View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
8:45 a.m. EST
March 25,2003

A Perspective on Inflation Targeting

Remarks by
Ben S. Bernanke
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Annual Washington Policy Conference
National Association of Business Economists
Washington, D.C.
March 25,2003

One of the more interesting developments in central banking in the past dozen
years or so has been the increasingly widespread adoption of the monetary policy
framework known as inflation targeting. The approach evolved gradually from earlier
monetary policy strategies that followed the demise of the Bretton Woods fixedexchange-rate system--most directly, I believe, from the practices of Germany's
Bundesbank and the Swiss National Bank during the latter part of the 1970s and the
1980s. For example, the Bundesbank, though it conducted short-term policy with
reference to targets for money supply growth, derived those targets each year by
calculating the rate of money growth estimated to be consistent with the bank's long-run
desired rate of inflation, normally 2 percent per year. Hence, the Bundesbank indirectly
targeted inflation, using money growth as a quantitative indicator to aid in the calibration
of its policy. Notably, the evidence suggests that, when conflicts arose between its
money growth targets and inflation targets, the Bundesbank generally chose to give
greater weight to its inflation targets (Bernanke and Mihov, 1997).1
The inflation-targeting approach became more explicit with the strategies adopted
in the early 1990s by a number of pioneering central banks, among them the Reserve
Bank of New Zealand, the Bank of Canada, the Bank of England, Sweden's Riksbank,
and the Reserve Bank of Australia. Over the past decade, variants of inflation targeting
have proliferated, with newly industrialized and emerging-market economies (Brazil,
Chile, Israel, Korea, Mexico, South Africa, the Philippines, and Thailand, among others)

1 The interpretation of the Bundesbank as a proto-inflation targeter is not universally accepted. Certainly,
the Bundesbank did not put the same emphasis on communication and transparency that modern inflationtargeting central banks do.

-2being among the most enthusiastic initiates. Most recently, this policy framework has
also been adopted by several transition economies, notably the Czech Republic, Hungary,
and Poland. 2 Central banks that have switched to inflation targeting have generally been
pleased with the results they have obtained. The strongest evidence on that score is that,
thus far at least, none of the several dozen adopters of inflation targeting has abandoned
the approach. 3
As an academic interested in monetary policy, several years ago I became
intrigued by inflation targeting and went on to co-author a book and several other pieces
about this approach. 4 As I continue to follow developments in the area, I must say,
however, that discussions of inflation targeting in the American media remind me of the
way some Americans deal with the metric system--they don't really know what it is, but
they think of it as foreign, impenetrable, and possibly slightly subversive. So, in the hope
of cutting through some of the fog, today I will offer my own, perhaps somewhat
idiosyncratic, view of inflation targeting and its potential benefits, at least in what I
consider to be its best-practice form. 5 I will also try to dispel what I feel are a few
misconceptions about inflation targeting that have gained some currency. Finally, I will
end with a few words, and one modest suggestion, about the implications of the
experience with inflation targeting for the practice of monetary policymaking at the

Mishkin and Jonas (forthcoming) describe the experiences of the three transition economies with inflation
targets.
3 A few countries that used inflation targeting in the transition to European monetary union are a partial
exception. The European Central Bank itself has an inflation objective (a ceiling of 2 percent) but does not
refer to itself as an inflation-targeting central bank, largely on the grounds that (officially, at least) it also
puts some weight on money growth in its policy decisions. As a newly created central bank presiding over
a monetary union, the ECB is unique in more fundamental ways as well; hence, the lessons from the ECB
experience for the Federal Reserve and other established central banks may be somewhat limited.
4 See in particular Bernanke and Mishkin (1997) and Bernanke, Laubach, Mishkin, and Posen (1999).
5 By focusing on what I call "best practice" inflation targeting, I must necessarily be somewhat subjective;
but then my goal today is largely normative, not descriptive.
2

