assumptions about portfolio behavior, the price
of equities increases.

In other words, the rate of return on equities

(the earnings-price ratio) decreases.
expansionary.

But a decrease in this rate is

As the rate on equities decreases, there is an increase

in the number of investment projects that can be undertaken with no
dilution of earnings per share.
6.

Thus, whether the rate of return on equities or the supply price of
capital is taken as the crucial variable, straight-forward application
of portfolio theory produces the conclusion that an increase in finan­
cial intermediation by the Federal government increases desired invest4/
ment and is therefore expansionary.— Of course, only a ceteris paribus
increase in such financial intermediation is expansionary.

If an

increase in such intermediation is accompanied by, say, an appropriate
change in the money stock, then only a reallocation of resources will
result.

There will be more investment in industries favored by Federal

financial intermediation and less in others.

4.

This conclusion requires that private-sector units view the government
as an institution apart and not, as it were, simply a mutual fund
holding a part of their portfolios.




-5DIRECT LENDING AND GUARANTEES
7.

We turn now to the Federal government's direct lending and its
guaranteeing of private-sector liabilities.
one or the other of these activities.

If suffices to analyze

For whether the Federal

government lends directly to a firm or guarantees its liabilities,
perhaps up to some limit, the effect is the same:
cost is decreased.

the firm's interest

Further, since the guaranteed liabilities of a
i

private firm are just like the liabilities of the Federal government,
the changes in the stocks of debt outstanding are the same; whether
the Federal government makes direct loans or guarantees private-sector
liabilities, there is an increase in the supply of Treasury (that is,
risk-free) securities.
8.

With a decrease in a firm's interest cost, current and expected
dividends increase.

So the price of the firm's equities increases.

Since this increase results from the change in the dividend stream,
there is, however, no decrease in the rate of return on equities.
Nor therefore is there any increase in the number of investment projects
that can be undertaken with no dilution of equity.

Direct lending does

not then result in an increase in desired investment.
9.

We have said that when the stock of Federal direct loans outstanding
increases, the (expected) dividend stream and the price of equities
also increase.

Tax payments must also increase, however, for with

more direct loans outstanding there are increased loan losses.

So

there is no increase in private-sector income (or, alternatively,
wealth).

And there is no increase in desired consumption spending.

Unless, of course, the Federal government deliberately decreases its




-6surplus.

What is expansionary then is not a ceteris paribus increase

in the stock of direct loans outstanding, but an increase that is
5/

accompanied by a decrease in the Federal budget surplus.—
'
AN ALTERNATIVE ANALYSIS OF DIRECT LENDING
10.

The conclusion of paragraph 8 -- that direct lending does not change
desired investment -- was obtained, however, using portfolio theory.
We suspect, however, that there is an important effect of Federal direct
lending, an effect on the situation of equity owners, that cannot be
taken account of within the confines of portfolio theory, and that
therefore this conclusion may well be wrong.

11.

We begin our alternative analysis by assuming, not unreasonably, that
there is a range of future states (outcomes) for some arbitrarily
selected firm.

In some of these states, the so-called bankruptcy states,

this equity value is zero.
12.

In all others, it is positive.

Suppose now that there is some investment project which is characterized
by a distribution of payoffs, there being a specific payoff for each
future state.

The problem of the firm is of course to decide whether

to undertake this project.

If it has no direct loans from the Federal

government on its books, then in so doing it will "value" all the payoffs,
even those of bankruptcy states.

This is because bankruptcy-state payoffs

are valuable to private-sector creditors.

And if the firm undertakes

this project, then the risk of default will decrease, allowing it to

5.

It might be that those who receive the extra dividends have a higher
propensity to spend than those who pay the taxes to cover the govern­
ment's loan losses. But it might also be that they have a lower
propensity to spend. The point is that if the distribution of income
is allowed to intrude, then anything can happen.




-7refinance its initial debt at a lower interest cost and thereby
increase the return to equity owners.
13.

