View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

WHY SHOULD WE ATTEMPT TO MANAGE
GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT?

Remarks

by
Bruce K. MacLaury
President
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

at the

WORKSHOP ON MANAGED GROWTH

University of Minnesota
October 16, 1974

The syllabus for session 1 lists five questions,

I will

address my remarks to the fourth of these, namely, "Why not continue as
we have in the past, letting private enterprise and the forces of supply
and demand determine the direction of growth?11
My remarks will be running "counter-goodform" in at least two
respects:

One, instead of concentrating on our own metropolitan area or

on the dynamics of urban growth— areas in which I must defer to the
expertise of others— I wish to apply the question at a more general
level.

Two, I will assume the role of a proponent of market forces.
With that, let me turn back to the question and as a first cut

give half an answer on the grounds that we have before us only half a
question.
The answer is that "We can't."

We can't continue relying on

an unfettered free-enterprise system to determine future patterns of
growth because such a system does not now, and has never, existed.
Governments have historically taken an active role in economic development.
Moreover, we have already been continuously changing our institutional
setting to plug up some of the "leaks"— real or imagined— that have
prevented the unfettered market from attaining the best results.
So, as a second approach, recasting the question somewhat, I
want to answer:

"We can."

We can continue as we have in the past.

Moreover, we ought to continue as we have in the past.

Expanding this

answer into an affirmative proposition I want to argue that we ought to
continue relying primarily on a private economic system, supplementing
it through government action in those cases where the potential gains
from government intervention can be firmly established.




- 2 -

This proposition, so stated, is the general guiding principle
I advocate.

It should apply to national growth and development issues

as well as regional, state and local ones.
Underlying it are two key normative premises:

One; the approach

takes maximum advantage of the inherent efficiencies of a decentralized
decision-making system.

It derives its power by harnessing, rather than

blunting, the self-interest and private motivations of individuals.
Two:

the approach suggests that the burden of proof falls

on the planner, or proponent of managed growth to
ask why the market hasn’t worked
examine how proposed intervention will work
. make a comprehensive assessment of the benefits and
costs of intervention.
At the most general level, our task is to determine the proper
balance between public and private decision-making.

In seeking this

balance, we might first note that, conceptually, we have two alternative
systems available to determine how resources are to be used.
One is the price system.

The second is the political system.

Both systems are used to allocate scarce resources to produce needed
goods and services.

Both systems influence the investments which will

determine future patterns of economic growth.
And at least conceptually, both systems are ultimately responsive
to the wishes and desires of individual citizens.

In the price system

consumers influence the allocation of resources through the dollars they
spend on different types of goods and services.

In the political system,

individuals influence policy choices and resource allocations through
the votes they cast for their elected representatives.




The important questions then become:

Which system is more

effective in determining the— in some sense— proper allocation of resources?
Or, more directly to the topic of economic growth, since the capital
investments made today will determine the course of economic growth in coming
decades, what should be the proper role of the public sector in determining
the types of investments which are made?
To understand the current and the future role of government, we
might first look to the past.

In our history we have moved from a situation

which closely approximated the laissez-faire economy of Adam Smith
to a system in which government is actively involved in the economy at all
levels in the federal system.

One might ask:

Why have governments felt

it necessary to intervene in the private economy at all?
A simple answer is that such intervention is due to dissatisfaction
with the market outcome:

the bundle of goods and services being produced

by the free-market system is in some way different from the bundle of
goods and services which consumers want.
arises out of market failures.

In a sense, government action

As the old saw goes, the government does

for the people those things which they cannot adequately provide for
themselves.
But our simple answer is not altogether satisfactory.
immediately face other, more specific questions:

For we

How severe must a market

breakdown be before government action is justified?

Can we in some objective

sense define the legitimate role of government in a free-enterprise system?
What specific types of goods and services are best produced by governments?
It seems natural to us that some goods— economists call them
public goods— can be more efficiently provided through collective action
than through individual action.




In such cases the collective benefits

- 4 -

might be relatively great but the benefits of any one individual are so
small that the public good would not be provided at all without collective
action.

Defense expenditures are perhaps the nearest thing we have to a

pure public good.
But such pure examples are relatively rare.
public goods there is a vast grey area.

In identifying

Some goods are provided both by

governments and by the private sector (housing, medical care).

Other

goods that are provided by governments might conceivably be provided by
the private sector (education)— and vice versa.
Local governments have historically provided for fire and
police protection, sewer and water systems, and health and educational
facilities.

These items may have some of the characteristics of public

goods, but need not necessarily be provided by the public sector.

For

instance, inadequate police services in some modern cities have led
citizens to purchase their own guns— in effect a substitution of private
police services for public services.
The pure public good is really an extreme example of a group
of market imperfections which we call externalities.
by now a familiar concept.