-3Federal Reserve. 6 My main objective today, however, is to clarify, not to advocate. Of
course, my comments today reflect my own views and do not necessarily reflect those of
my colleagues at the Federal Reserve Board or on the Federal Open Market Committee.
Best-Practice Inflation Targeting: One View
Although inflation targeting has a number of distinguishing features--the
announcement of a quantitative target for inflation being the most obvious--capturing the
essence of the approach is not entirely straightforward. The central banks that call
themselves inflation targeters, as well as the economies they represent, are a diverse
group indeed, and (not surprisingly) institutional and operational features differ.
Moreover, many central banks that have not formally adopted the framework of inflation
targeting have clearly been influenced by the approach (or, if you prefer, the same ideas
and trends have influenced both inflation-targeters and non-inflation-targeters). For
example, over the past twenty years, the Federal Reserve, though rejecting the inflationtargeting label, has greatly increased its credibility for maintaining low and stable
inflation, has become more proactive in heading off inflationary pressures, and has
worked hard to improve the transparency of its policymaking process--all hallmarks of
the inflation-targeting approach. In short, to draw a bright line between central banks
practicing full-fledged inflation targeting and those firmly outside the inflation-targeting
camp is more difficult than one might first guess--a fact, by the way, that substantially
complicates economists' attempts to assess empirically the effects of this approach.
Nevertheless, for expository purposes, I find it useful to break down the inflation
targeting approach into two components: (1) a particular framework for making policy

For a more detailed exposition of the case for inflation targeting in the United States, see Goodfriend
(forthcoming) .

6

-4 choices, and (2) a strategy for communicating the context and rationale of these policy
choices to the broader public. Let's call these two components of inflation targeting the
policy framework and the communications strategy, for short.
The policy framework of inflation targeting
By the policy framework I mean the principles by which the policy committee
decides how to set its policy instrument, typically a short-term interest rate. In an earlier
speech, I referred to the policy framework that describes what I consider to be bestpractice inflation targeting as constrained discretion. 7 Constrained discretion attempts to
strike a balance between the inflexibility of strict policy rules and the potential lack of
discipline and structure inherent in unfettered policymaker discretion. Under constrained
discretion, the central bank is free to do its best to stabilize output and employment in the
face of short-run disturbances, with the appropriate caution born of our imperfect
knowledge of the economy and of the effects of policy (this is the "discretion" part of
constrained discretion). However, a crucial proviso is that, in conducting stabilization
policy, the central bank must also maintain a strong commitment to keeping inflation-and, hence, public expectations of inflation--firmly under control (the "constrained" part
of constrained discretion). Because monetary policy influences inflation with a lag,
keeping inflation under control may require the central bank to anticipate future
movements in inflation and move preemptively. Hence constrained discretion is an
inherently forward-looking policy approach.
Although constrained discretion acknowledges the crucial role that monetary
policy plays in stabilizing the real economy, this policy framework does place heavy

7

Bernanke (2003).

-5weight on the proposition that maintenance of low and stable inflation is a key element-perhaps I should say the key element--of successful monetary policy. The rationale for
this emphasis goes well beyond the direct benefits of price stability for economic
efficiency and growth, important as these are. The maintenance of price stability--and
equally important, the development by the central bank of a strong reputation for and
commitment to it--also serves to anchor the private sector's expectations of future
inflation. Well-anchored inflation expectations (by which I mean that the public
continues to expect low and stable inflation even if actual inflation temporarily deviates
from its expected level) not only make price stability much easier to achieve in the long
term but also increase the central bank's ability to stabilize output and employment in the
short run. Short-run stabilization of output and employment is more effective when
inflation expectations are well anchored because the central bank need not worry that, for
example, a policy easing will lead counterproductively to rising inflation and inflation
expectations rather than to stronger real activity.
In my earlier speech, I gave the Great Inflation of the 1970s in the United States

as an example of what can happen when inflation expectations are not well anchored.
Contrary to the belief in a long-run tradeoff between inflation and unemployment held by
many economists in the 1960s, unemployment and inflation in the 1970s were both high
and unstable. Even today conventional wisdom ascribes this unexpected outcome to the
oil price shocks of the 1970s. Though increases in oil prices were certainly adverse
factors, poor monetary policies in the second half of the 1960s and in the 1970s both
facilitated the rise in oil prices themselves and substantially exacerbated their effects on
the economy.