And if all of the firm's debt is in the form of direct loans from
the Federal government? Then, since it is borrowing at the lowest
possible rate, the bankruptcy-state payoffs are worth nothing.

14.

So it is easy to imagine two firms -- one that has no direct loans
from the Federal government and one that has only direct loans —
deciding differently about any particular investment project.
a project that pays off only in bankruptcy states.
direct loans may undertake it.
not.

Consider

The firm with no

The firm with only direct loans will

Or consider a project that pays off only in nonbankruptcy states.

The firm with no direct loans may not want to undertake this project.
Even so, the firm with all direct loans may.
15.

The conclusion is therefore that direct lending by the Federal govern­
ment (or a Federal guarantee program) may increase or decrease desired
investment.

Without specifying in detail the payoff distributions of

all the various investment projects, it is not possible to say whether
such lending is expansionary or contractionary.
16.

Our inclination is to accept the conclusion that direct lending is
indeterminate in its effect on desired investment and to reject the
conclusion of paragraph 8 (that direct lending leaves desired invest­
ment unchanged).

For as we have indicated, we are not all that sure

about using portfolio theory to get at the macroeconomic effects of
Federal direct lending and loan-guarantee programs.

The conclusion

of paragraphs 3 and 5 -- that financial intermediation by the Federal
government increases desired investment and is therefore expansionary -


-8was obtained using portfolio theory.
of it.

So we should perhaps be suspicious

We are rather confident, though, that we can get this conclusion

by analyzing how governmental financial intermediation alters the
situation of equity owners and evaluations of investment projects.^
INTEREST SUBSIDIES
17.

We consider two kinds of Federal interest-subsidy programs.

The

first, our fixed-subsidy program, involves a subsidy that is independent
of the rate at which the subsidized firm or household borrows in the
market.

Whatever this rate may be, the subsidized unit receives a cer­

tain number of dollars per unit of debt.

The second type of program,

the variable-subsidy program, involves payments that depend on the market
rate of interest paid by the subsidized unit.

The government pays the

difference between this rate and some stated rate (which may be the same
as or greater or less than the government's borrowing rate).
18.

The fixed-subsidy program is in a sense expansionary.

The introduction

or extension of the coverage of such a program increases desired invest­
ment.

With or without a fixed subsidy, the subsidized unit values all

investment project payoffs, including those of bankruptcy states.

But

if there is a fixed subsidy, then there is additional revenue or payoff
in every state.

In effect, all investment projects cost less than they

otherwise would.
19.

6.

If, however, a variable-subsidy program is introduced or extended to

We should note that although the FHLB can be regarded as a governmental
intermediary, the FNMA, being privately owned, cannot. It has to be
regarded as part of the Federal government's loan guarantee program.




-9more finns and/or households, then desired investment does not
necessarily increase.

This type of program can be regarded as a

combination of a direct or guaranteed-loan program and a fixed
subsidy program, with the amount of the fixed subsidy depending
on the rate that is stated or used in calculating the subsidy.

If

this rate is the government's borrowing rate, so that under the
variable-subsidy program it pays the difference between private
/

borrowing rates and the government rate, then this program js a
direct or guaranteed-loan program.
subsidy involved.

There is no (additional) fixed

And as we have already indicated, the introduc­

tion of a direct loan program has an indeterminate effect on desired
investment.
20.

Under a variable-subsidy program, however, the government may pay
the difference between the subsidized units borrowing rate and a rate
that is greater or less than its own rate.

If it does, theq there is

some fixed-subsidy effect on desired investment -- in addition, that
is, to a direct or guaranteed-loan effect.

Even so, the introduction

or extension of the coverage of a variable-subsidy program that has a
stated rate below the government rate does not guarantee an increase
in desired investment.

But it would seem to follow from what we have

said that a decrease in the stated rate of a variable-subsidy program
(the rate used to calculate the subsidy) is expansionary.
is this rate, the greater is desired investment.




The lower