View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
10:00 a.m., E.D.T.
August 1, 1989

Statement by
Alan Greenspan
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs
U.S. Senate

August 1, 1989

Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee:

I appreciate

this opportunity to appear before you in connection with the
Federal Reserve's semiannual Monetary Policy Report to
Congress.

In my prepared remarks today I will adhere

closely to the matter at hand—that is, monetary policy and
the state of the nation's economy.

Economic and Monetary Developments Thus Far in 1989
Over the course of this year, the contours of the
broad economic setting have changed.

As a consequence, the

stance of monetary policy also has shifted somewhat,
although the fundamental objective of our policy has not.
That objective remains to maximize sustainable economic
growth, which in turn requires the achievement of price
stability over time.
Early in the year, the Federal Reserve continued on
the path toward increased restraint upon which it had
embarked in the spring of 1988.

At the time of our report

to Congress in February of this year, I characterized the
economy as strong, with the risks on the side of a further
intensifying of price pressures.

Labor markets had been

tightening noticeably, heightening concerns that
inflationary pressures might be building.

Moreover,

increases in food and crude oil prices were raising the
major inflation indexes.

-2In view of the dimensions of the inflation threat,
the Federal Reserve tightened policy further early this
year.

Additional reserve restraint was applied through open

market operations, and the discount rate was raised 1/2
percentage point.

The determination to resist any pickup in

inflation also motivated the decision of the Federal Open
Market Committee at its February meeting to lower the ranges
for money and credit growth for 1989.

This marked the third

consecutive year in which the target ranges were reduced,
and it underscored our commitment to achieving price
stability over time.
Reflecting the economy's apparent strength and the
tighter stance of policy, interest rates rose during the
first quarter.

Short-term market rates increased around 1

percentage point over the quarter, leaving them up more than
3 points from a year earlier, but long-term rates held
relatively steady.

The year-long rise in short-term rates

had a marked impact on growth of the monetary aggregates,
restraining the demand for money as funds flowed instead
into higher-yielding market instruments.
By the beginning of the second quarter, the outlook
for spending and prices was becoming more mixed.

Scattered

indications of an emerging softening in economic activity
began to appear, prompting market interest rates to pull
back.

Rates continued to fall as a variety of factors

-3pointed to some lessening of price pressures in the period
ahead.

In particular, money growth weakened further, the

underlying trend in inflation appeared to be less severe
than markets had feared, the dollar continued to climb, and
domestic demand slackened.

Against this background, the

Federal Reserve began to ease reserve conditions in early
June.

The easing has consisted of several steps, the most

recent of which took place last week.

By the end of July,

most short-term market rates had dropped more than 1-1/2
percentage points from their March peaks, and long-term
interest rates were down somewhat less, with bond rates at
their lowest levels in more than two years.
Economic activity is estimated to have grown in the
first half of this year at a rate somewhat below that of
potential GNP.

This stands in sharp contrast to the

performance of the preceding two years during which growth
proceeded at a pace that placed increasing pressures on
labor and capital resources.

Job creation has remained the

hallmark of the current expansion, however.

Even with the

more moderate pace of economic growth in the first half of
this year, nearly 1-1/2 million new jobs were added to
payrolls.

And this occurred apparently without triggering

an acceleration in wages.
Prices did accelerate in the first six months of
this year, but most of the increase may be transitory,

-4related to supply conditions in food and petroleum markets.
After a gradual pickup over the preceding two years, price
inflation outside of food and energy held near its 1988
pace.
Excluding food and energy is one traditional way of
estimating the "underlying" rate of inflation.

Although

there is some logic in abstracting from these prices, which
are quite volatile and can be dominated over the short run
by supply disturbances, this approach is incomplete.

An

alternate picture of near-term price-setting behavior can be
gleaned by examining the components of prices, that is, the
cost pressures facing firms and the behavior of their
profits.

Such an analysis reveals that, in manufacturing,

much of the pickup in inflation thus far in 1989 is
accounted for by higher unit energy and labor costs.

The

runup in world crude oil prices, which reflected a series of
production accidents this spring as well as a degree of
output restraint on the part of some OPEC oil producers, is
the main reason for the increase in energy costs.
In contrast, movements in hourly compensation
were quite moderate in the first half of this year, and the
acceleration in unit labor costs largely reflected slower
growth in productivity.

Such a deceleration in productivity

is typical as the pace of economic activity slows.