Externalities are

External pluses occur when one’s actions

result in benefits for which one cannot expect full compensation (e.g.,
education).

Conversely, external minuses occur when one’s actions result in

costs for which one is not liable.

Thus, in the former case, too little

of a good or service may be produced, simply because the individual
cannot capture compensation for the social benefits of his actions.

In

the latter case, there is a tendency to overproduce (e.g., autos) insofar
as individuals are not bearing the true costs of their actions.

Today,

economists— and planners— are increasingly aware of ways in which




- 5 -

externalities pervade the economy, and increasingly, the existence of
externalities provides a rationale for more government action.
Certainly I need not remind metro planners of the complexities
of modern industrialized urban centers.

Indeed much metro planning is

devoted to f,internalizingM the diseconomies which are external to any one
municipality.
Moreover, externalities play a prominent role in the growth and/or
decline of cities.

The mere fact that cities consist of dense concentrations

of people mean that the actions taken by any one individual or firm will
create unintended costs and benefits for others.
Businessmen are aware of some externalities or spillover effects.
Modernizing one store will very likely improve the sales of surrounding
stores.

Conversely, the physical deterioration of some establishments in

a core city no doubt reduces the attractiveness of an entire business locality.
And the failure of one homeowner to improve his property may hasten the
decline of a neighborhood and the subsequent flight to more distant
suburbs.
There are still other areas in which the market mechanism may
break down.

Some have argued that the market, left to itself, may not

adequately allocate resources between present and future generations.
Clearly, tomorrow's citizens— the persons not yet born— have
a stake in the way that resources are allocated today.

Equally clearly,

tomorrow's citizens have as yet no dollar votes to cast in the marketplace.
The result is that the market economy may take a short-sighted view of the
needs of its citizens.

Current consumption may be biased upward at the

expense of future generations.
used too quickly.

A society's depletable resources may be

Or its land base may be used in ways that unduly

constrain the possibilities open to future generations.




Our increased

- 6 -

reliance on land-use planning is a direct response to the perceived needs
of future citizens.
Another market imperfection— the final one on our list— is that
monopoly elements may hamper the effectiveness of the market mechanism.
In such instances, government action has typically come at the national
level, rather than at the state or local level.
A final reason for government intervention— though not a response
to a market imperfection per se— is to realign the distribution of income.
Such intervention has been both direct, through the use of such tools as the
income tax and indirect, through the use of specific subsidies such as
low-income housing and food stamps.
Market imperfections are fairly common in our private economy.

Some

might go so far as to suppose that the existence of such market imperfections
is a sufficient condition for heavier reliance on the alternative
allocative mechanism.

But such is not the case.

For, in looking at the political system, we find that it too is
subject to various types of inefficiencies and imperfections, some of which
are very much like the imperfections in the private economy.
First, the political system probably uses information less
efficiently than does the price system,

In the market system changes

in prices are relatively clear and unambiguous signals of changing consumer
tastes or changing resource scarcities.
system are more ambiguous.

But the signals in the political

The citizen’s vote for a political representative

may be interpreted in different ways by different people.

Certainly,

there is little guarantee that the political system will be finely tuned
to the changing needs and desires of individuals.
Secondly, there may be a mal-distribution of power in the political
system just as there is an undesirable distribution of income in the




- 7 -

private sector.

For one thing, the votes of some have often counted

for more than the votes of others because legislative districts were
not properly apportioned.

Supreme court decisions and legislative

reapportionment eliminated the worst abuses, though shifting populations
would seem to demand continuous reapportionment if all votes are always
to count equally.
Perhaps more seriously, special interest groups— which may
be thought of as somewhat analogous to monopolistic abuses in the private
economy— influence allocative decisions in the public sector just as in
the private market economy.

We need not cite in detail the abuses which

stem from the legislative process.

Suffice it to say that every special

interest group has its own sacred cow.

And too often, government action

has merely served to mandate inefficiencies in the private economy.
Moreover, since the government itself occupies a monopolistic position
in our society, its own inefficiencies and actions may be less subject
to competitive forces than are monopolistic abuses in the private sector.
Third, government actions themselves create external economies
and external diseconomies, as any city planner is well aware.

Locating

a highway or airport at one site or another creates benefits for
some citizens and creates havoc for others.
private developers1 plans.
reduce sales elsewhere.

Public parks may preclude

Decisions to renovate a downtown area may

Planners who have had to deal with these problems

on a day-to-day basis could no doubt provide a lengthy list of additional
examples.
Finally, the government itself may be ill-equipped to evaluate
the tradeoff between present and future generations.