-6Monetary policy contributed to the oil price increases in the first place by creating
an inflationary environment in which excess nominal demand existed for a wide range of
goods and services. For example, in an important paper, Barsky and Kilian (2001) noted
that the prices of many industrial commodities and raw materials rose in the 1970s about
the same time as oil prices, reflecting broad-based inflationary pressures. Without these
general inflationary pressures, it is unlikely that the oil producers would have been able
to make the large increases in oil prices "stick" for any length of time.
Besides helping to make the oil price increases possible, the legacy of poor
monetary policies also exacerbated the effects of the oil price increases on output and
employment. When the oil price shocks hit, beginning in 1973, inflation expectations
had already become very unstable, after several years of increased inflationary pressures
and a failed program of price controls under President Nixon. Because inflation
expectations were no longer anchored, the widely publicized oil price increases were
rapidly transmitted into expectations of higher general inflation and, hence, into higher
wage demands and other cost pressures. Faced with an unprecedented inflationary surge,
the Fed was forced to tighten policy. As it turned out, the Fed's tightening was not
enough to contain the inflationary surge but was sufficient to generate a severe recession.
The upshot is that the deep 1973-75 recession was caused only in part by
increases in oil prices per se. An equally important source of the recession was several
years of overexpansionary monetary policy that squandered the Fed's credibility
regarding inflation, with the ultimate result that the economic impact of the oil producers'
actions was significantly larger than it had to be. Instability in both prices and the real
economy continued for the rest of the decade, until the Fed under Chairman Paul Volcker

-7re-established the Fed's credibility with the painful disinflationary episode of 1980-82.
This latter episode and its enormous costs should also be chalked up to the failure to keep
inflation and inflation expectations low and stable.
In contrast to the 1970s, fluctuations in oil prices have had far smaller effects on

both inflation and output in the United States and other industrialized countries since the
early 1980s. In part this more moderate effect reflects increased energy efficiency and
other structural changes, but I believe the dominant reason is that the use of constrained
discretion in the making of monetary policy has led to better anchoring of inflation
expectations in the great majority of industrial countries. Because inflation expectations
are now more firmly tied down, surges and declines in energy prices do not significantly
affect core inflation and thus do not force a policy response to inflation to the extent they
did three decades ago. Indeed, rather than leading to a tightening of monetary policy,
increases in oil prices today are more likely to promote consideration of increased policy
ease--a direct and important benefit of the improved control of inflation.
The communications strategy of inflation targeting
The second major element of best-practice inflation targeting (in my view) is the
communications strategy, the central bank's regular procedures for communicating with
the political authorities, the financial markets, and the general public. In general, a
central bank's communications strategy, closely linked to the idea of transparency, has
many aspects and many motivations. 8 Aspects of communication that have been
particularly emphasized by inflation-targeting central banks are the public announcement
of policy objectives (notably, the objective for inflation), open discussion of the bank's

8 In some countries, improved transparency has accompanied greater central bank independence, on the
argument that more independent central banks must also provide enhanced accountability.

-8-

policy framework (including in some cases, but not all, a timeframe for achieving the
inflation objective), and public release of the central bank's forecast or evaluation of the
economy (as reported, for example, in the Inflation Reports issued by a number of
inflation-targeting central banks).9
Why have inflation-targeting central banks emphasized communication,
particularly the communication of policy objectives, policy framework, and economic
forecasts? In the 1960s, many economists were greatly interested in adapting
sophisticated mathematical techniques developed by engineers for controlling missiles
and rockets to the problem of controlling the economy. At the time, this adaptation of socalled stochastic optimal control methods to economic policymaking seemed natural; for
like a ballistic missile, an economy may be viewed as a complicated dynamic system that
must be kept on course, despite continuous buffeting by unpredictable forces.
Unfortunately, macroeconomic policy turned out not to be rocket science! The
problem lay in a crucial difference between a missile and an economy--which is that,
unlike the people who make up an economy, the components of a missile do not try to
understand and anticipate the forces being applied to them. Hence, although a given
propulsive force always has the same, predictable effect on a ballistic missile, a given
policy action--say, a 25-basis-point cut in the federal funds rate--can have very different
effects on the economy, depending (for example) on what the private sector infers from
that action about likely future policy actions, about the information that may have