But,

given the relatively high levels of resource utilization, it

-5also is possible that firms were forced to draw on less
skilled workers than was the case earlier in the expansion.
A significant moderation in the unit cost of imported
materials, likely reflecting the higher value of the dollar
on foreign exchange markets, provided a notable offset to
these cost pressures.

On balance, it appears that firms

have continued to experience upward pressures on costs.

The

intensity of these pressures as related to energy inputs may
well diminish in coming months, but it remains to be seen
how other elements of the cost structure will evolve.
This approach, while helpful in understanding the
interaction of prices and costs, does not tell us how an
inflation cycle begins or why it may persist.

Short-run

inflation impulses can originate from a variety of sources,
on both the demand and the supply sides of the economy.

But

over longer periods of time, inflation cannot persist
without at least passive support from the monetary
authorities.
The strength of the inflation pressures in 1988 and
into 1989 was, of course, the motive for the progressive
tightening of policy that the Federal Reserve undertook over
that period.

And the outlook for some reduction in these

pressures owes in part to that policy restraint.

The

associated rise in market interest rates, beginning early
last year, opened up wide "opportunity" costs of holding

-6money assets and resulted in a sharp slowing of money
growth.

This was especially the case for liquid deposits,

whose rates were adjusted upward only very sluggishly,
providing depositors with strong incentives to economize on
balances.
In addition to the effect of interest rates,
several special factors played a role in slowing money
growth and boosting velocity—that is, the ratio of nominal
GNP to money.

Probably the most important of these was the

unexpectedly large size of personal tax liabilities in
April.

Many individuals evidently were surprised by the

size of their liabilities, and drew down their money
balances below normal levels to make the required payments.
As the IRS cashed those checks, M2 registered outright
declines.
The difficulties of the thrift industry also may
have affected M2 growth.

Late last year, as public

attention increasingly focused on the financial condition of
the industry and its insurance fund, FSLIC-insured
institutions began to lose deposits at a significant rate.
These deposit withdrawals were particularly strong in the
first quarter of this year, and while most of the funds
apparently were repositioned within M 2 — a t commercial banks
or money funds--this factor likely also had some damping
effect on that aggregate.

-7More recently, growth of the broader monetary
aggregates has picked up markedly.

The restraint imposed by

the earlier rise in market interest rates is fading, and
households appear to be rebuilding their tax-depleted
balances.

The level of M2 on average in May was just 1

percent at an annual rate above its fourth-quarter base, but
rapid growth in June and July has lifted the year-to-date
increase to around the lower end of its 3 to 7 percent
annual target cone.

M3 also has accelerated in June and

July, placing it well into the lower half of its range.
Ml, which is the most interest-sensitive of the
monetary aggregates, declined at a 3-1/2 percent rate
through June, although it too has strengthened most
recently.

The unusual drop in Ml in the first half of the

year stemmed from sizable declines in NOW accounts and
demand deposits.

NOW accounts were reduced both by the

large personal tax payments this spring and by the high
level of interest rates, which drew savings-type balances
instead toward market instruments or other types of accounts
whose offering rates adjusted upward more quickly.

The

decline in demand deposits was related in part to a
reduction in balances that businesses are required to hold
to compensate their banks for various services; for a set
amount of services, higher market rates translate into lower
required balances.

-8Monetary Policy and the Economy into 1990
Looking ahead at the remainder of 1989 and into
1990, recent developments suggest that the balance of risks
may have shifted somewhat away from greater inflation.

Even

so, inflation remains high--clearly above our objective.
Any inflation that persists will hinder the economy's
ability to perform at peak efficiency and to create jobs.
Consequently, monetary policy will need to continue to focus
on laying the groundwork for gradual progress toward price
stability.

Such an outcome need not imply a marked downturn

in the economy, and policy will have to be alert to any
emerging indications of a cumulative weakening of activity.
However, progress on inflation and optimum growth over time
also require that our productive resources not be under such
pressures that their prices continue to rise without
abating.

In light of historical patterns of labor and

capital growth and productivity, this progress very likely
will be associated with a more moderate, and hence
sustainable, expansion in demand than we experienced in 1987
and 1988.
At its meeting last month, the Federal Open Market
Committee determined that a combination of continued
economic growth and reduced pressures on prices would be
promoted by growth of money and debt in 1989 within the
annual ranges that were set in February.