Just as in the

- 8 -

private sector, governments may have difficulty in anticipating the
future needs of society and the types of investments which can provide
for those needs.
Of course, the private sector has also made its share of what
we now consider bad investments, bad in perhaps both a private and a
social sense.

But since no one knows the future, the investment decisions

made 20 years ago were not necessarily bad investments, given the information
available and the existing values of society.

Certainly, no corporation

of a quarter-century ago was building its plants to intentionally pollute
our lakes and streams.

Instead, those investments were made in order to

satisfy the perceived needs of the society, and it is not at all clear
that decisions made by a government agency would have been any different
or any better.
However, I would not argue that ours should be a laissez-faire
economy, or even that government’s current role should necessarily be
reduced.

Governments have played an important role in the past and will

continue to do so.

We know that there are goods and services which the

public sector must provide, simply because they would not be provided by
the private sector adequately or would not be provided at all.

Moreover,

we know that governments can play an important role in coordinating the
direction of economic growth.

Certainly this is true of metropolitan

governments.
I repeat:

our task is not that of choosing either a private

economy or a planned economy, but is instead that of finding the proper
balance between private and governmental decision making.




- 9 -

We cannot of course determine that balance in a fifteen minute
presentation.

Nor are we likely to adequately define it in the five

sessions of this symposium.

But still, I argue that finding such a balance

should be our over-riding consideration, and while still on this rather
conceptual level, I want to leave you with several thoughts:
First, the future is uncertain.

Constructing elaborate growth

plans does not mean that the plans can be implemented or that the plans
will be accepted by the citizenry.

Moreover, the technologies available

a quarter- or half-century from now may permit reorganizations in our
society which are now inconceivable.

Given so much uncertainty, any

planning that is undertaken should have as one of its key precepts that
of flexibility.
Second, governments can misallocate resources just as easily
as can private groups.

There is not convincing evidence to suggest that

fully-managed growth would have avoided many of the problems we now
face.

Indeed, in looking at a cross-section of the world's industrialized

economies, they are all beset by the same economic and technological
problems regardless of the degree of planning in their internal economies.
Third, I take it as axiomatic that there are inherent advantages
in a decentralized decision-making system.
detail— it seems to me— is impossible.

To plan the future in meticulous

The world is too complex and is

changing too rapidly to permit precise management of economic growth.
Thus, if for no other reason than by default, our society will likely
continue to rely heavily on private decentralized decision making.
A fundamental reliance on market forces already seems widely
accepted.




Indeed, in framing our analysis, what we commonly seek to do

- 10 -

is to define the proper role of government in a market economy, not the
proper role for markets in a planned economy.
Finally, given this orientation, I would argue that to justify
government planning of economic growth, the burden of proof falls on the
planner to establish what the gains from intervention might be.

Legitimate

intervention results only when the benefits of intervention are likely
to outweigh the costs.
Briefly, in closing, let's apply these fairly lofty generalizations
to the concrete problems of metropolitan areas.

Even though my concluding

comments are directed at an application of the principles I’ve argued, I
have no definitive answers to offer to planners1 problems and no specific
recommendations to make about metropolitan planning.

I deliberately—

and I think appropriately— interpret my role in this opening session as
one of laying out a broad framework and perhaps evoking from the ensuing
speakers and from you, the audience, reflections on the fundamentals of
a metropolitan planning approach.
In the metropolitan-local area setting, I can think of three—
maybe more— categories of decisions in which private— as opposed to
public— decisions have dominated much of our postwar development.

These

are housing decisions, transportation decisions, and business location
decisions.

In reality these decisions are obviously not independent of

one another.
Let's look separately at decisions to produce a new housing
unit— an investment decision, whether made by a tract builder-developer
for sale or by an individual for his/her own use.
aspect of these decisions.




Consider the "where"

In the main, thousands upon thousands of

- 11 -

private, market-type decisions have created the metropolitan cityscape
we see today— the suburbs and the exurbs.
planners as it were a blight.

Urban sprawl is viewed by

The Metropolitan Development Guide proposes

to constrain future private decisions by predesignating part of the
potential "next tier" of development land as growth areas and part of it
as no-growth areas.

And according to some calculations made by the

Metropolitan Council, that kind of planned restriction on private
decisions could save $2 billion in outlays on municipal services capital
facilities between now and 1990.

Although it is not a point I will

pursue here for lack of time, I will note that according to my earlier
proscription the projected $2 billion in capital savings would need to
be compared to costs of constraining private options before we bring in
the final verdict.
What is it about the private decisions in a metro context that
might lead to bad results within the traditional neoclassical competitive
model analysis.

Certainly the projected $2 billion dollar "waste" of

public capital that would occur through continuing urban sprawl in our
metropolitan area suggests— though it does not unequivocally establish—
the degree of market breakdown which might result from private decisions.
To pursue our example the market breaks down in fact because
diseconomies external to the production or purchase of a new residence
are very substantial.