9 I refer to these features as communication rather than as rules because they simply make public the
elements of the policy framework, that is, constrained discretion. Even when the inflation target itself is set
outside the central bank or by an outside agency with the cooperation of the central bank, for the most part
inflation-targeting central banks themselves rather than outsiders (such as the legislature) are the principal
enforcers of their own targets and procedures. "Self-enforced" inflation targets are the only case I will
consider here.

-9induced the policymaker to act, about the policymaker's objectives in taking the action,
and so on. Thus, taking the "right" policy action--in this case, changing the federal
funds rate by the right amount at the right time--is a necessary but not sufficient condition
for getting the desired economic response. Most inflation-targeting central banks have
found that effective communication policies are a useful way, in effect, to make the
private sector a partner in the policymaking process. To the extent that it can explain its
general approach, clarify its plans and objectives, and provide its assessment of the likely
evolution of the economy, the central bank should be able to reduce uncertainty, focus
and stabilize private-sector expectations, and--with intelligence, luck, and persistence-develop public support for its approach to policymaking.
Of course, as has often been pointed out, actions speak louder than words; and
declarations by the central bank will have modest and diminishing value if they are not
clear, coherent, and--most important--credible, in the sense of being consistently backed
up by action. But agreeing that words must be consistently backed by actions is not the
same as saying that words have no value. In the extreme, I suppose a central bank could
run a "Marcel Marceau" monetary policy, allowing its actions to convey all its intended
meaning. But common sense suggests that the best option is to combine actions with
words--to take clear, purposeful, and appropriately timed policy actions that are
supported by coherent explanation and helpful guidance about the future.
One objection that has been raised to the public announcement of policy
objectives, economic forecasts, and (implicit or explicit) policy plans by central banks is
that even relatively modest commitments along these lines may limit their flexibility to
choose the best policies in the future. Isn't it always better to be more rather than less

- 10flexible? Shouldn't the considered judgment of experienced policymakers always trump
rules, even relatively flexible ones, for setting policy?
I agree that human judgment should always be the ultimate source of policy
decisions and that no central bank should--or is even able to--commit irrevocably in
advance to actions that may tum out to be highly undesirable. However, the intuition that
more flexibility is always better than less flexibility is quite fallacious, a point understood
long ago by Homer, who told of how Ulysses had himself tied to the mast so as not to fall
victim to the songs of the Sirens. More recently, the notion that more flexibility is always
preferable has been pretty well gutted by modem game theory (not to mention modem
monetary economics), which has shown in many contexts that the ability to commit in
advance often yields better outcomes.
For illustration of the potential benefits to policymakers of even modest selfimposed restrictions on flexibility, consider fiscal policy, which shares with monetary
policy some of the same issues that arise when a group of shifting membership makes a
series of policy decisions that have both short-run and long-run implications. In the short
run, fiscal policymakers may have important and legitimate reasons to depart from
budget balance, sometimes even substantially--for example, to appropriate funds to deal
with a national emergency or to provide a stimulus package to assist economic recovery.
In the long run, however, maintaining public confidence requires that fiscal policy be
conducted in such a way that the ratio of national debt to GDP remains stable at a
moderate level. Arguably, public confidence, and hence the ability of policymakers to
use fiscal instruments aggressively to address short-term concerns, is enhanced by
whatever legislative rules, guidelines, or procedures exist that--however gently or