Moreover, it

-9tentatively decided to maintain these same ranges through
1990.
The specified ranges, both for this year and next,
retain the 4-percentage-point width first instituted for the
broader aggregates in 1988.

Considerable uncertainties

about the behavior of money and credit remain, and the
greater breadth allows for a range of paths for these
aggregates as financial and economic developments may
warrant.

Uncertainties about the link between the narrow

transactions aggregate, Ml, and the economy have, if
anything, increased, and the Committee once again did not
specify a range for this aggregate.
In view of the apparent variability, particularly
over the short run, in the relationships between the
monetary aggregates and the economy, policy will continue to
be carried out with attention to a wide range of economic
and financial indicators.

The complex nature of the economy

and the chance of false signals demand that we cast our net
broadly—gathering information on prices, real activity,
financial and foreign exchange markets, and related data.
While the monetary aggregates may not be preeminent
on this list, they always receive careful consideration in
our policy decisions.

This is especially true when they

exhibit unusual strength or weakness relative to past
patterns and relative to our announced ranges.

Thus, the

-10very sluggish growth in M2 for the year to date was an
important influence in the decision to begin to ease policy.
Velocity may vary considerably over a few quarters, but the
provision of liquidity, as measured by one or another of the
monetary aggregates, is an important factor in the
performance of the economy over the shorter run and over the
long run broadly determines the rate of price increase.
Over the remainder of the year, M2 should continue
to be supported by the decline in interest rates in recent
months, which, along with growth of income, is likely to
result in an expansion of that aggregate well within its
target range.

Growth in M2 likely will be augmented by a

cessation of the special influences I noted earlier that
depressed it in the first half of the year.

In particular,

households may continue to rebuild their money balances
after the tax-related drawdowns in April and May. Also,
deposit withdrawals from thrift institutions have subsided,
and enactment of legislation that restores full confidence
in the industry would bode well for deposit flows into
FSLIC-insured institutions.
Further steps in the resolution of the thrift
industry difficulties also have implications for M3. With
deposits flowing in again, thrifts will not have to rely so
heavily on the Federal Home Loan Banks for their funding as
they did earlier this year.

Partly as a result, we expect

-11M3 to strengthen from its rate of growth over the first half
of the year, moving up into the middle of its target range
by year-end.
Our outlook for debt growth foresees little change
from the pace of the first two quarters.

The broad credit

measure that we monitor, the debt of domestic nonfinancial
sectors, has grown at about an 8 percent rate this year,
near the midpoint of its 6-1/2 to 10-1/2 percent range.

We

have little reason to expect its growth through the end of
the year to be very different, implying some slowing from
the pace of 1988.

Nevertheless, the expansion of debt is

likely to exceed nominal GNP growth again this year.
Growth of money and debt within the 1989 ranges is
expected to be consistent with nominal GNP rising this year
at a pace not too far from last year's increase, according
to the projections of FOMC members and other presidents of
Reserve Banks.

These projections, however, incorporate

somewhat more inflation and less real growth than we
experienced in 1988.

The central tendency of the

projections of 2 to 2-1/2 percent real GNP growth over the
four quarters of this year implies continued moderate
economic growth throughout the year.

For the year as a

whole, these projections anticipate that growth is likely to
be strongest in the investment and export sectors of the

-12economy, with expansion of consumer expenditures and
government purchases rather subdued.
A sectoral pattern of growth such as this would in
fact serve the nation's longer-term needs by contributing to
a better external balance.

Fundamentally, improvement in

our international payments position requires productivityenhancing investment and a higher national saving rate.

In

this regard the federal government can play a significant,
positive role by reducing the budget deficit.
The outlook for inflation this year, as reflected
in the central tendency of the projections expressed at the
FOMC meeting, is for a 5 to 5-1/2 percent increase in the
consumer price index.

A figure in this range would

represent the highest annual inflation rate in the United
States since 1981; this is a source of concern to the
Federal Reserve.

Yet this rate is below that experienced in

the first six months.

This implies a considerable slowing

over the remainder of the year, reflecting earlier monetary
policy restraint and a prospective moderation in food and
energy prices.
Federal Reserve policy is focused on laying the
groundwork for more definite progress in reducing inflation
pressures in 1990, while continuing support for the economic
expansion.

The ranges provisionally established for growth

of money and debt next year are consistent with these

-13intentiona.

They allow for a noticeable pickup in money

growth from that likely to prevail this year, should that be
appropriate.

