View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

.CONDUCT OF MONETARY POLICY
(Pursuant to the Full Employment and Balanced Growth
Act of 1978, P.L. 95-523)

HEARING
BEFORE THE

COMMITTEE ON
BANKING, FINANCE AND URBAN AFFAIRS
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES




NINETY-SIXTH CONGRESS
FIRST SESSION
JULY 17, 1979

Serial No. 96-22
Printed for the use of the
Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs

U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE
WASHINGTON : 1979

COMMITTEE ON BANKING, FINANCE AND URBAN AFFAIRS
HENRY S. RBUSS, Wisconsin, Chairman
J. WILLIAM STANTON, Ohio
THOMAS L. ASHLEY, Ohio
WILLIAM S. MOORHEAD, Pennsylvania
CHALMERS P. WYLIE, Ohio
FERNAND J. ST GERMAIN, Rhode Island STEWART B. McKINNEY, Connecticut
GEORGE HANSEN, Idaho
HENRY B. GONZALEZ, Texas
JOSEPH G. MINISH, New Jersey
HENRY J. HYDE, Illinois
RICHARD KELLY, Florida
FRANK ANNUNZIO, Illinois
JAMES M. HA&LEY, New York
JIM LEACH, Iowa
PARREN J. MITCHELL, Maryland
THOMAS B. EVANS, JR., Delaware
WALTER E. FAUNTROY,
S. WILLIAM GREEN, New York
RON PAUL, Texas
District of Columbia
STEPHEN L. NEAL, North Carolina
ED BETHUNE, Arkansas
JERRY M. PATTERSON, California
NORMAN D. SHUMWAY, California
JAMES J. BLANCHARD, Michigan
CARROLL A. CAMPBELL, JR.,
CARROLL HUBBARD, JR., Kentucky
South Carolina
JOHN J. LAFALCE, New York
DON RITTER, Pennyslvania
JON HINSON, Mississippi
GLADYS NOON SPELLMAN, Maryland
LES AuCOIN, Oregon
DAVID W. EVANS, Indiana
NORMAN E. D'AMOURS, New Hampshire
STANLEY N. LUNDINE, New York
JOHN J. CAVANAUGH, Nebraska
MARY ROSE OAKAR, Ohio
JIM MATTOX, Texas
BRUCE F. VENTO, Minnesota
DOUG BARNARD, Georgia
WES WATKINS, Oklahoma
ROBERT GARCIA, New York
MIKE LOWRY, Washington
PAUL NELSON, Clerk and Staff Director
MICHAEL P. FLAHERTY, General Counae*
MERCER L. JACKSON, Minority Staff Director




(II)

CONTENTS
STATEMENT OF
Miller, Hon. G. William, Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System

3

ADDITIONAL INFOKMATION SUBMITTED FOR THE RECORD
Miller, Hon. G. William:
"Midyear Monetary Policy Renort to Congress," pursuant to the Full
Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978
Response to questions of:
Hon. Henry B. Gonzalez
Hon. Mary Rose Oakar
Hon. Jerry M. Patterson
APPENDIXES
APPENDIX I.—"Briefing Materials for Mid-Year 1979 Monetary Policy Oversight," document prepared by the economics division of the Congressional
Research Service of the Library of Congress
APPENDIX II.—"Briefing Materials" prepared by the Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy
(in)




6
93
90
103

109
129

CONDUCT OF MONETARY POLICY
(Pursuant to the Full Employment and Balanced Growth
Act of 1978, Public Law 95-523)
TUESDAY, JULY 17, 1979

HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES,
COMMITTEE ON BANKING, FINANCE AND URBAN AFFAIRS,
Washington, D.O.
The committee met at 2:35 p.m., in room 2128, of the Rayburn House
Office^Building; Hon. Henry S. Reuss (chairman of the committee),
presiding.
Present: Representatives Reuss, Gonzalez, Hanley, Mitchell, Neal,
Blanchard, LaFalce, Cavanaugh, Oakar, Vento, Barnard, Watkins,
Lowry, Stanton, Wylie, McKinney, Hansen, Kelly, Leach, Evans of
Delaware, Green, Bethune, Campbell, and Ritter.
The CHAIRMAN. Good afternoon. The House Committee on Banking, Finance, and Urban Affairs will be in order for its hearings on
the conduct of monetary policy.
We are very happy to welcome Chairman G. William Miller to our
second hearing under the Humphrey-Hawkins law.
In the months ahead, Mr. Miller, the Federal Reserve will face
perhaps the most difficult test and the most challenging opportunity
of your tenure. A great many things, including the future of the
energy program announced yesterday in Kansas City by President
Carter, will hinge on whether the fire brigade at the Federal Reserve can prevent the economy from burning before the necessary
structural reforms toward which we now appear to be moving are
in place.
The months ahead will be difficult because, in addition to the high
inflation which has beset us since last year, we now see the multiplying signs of a recession. Slower growth in retail sales, especially in
autos and durable goods, declining industrial production, and surging
import bills have combined to convince a majority of economic opinion,
and now even the administration, that a recession is under way.
The task facing the Federal Reserve today was, I think, well expressed by this committee in its report to the Congress in March.
We stated:
Anti-inflationary policies must not cause a recession. The committee recog;nizes that reducing inflation will require persistent, measured monetary and fiscal
restraint. Policies which attempt to break inflation quickly would lead to recession and high unemployment and defeat themselves. Such policies would not
stop inflation because they are too costly in terms of lost output and employment.
As a result, they would be abandoned before they were in place long enough to
stop inflation and replaced instead by policies designed to fight unemployment
which would rekindle inflation.