- 11 -

firmly--tend to compel the policymakers to bring the budget back toward balance, and the
debt-GDP ratio back toward stability, after the crisis has passed. True, spending caps,
comprehensive budget resolutions, mandatory long-term deficit projections, and similar
provisions, to the extent that they are effective, may reduce at least a bit the flexibility of
fiscal policymakers. But if intentionally yielding a bit of flexibility increases public
confidence in the long-run sustainability of the government's spending and tax plans,
fiscal policymakers may find that adopting these rules actually enhances their ability to
act effectively in the short run.
As with fiscal policy, public beliefs about how monetary policy will perform in
the long run affect the effectiveness of monetary policy in the short run. Suppose, for
example, that the central bank wants to stimulate a weak economy by cutting its policy
interest rate. The effect on real activity will be strongest if the public is confident in the
central bank's unshakable commitment to price stability, as that confidence will moderate
any tendency of wages, prices, or long-term interest rates to rise today in anticipation of
possible future inflationary pressures generated by the current easing of policy. Now the
central bank's reputation and credibility may be entirely sufficient that no additional
framework or guidelines are needed. Certainly, in general, the greater the inherited
credibility of the central bank, the less restrictive need be the guidelines, targets, or the
like that form the central bank's communication strategy. But credibility is not a
permanent characteristic of a central bank; it must be continuously earned. Moreover, an
explicit policy framework has broader advantages, including among others increased
buy-in by politicians and the public, increased accountability, reduced uncertainty, and
greater intellectual clarity. Hence, though a central bank with strong credibility may wish

- 12to adopt a relatively loose and indicative set of guidelines for communication with the
public, even such a bank may benefit from increasing its communication with the public
and adding a bit of structure to its approach to making policy. From the public's
perspective, the central bank's commitment to a policy framework, including a long-run
inflation target, imposes the same kind of discipline and accountability on the central
bank that a long-term commitment to fiscal stability places on the fiscal authorities.
Misconceptions about Inflation Targeting
I would like to turn now, briefly, to comment on a few key misconceptions about
inflation targeting that have gained some currency in the public debate.
Misconception #1: Inflation targeting involves mechanical, rule-like
policymaking. As Rick Mishkin and I emphasized in our early expository article
(Bernanke and Mishkin, 1997), inflation targeting is a policy framework, not a rule. If it
is to be coherent and purposeful, all policy is made within some sort of conceptual
framework; the question is the degree to which the framework is explicit. Inflation
targeting provides one particular coherent framework for thinking about monetary policy
choices which, importantly, lets the public in on the conversation. If this framework
succeeds in its goals of anchoring inflation expectations, it may also make the
policymaker's ultimate task easier. But making monetary policy under inflation targeting
requires as much insight and judgment as under any policy framework; indeed, inflation
targeting can be particularly demanding in that it requires policymakers to give careful,
fact-based, and analytical explanations of their actions to the public.
Misconception #2: Inflation targeting focuses exclusively on control of inflation
and ignores output and employment objectives. Several authors have made the

- 13 distinction between so-called "strict" inflation targeting, in which the only objective of
the central bank is price stability, and "flexible" inflation targeting, which allows
attention to output and employment as well. In the early days of inflation targeting, this
distinction may have been a useful one, as a number of inflation-targeting central banks
talked the language of strict inflation targeting and one or two came close to actually
practicing it. For quite a few years now, however, strict inflation targeting has been
without significant practical relevance. In particular, I am not aware of any real-world
central bank (the language of its mandate notwithstanding) that does not treat the
stabilization of employment and output as an important policy objective. To use the
wonderful phrase coined by Mervyn King, the Governor-designate of the inflationtargeting Bank of England, there are no "inflation nutters" heading major central banks. 10
Moreover, virtually all (I am tempted to say "all") recent research on inflation targeting
takes for granted that stabilization of output and employment is an important policy
objective of the central bank. In short, in both theory and practice, today all inflation
targeting is of the flexible variety. 11
A second, more serious, issue is the relative weight, or ranking, of inflation and
unemployment (or, more precisely, the output gap) among the central bank's objectives.
Countries differ in this regard, both in formal mandate and in actual practice. 12 As an
extensive academic literature shows, however, the general approach of inflation targeting