The initial cost/price of a residential unit has

not ever included all of the costs to the community of building that
unit.

For illustration the following kinds of costs are actuarially

inevitable increments to social costs, but typically are not part of the
market calculus at the time a private decision is made (view these, of




- 12 -

course, as present-value computations of resource outlays that will be
required over an extended period as a consequence of the decision to
construct a particular unit.)
Incremental expenditures on additional school facilities to
service the unit in the future.
Incremental cost of additional municipal services.
Incremental costs of providing new public roads and
highways.
Increased costs imposed on prior users of roads and
highways due to increased congestion.
Social costs of increased loss of life and property due
to more highway traffic.
Loss of open spaces; aesthetic costs.
While I know of no creditable estimates of the magnitudes of these
social costs that escape the market pricing mechanism, I would guess
they are very substantial.
Now suppose we are able to determine in some reasonable way
the incremental costs of these external diseconomies and that, further,
we include these costs in the market price of a new home.

One result of

such an action— I would conjecture— is that metropolitan cityscape would
have been vastly different from what it is now.

The costs of turning

suburban farmland into residential units would be very much higher than
in fact it has been and very much less of it would be done while the
costs— at least relatively speaking— -of building or adding residential
units in established areas (including inner city areas) would be very
much less— and much more of it would be done.




- 13 -

I’m willing to conjecture that the end results in a general
way would have been similar to those sought by the Metropolitan Council’s
Guides to growth.
This of course is hypothetical.

I cannot argue that a practical

means can necessarily be devised to bring into the market calculus those
currently unpriced elements listed on the slide because I don’t know.
But if we scrutinize the Metropolitan Development Guide plan alongside
the Mmarket solution” I think we can better weigh the loss of options to
individual choice that planning by political authority inevitably entails.
The use of a system of development rights” discussed in some of the
Council’s publications goes part way toward restoring some options lost
under a growth/no growth arrangement but it still does not approach the
number of individual options available under an open market regime.
We could continue on in the same vein to look at decisions on
transportation services, and I think we would agree that some enormous
external diseconomies are attendant on the private decision by individuals
to buy (and operate) automobiles.

And I think we would similarly be led

to observe that if we could produce a full social-cost pricing of private
automobile travel, we could at once achieve some of the fundamental
land-use objectives sought by Metropolitan Development Guide planning
and at the same time preserve a maximum of options open to the liberties
of individual choice.
Urban renewal is another decision area that I think is also
amenable to this kind of an analysis.
In sum, then, this analytical exercise may contribute to our
review and evaluation of metropolitan growth policies in two ways:
first, it may stimulate us to explore some possibilities for market




- 14 -

correctives that may— at least in part— be translatable into practical
elements of a metropolitan program; and second, it may provide a useful
discipline to the evaluation process we apply to metropolitan and local
area planning as new programs unfold.




Contents of Slides

Slide 1
Why not continue as we have in the past, letting private enter­
prise and the forces of supply and demand determine the direction of
growth?

Slide 2
We ought to continue relying primarily on a private economic
system, supplementing it through government action in those cases
where the potential gains from government intervention can be firmly
established*

Slide 3
My underlying premises:
We should take maximum advantage of our private, decentralized
decision-making system.
The burden of proof ought to rest with planners to show
how a managed system would do better than the private
system.

Slide 4
We have two allocative systems:
The price system.
The political system.
Slide 5




Imperfections in the private economy:
Does not provide public goods and services.
Suffers from external economies and diseconomies.
May allocate resources improperly between present and
future generations.
Monopolistic abuses.

Slide 6

External economies (education, health, new technologies)
Too little of a good or service is produced.
Governments may act to encourage additional production.

External diseconomies (pollution, noise)
Too much of a good or service is produced.
Governments may act to restrict production.

Slide 7
Imperfections in the political system:
System may not be highly responsive to individual needs.
Political power may be inequitably distributed.
Government actions create external economies and diseconomies.
Government actions are based on imperfect knowledge of the
future.

Slide 8




Final considerations:
The future is uncertain and any planning must be highly
flexible.
Imperfections are common in both the market and political
systems.
A decentralized decision-making system has inherent
advantages.
Intervention by government is desirable only if the benefits
of intervention outweigh the costs.




Social Costs Not Commonly Included
in the Price of a New Residence
Incremental expenditures on additional school facilities
service the unit in the future.
Incremental cost of additional municipal services.
Incremental costs of providing new public roads and
highways.
Increased costs imposed on prior users of roads and
highways due to increased congestion.
Social costs of increased loss of life of property due
to more highway traffic.
Loss of open spaces; aesthetic costs.