should not respond to every weakening of 'aggregate demand by
rushing in a panic to embrace tax-cuttery and other forms of fiscal
foolishness. But I believe, this committee believes, and I hope that
you believe, that the recession which may be upon us is the enemy, not
the friend, of a successful policy to spur investment, and thus to
increase productivity and fight inflation. Therefore, it is the Federal
Reserve's clear responsibility to insure so far as possible that the
threatened recession either does not occur, or that it occurs in only
the most benign form.
The months ahead represent an opportunity for the Fed as well as a
challenge. You have on many occasions, to the press and before the
Congress, let it be known that in your opinion the Federal Reserve,
not the Treasury, should take the activist role in bringing the economy
out of any recession. This is a position that many economists, from
Keynes himself in 1930, have long urged on central bankers with
little success.
Of course, your immediate task today is to update and revise the
monetary policy plan you presented to us in February, and to present
preliminary estimates of monetary expansion, in 1980. I want to call
your attention to one point which I hope you will clarify in your
remarks. As you know, growth of M1? the narrowly-defined money
stock, has proceeded in the past 2 quarters at a 2.7 percent annual
rate. This would place M± growth squarely in the middle of your announced 1.5-4.5 'percent track, and would correspond to a sensible 5.7
percent annual growth rate of M! in the old preautomatic transfer
days, but if and only if the shifting of funds to ATS and NOW accounts has proceeded at the 3 percent annual rate that your M± growth
target subsumed.
If ATS and NOW accounts have been substituting for MI at a
slower rate, then the "true" growth rate of MI is lower than the
sensible target range you are committed to pursue. As you are the
custodian of the truth in this matter, we look forward to enlightenment.
One final matter, by no means the least important: This week, perhaps tomorrow morning, the House of Representatives will have an
opportunity to vote directly on legislation rationalizing the structure
of commercial bank reserve requirements and providing, we hope,
the tools that the Federal Reserve needs for an effective monetary
policy. H.R. 7 will solve the Federal Reserve's membership problem,
and, in so doing, it should go a long way toward ending the confusion
that has characterized measurement and interpretation of fluctuations
in the monetary aggregates in recent months. As such, it will make a
substantial contribution both to the fabrication of good monetary
policy and to a clear understanding of what that policy is by the
public at large.
So, I ask you, like myself, to pray for H.R. 7. And I want to thank
you for the excellent semiannual report which you and your associates
on the Board of Governors have handed to us. I think it is not too
much to say that it is historic in that for the first time the Federal
Reserve, pursuant to the requirements of the Humphrey-Hawkins
law, have projected such future economic matters as growth, inflation,
and employment. We believe you are doing your job very nobly, and
we are delighted to have you here.




Mr. Stanton and Mr. McKinney.
Mr. McKiNNEY. Mr. Chairman, if I might, I would just like to,
due to ia change in schedule, express my apologies to Mr. Miller for
the fact that I will have to leave, and to thank him for his note and to
reassure him that I will read his testimony in full.
The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Miller, your full report, under the rule and
without objection, is received into the record, with thanks. Would
you now proceed in your own way.
STATEMENT OF HON. G. WILLIAM MILLER, CHAIRMAN, BOARD OF
GOVERNORS, FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
Mr. MTLLER. Thank you very much.
I would like to say to the committee that I apologize for the change
in schedules and the delay that has perhaps made it a little more
^difficult for all of us to get together for this important review. The
action expected in the House has changed our testimony from tomorrow to today, and we are getting a little later start today. So I
would like to suggest, Mr. Chairman, since the report is available—
and since it does recap many of the factors that we reviewed earlier
with this committee—that I make very brief remarks and then turn
to questions.
The CHAIRMAN. Excuse me. I am told that your microphone is not on.
Mr. MILLER. There we are. Now can you hear?
The CHAIRMAN. Thank you.
Mr. MiiXER. I think they are on now. I apologize. I did not realize
they were off*
I was saying that because of the delays I would suggest making
brief remarks and then turning to the questions and concerns of the
committee.
The main event that has taken place since the report to this committee in February has been the oil price shock, and this is indeed
difficult news for us to face. The oil price shock will have the effect of
increasing inflation this year, of slowing real growth in the economy,
and therefore of setting us back in both our timetable and the level
of inflation we must deal with in the overall strategy to combat
inflation.
Without this oil shock, we had looked forward to an economy that
would slow, that would come to relatively low levels of growth, but
without ia technical recession this year or next year.
With the oil shock, we now expect that there will be a recession this
year. It will foe moderate and the economy will begin to recover as we
progress through the year and into 1980. We expect that we will have,
as you will note from our report, a negative growth rate of somewhere between minus 2 and minus one-half percent for the period
fourth quarter of 1978 to fourth quarter of 1979, and a growth rate
probably somewhere between a minus one-half to plus 2 in 1980, on
the positive side.
The oil price shock, as I say, sets us back in our timetable for
winning the war against inflation. It had been our report to this committee that with the strategic policies being put into place—involving
fiscal discipline, involving incomes policy, involving dollar and international account policies, involving energy policies, and involving