King (1997) appears to be the source of the phrase.
Svensson (1999), who I believe coined the phrase "strict inflation targeting", calls this point
"uncontroversial." Svensson's paper and his related work also show in detail the consistency of inflation
targeting with a dual mandate.
12 A number of inflation-targeting central banks refer to inflation stabilization as the central bank's
"primary long-run objective." At one level, this statement does not have much content because inflation is
the only variable that central banks can control in the long run. Its real import is to say that the central bank
is responsible for long-run price stability, a statement that should be unobjectionable in any framework.
10
11

- 14is fully consistent with any set of relative social weights on inflation and unemployment;
the approach can be applied equally well by "inflation hawks," "growth hawks," and
anyone in between. What I find particularly appealing about constrained discretion,
which is the heart of the inflation-targeting approach, is the possibility of using it to get
better results in terms of both inflation and employment. Personally, I subscribe
unreservedly to the Humphrey-Hawkins dual mandate, and I would not be interested in
the inflation-targeting approach if I didn't think it was the best available technology for
achieving both sets of policy objectives. 13
Misconception #3: Inflation targeting is inconsistent with the central bank's
obligation to maintain financial stability. Let me address this point in the context of the

United States. The most important single reason for the founding of the Federal Reserve
was the desire of the Congress to increase the stability of American financial markets,
and the Fed continues to regard ensuring financial stability as a critical responsibility.
(By the way, this is a reason to be nervous about the recent trend of separating central
banking and financial supervision; I hope we have the sense not to do that here.) I have
always taken it to be a bedrock principle that when the stability or very functioning of
financial markets is threatened, as during the October 1987 stock market crash or the
September 11 terrorist attacks, that the Federal Reserve would take a leadership role in
protecting the integrity of the system. I see no conflict between that role and inflation
targeting (indeed, inflation targeting seems to require the preservation of financial

13 Meyer (2001) draws a distinction between a hierarchical mandate, which subordinates other objectives to
the price stability objective, and a dual mandate, which places price stability and employment objectives on
equal footing. Like Meyer, I prefer the dual mandate formulation and find it to be fully consistent with
inflation targeting. Formally, the dual mandate can be represented by a central bank loss function that
includes both inflation and unemployment (or the output gap) symmetrically.

- 15 stability as part of preserving macroeconomic stability), and I have never heard a
proponent of inflation targeting argue otherwise. 14
Inflation Targeting and the Federal Reserve
As I noted earlier, the Federal Reserve, though rejecting any explicit affiliation
with inflation targeting, has been influenced by many of the same ideas that have
influenced self-described inflation targeters. Increasingly greater transparency and more
forward-looking, proactive policy are two examples of convergence in practice between
the Fed and inflation-targeting central banks, and I think most would agree that both of
these developments have been positive and have led to better outcomes. Most important,
however, as I discussed in the earlier speech, under Chairman Volcker and Chairman
Greenspan, the Fed has moved gradually toward a policy framework of constrained
discretion.

15

In particular, through two decades of effort the Fed has restored its

credibility for maintaining low and stable inflation, which--as theory suggests--has had
the important benefit of increasing the institution's ability to respond to shocks to the real
economy. The acid test occurred in 2001, when the FOMC cut interest rates by nearly
500 basis points without any apparent adverse effect on inflation expectations.
Given the Fed's strong performance in recent years, would there be any gains in
moving further down the road toward inflation targeting? The most heated debates are

14 Here is part of a verbal reply that I made to a commenter on a paper about inflation targeting and asset
prices that Mark Gertler and I presented at the Fed's Jackson Hole conference in August 1999, as published
in the conference volume: "I want to correct the impression ... that Mark and I are somehow against
lender-of-Iast-resort activities, which is absolutely wrong. I have studied the Depression quite a bit in my
career, and I think there are two distinguishing mistakes that the Federal Reserve made. The first was to
allow a serious deflation, which an inflation targeting regime would not have permitted. And the second
was to allow the financial system to collapse, and I absolutely agree with, for example, what happened in
October 1987 and other interventions ... One advantage of the inflation targeting approach as opposed, for
example, to a currency board, is [that] it gives you considerably more scope for lender-of-Iast-resort
activities." (Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 1999, p. 145)
15 Bernanke (2003). Gramlich (2000) made a similar observation and cited empirical evidence.