If pressures on prices and in financial

markets are less intense than in recent years, velocity
would not be expected to continue to increase, and faster
money growth, perhaps in the top half of the range, would be
needed for a time to support economic growth.

Conversely,

if price pressures prove intractable, the ranges are low
enough to permit the needed degree of monetary restraint.
Thus, although the 1990 ranges do not represent
another step in the gradual, multiyear lowering of ranges,
the Federal Reserve's intent to make further progress
against inflation remains intact.

Uncertainties about the

outlook suggested a pause in the process of reducing the
ranges; however, the Committee recognizes that our goal of
price stability will require additional downward adjustments
in these ranges over time.

Of course, as we draw closer to

1990, the economic and financial conditions prevailing will
become clearer, allowing us to approach our decisions on the
ranges with more confidence.

Hence, the current ranges for

money and credit growth in 1990 should be viewed as very
preliminary.
The economic projections for 1990 made by the
governors and Reserve Bank presidents center in a range of
1-1/2 to 2 percent real GNP growth and 4-1/2 to 5 percent

-14inflation for next year.

Naturally, as I've already noted,

there are considerable uncertainties surrounding forecasts
for 1990.

In particular, developments in the external

sector will depend in part on economic activity abroad, as
well as on the efforts of U.S. firms to become more
competitive in world markets.

Domestically, performance

will be affected by a large number of influences, including
importantly the budget deficit.

Monetary Policy in Perspective
The Federal Reserve is committed to doing its
utmost to ensure prosperity and rising standards of living
over the long run.

Given the powers and responsibilities of

the central bank, that means most importantly maintaining
confidence in our currency by maintaining its purchasing
power.

The principal role of monetary policy is to provide

a stable backdrop against which economic decisions can be
made.

A stable, predictable price environment is essential

to ensure that resources can be put to their best use and
ample investment for the future can be made.
In the long run, the link between money and prices
is unassailable.

That link is central to the mission of the

Federal Reserve, for it reminds us that without the
acquiesence of the central bank, inflation cannot take root.
Ultimately, the monetary authorities must face the

-15responsibility for lasting price trends.

While oil price

shocks, droughts, higher taxes, or new government
regulations may boost broad price indexes at one time or
another, sustained inflation requires at least the
forbearance of the central bank.

Moreover, as many nations

have learned, inflation can be corrosive.

As it

accelerates, the signals of the market system lose their
value, financial assets lose their worth, and economic
progress becomes impossible.
Thankfully, this bleak scenario is not one that we
in the United States are confronting.
a difficult balancing act.
recent years:

We do, however, face

The economy has prospered in

the economic expansion has proven

exceptionally durable, employment has surpassed all but the
most optimistic expectations, and the underlying inflation
rate, after coming down quickly in the early 1980s, has
accelerated only modestly.

But now signs of softness in the

economy have shown up.
Accordingly, it is prudent for the Federal Reserve
to recognize the risk that such softness conceivably could
cumulate and deepen, resulting in a substantial downturn in
activity.

We also recognize, however, that a degree of

slack in labor and product markets will ease the
inflationary pressures that have built up.

So our policy,

under current circumstances, is not oriented toward avoiding

-16a slowdown in demand, for a slowing from the unsustainable
rates of 1987 and 1988 is probably unavoidable.

Rather what

we seek to avoid is an unnecessary and destructive
recession.
The balance that we must strike is to support
moderate growth of demand in the near term, while
concurrently progressing toward our longer-run goal of a
stable price level. Admittedly, the balance we are seeking
is a delicate one.

I wish I could say that the business

cycle has been repealed.

But some day, some event will end

the extraordinary string of economic advances that has
prevailed since late 1982. For example, an inadvertent,
excess accumulation of inventories or an external supply
shock could lead to a significant retrenchment in economic
activity.
Moreover, I cannot rule out a policy mistake as the
trigger for a downturn.

We at the Federal Reserve might

fail to restrain a speculative surge in the economy or fail
to recognize that we were holding reserves too tight for too
long.

Given the lags in the effects of policy, forecasts

inevitably are involved and thus errors inevitably arise.
Our job is to keep such errors to an absolute minimum.

An

efficient policy is one that doesn't lose its bearings, that
homes in on price stability over time, but that copes with
and makes allowances for any unforeseen weakness in economic

-17activity.

It is such a policy that the Federal Reserve will

endeavor to pursue.