- 16 said to occur on questions that are inherently impossible to prove either way, and I am
afraid that this question gives rise to one of those debates, involving as it does
counterfactual futures. Personally, though, I believe that U.S. monetary policy would be
better in the long run if the Fed chose to make its policy framework somewhat more
explicit. First, the Fed is currently in a good and historically rare situation, having built a
consensus both inside and outside the Fed for good policies. We would be smart to try to
lock in this consensus a bit more by making our current procedures more explicit and less
mysterious to the public. Second, making the Fed's inflation goals and its medium-term
projections for the economy more explicit would reduce uncertainty and assist planning
in financial markets and in the economy more generally. Finally, any additional
anchoring of inflation expectations that we can achieve now will only be helpful in the
future.
To move substantially further in the direction of inflation targeting, should it
choose to do so, the Fed would have to take two principal steps: first, to quantify
(numerically, and in terms of a specific price index) what the Federal Open Market
Committee means by "price stability", and second, to publish regular medium-term
projections or forecasts of the economic outlook, analogous to the Inflation Reports
published by both inflation-targeting central banks.
Particularly now that we are in the general range of price stability, I believe that
quantifying what the FOMC means by price stability would provide useful information to
the public and lend additional clarity to the policymaking process. Let me add a caveat
however. Despite the potential long-run benefits of such a change, FOMC members may
be concerned at this juncture that the Congress and the public would misperceive the

- 17 quantification of price stability as an elevation of the Fed's price stability objective above
its employment objective in violation of the dual mandate, even if that were in no way the
intention. Although personally I have no doubt that quantification of the price stability
objective is fully consistent with the current dual mandate, I also appreciate the delicate
issues of communication raised by such a change. Realistically, this step is unlikely to
occur without a good bit more public discussion. I hope that my talk today contributes to
that discussion. 16
The publication of medium-term forecasts does not raise nearly the same difficult
political and communication issues that quantification of price stability may, in my view,
and so I propose it here as a more feasible short-term step. The FOMC already releases
(and has released since 1979) a range and a "central tendency" of its projections for
nominal GDP growth, real GDP growth, PCE inflation, and the civilian unemployment
rate twice each year, publishing them as part of the semiannual Monetary Policy Report
to the Congress. 17 These projections are actually quite interesting, as they represent the
views of Fed policymakers of the future evolution of the economy, conditional on what
each policymaker views as the best path for future policy. Two drawbacks of these
projections as they now stand are that (1) they are sometimes not released for a number of
weeks (the time between the FOMC meeting at which they are assembled and the
Chairman's testimony to the Congress), and (2) the January projections cover only the

16 In principle, the Federal Reserve could also publish its estimate of the long-run growth potential of the
U.S. economy, for symmetry with its estimate of price stability. Unfortunately, potential output growth
tends to be variable and difficult to measure with precision. A deeper asymmetry arises from the fact that,
unlike the long-run rate of inflation, the Federal Reserve cannot control, and thus cannot be held
responsible for, the long-run economic growth rate.
17 The Monetary Policy Report is required by the Congress under Section 2B of the Federal Reserve Act.
The report is required to contain "a discussion of the conduct of monetary policy and economic
developments and prospects for the future ..." The projections may be interpreted as satisfying part of the
requirement to provide the Federal Reserve's view on prospects for the future.

- 18 remainder of the current year (the July projections cover the remainder of the current year
and all of the subsequent year).
I think it would be very useful to detach these projections from the Monetary
Policy Report and instead release them shortly after the meetings (in January and July) at

which they are compiled. I would also suggest adding a second year of forecast to the
January projection, to make it more parallel to the July projection as well as to the
forecasts in the staff-prepared Greenbook. By releasing the projections in a more timely
manner, and by adding a year to the January projection, the FOMC could provide quite
useful information to the public. In particular, the FOMC projections would convey the
policymakers' sense of the medium-term evolution of the economy, providing insight
into both the Fed's diagnosis of economic conditions and its policy objectives. 18 Ideally,
the release of these projections also would provide occasions for Governors and regional
Bank Presidents, drawing on the expertise of their respective staffs, to convey their
individual views on the prospects for the economy and the objectives of monetary policy.
Conclusion
Inflation targeting, at least in its best-practice form, consists of two parts: a policy
framework of constrained discretion and a communication strategy that attempts to focus
expectations and explain the policy framework to the public. Together, these two
elements promote both price stability and well-anchored inflation expectations; the latter
in turn facilitates more effective stabilization of output and employment. Thus, a well-

18 An alternative, suggested by Blinder et al. (2001), is to release a summary of the staff-prepared forecasts
(the "Greenbook" forecasts). I think that option is worth considering but prefer focusing on the FOMC
projections for now. The projections of the FOMC members draw heavily on the expertise of the Board
staff, as well as the staff of the regional Banks, but they also reflect the policymakers' personal views,
which I think is important. Reporting policymakers' projections rather than staff projections is in keeping
with the practices of most other central banks.

- 19 conceived and well-executed strategy of inflation targeting can deliver good results with
respect to output and employment as well as inflation.
Although communication plays several important roles in inflation targeting,
perhaps the most important is focusing and anchoring expectations. Clearly there are
limits to what talk can achieve; ultimately, talk must be backed up by action, in the form
of successful policies. Likewise, for a successful and credible central bank like the
Federal Reserve, the immediate benefits of adopting a more explicit communication
strategy may be modest. Nevertheless, making the investment now in greater
transparency about the central bank's objectives, plans, and assessments of the economy
could pay increasing dividends in the future.

- 20REFERENCES
Barsky, Robert and Lutz Kilian (2001). "Do We Really Know That Oil Caused the Great
Stagflation? A Monetary Alternative," in B. S. Bernanke and K. Rogoff, eds.,
Macroeconomics Annual, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press for NBER, pp. 137-82.
Bernanke, Ben (2003). " 'Constrained Discretion' and Monetary Policy", Remarks to the
Money Marketeers of New York University, February 3, www.federalreserve.gov.
Bernanke, Ben, Thomas Laubach, Frederic Mishkin, and Adam Posen (1999). Inflation
Targeting: Lessonsfrom the International Experience. Princeton N.J.: Princeton
University Press.
Bernanke, Ben, and Ilian Mihov (1997). "What Does the Bundesbank Target?"
European Economic Review, vol. 41, pp. 1025-53.
Bernanke, Ben, and Frederic Mishkin (1997). "Inflation Targeting: A New Framework
for Monetary Policy?" Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 11, pp. 97-116.
Blinder, Alan, Charles Goodhart, Philipp Hildebrand, David Lipton, and Charles
Wyplosz (2001). How Do Central Banks Talk? Geneva: International Center for
Monetary and Banking Studies.
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City (1999). New Challenges for Monetary Policy: A
Symposium 5ponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Jackson Hole,
Wyoming, August 26-28.
Goodfriend, Marvin (forthcoming). "Inflation Targeting in the United States?" in B.
Bernanke and M. Woodford, eds., Inflation Targeting. Chicago: U. of Chicago Press for
National Bureau of Economic Research.
Gramlich, Edward (2000). "Inflation Targeting." Remarks before the Charlotte
Economics Club, January 13.
King, Mervyn (1997). "Changes in U.K. Monetary Policy: Rules and Discretion in
Practice." Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 39 (June), pp. 81-97.
Meyer, Laurence (2001). "Inflation Targets and Inflation Targeting," Remarks at the
University of San Diego Economics Roundtable, July 17.
Mishkin, Frederic and Jiri Jonas (forthcoming). "Inflation Targeting in Transition
Economies: Experience and Prospects," in B. Bernanke and M. Woodford, eds., Inflation
Targeting. Chicago: U. of Chicago Press for National Bureau of Economic Research.
Svensson, Lars (1999). "Inflation Targeting as a Monetary Policy Rule". Journal of
Monetary Economics, vol. 43 (June), pp. 607-54.