monetary policies—we would wring out inflation over 5, 6, or 7 years.
We have been put back in that timetable, in my opinion, by 1 year
or more. And we are now going to start downward in wringing out
inflation from a higher plateau than we otherwise would have reached.
The effect of the oil price shock .will probably add about 2 percent to
inflation this year, and 1 more percent to inflation next year; this is
the level of additional difficulty that we are going to have to overcome in our long-term program to wring out inflation.
In the meantime, on Sunday, the President took some initiatives
through a series of policies to reduce our dependence upon petroleum
as a source of energy and to reduce our dependence upon imported
petroleum. In the aftermath of that particular announcement, we still
must cope with the short-term and the intermediate-term problems of
the economy and be sure that we continue to commit ourselves to firmness and determination in combating inflation and that we commit
ourselves once again to a determination to maintain a sound and stable
value of (the dollar.
If we relent in our fight against inflation, if we relent in our concern for the dollar, we will set ourselves back further. So it is important not only that we absorb the shock that we have been given, but
also that we avoid imposing any further delay or any further impediment on our steady march forward to wring out inflation.
Mr. Chairman, I call your attention to the structure of our report.
There is an introduction that points out the performance of the
economy, the shocks that I have just mentioned, and their effect upon
our intermediate-term goals and long-term goals. Chapter I, in accordance with the Humphrey-Hawkins Act, is a review and analysis of
recent developments affecting the economy; it begins on page 4. Chapter II is a recitation of the objectives and plans of the Board of
Governors and the Federal Open Market Committee with respect to
the ranges of monetary aggregate growth or diminution; it begins on
page 40.
I wanted to point out to you with the charts on pages 44, 45, and 46,
in chapter II that, as you have already mentioned, the growth of the
monetary aggregates are well within the ranges that were established
for this year in our report to you in February. I say that because this
is the first opportunity I have had since becoming Chairman of the
Federal Reserve in March 1978 to be able to report that. I was afraid
you wouldn't notice it, so I wanted to call it to your attention.
I might just try to say that we did intend to have ranges that we
think are correct and to live within them.
The CHAIRMAN. Since this committee approved your ranges, it will
note this now.
Mr. MILLER. Mr^ Chairman, chapter II also includes the consensus
of the Board of Governors on the outlook for the economy and its
important aspects: nominal growth, real growth of GNP, the implicit price deflator, and the expected unemployment rate. These are
set forth in a table on page 48, and demonstrated in other charts on
the following pages.
And finally, I call your attention to chapter Ill^which is our report on how our monetary stance, our monetary objectives, relate to
the most recent plans of the administration with respect to the eco-




nomic performance of the Nation. Here, we have variance from the
President's report in terms of the outlook for the economy. But
the ranges that we have provided as a consensus of the Board of
Governors encompass and therefore are consistent with the outlook
for the economy as reported in the President's Economic Keport to
Congress.
Mr. Chairman, I would close simply by saying that the events since
my last report are historic. They will test our will and determination
as to whether we are going to continue on a course with the commitment to curb inflation and to wring it out of our economy, or
whether we are going to relent and to give way to transitory forces
and therefore, in my opinion, do more harm to the economy long term
by merely letting the fight against incipient inflationary forces be
put off to some other year or to some other generation.
The overall stance of the Federal Keserve is one of maintaining a
strong anti-inflation policy, one of maintaining the belief that we
have within the capacity of this Nation both the policies, the will,
and the determination to win this war. We commit to you that we
are going to continue to play our role in cooperation with other elements of government to achieve this.
Thank you very much.
[The Midyear Monetary Policy Keport to the Congress pursuant
to the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978, submitted by Mr. Miller follows:]




For use at 2 p.m.,
July 17, 1979

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Midyear Monetary Policy Report to Congress
Pursuant to the
Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978
July 17, 1979




Letter of Transmittal

BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE
FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
Washington, D.C., July 17, 1979
THE PRESIDENT OF THE SENATE
THE SPEAKER OF THE HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES.
The Board of Governors is pleased to submit its Midyear Monetary Policy Report to the Congress pursuant
to the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978.
Sincerely,
G. William Miller, Chairman




TABLE OF CONTENTS

Letter of Transmittal
Introduction
Chapter 1.

Chapter 2.

Chapter 3.




Recent Economic and Financial Developments
Section 1.

Economic Activity During the First
Half of 1979

Section 2.

Employment and Unemployment

22

Section 3.

Wages, Productivity, and Prices

24

Section 4.

Financial Developments

29

Objectives and Plans of the Federal Reserve
Section 1.

Outlook for Monetary Growth

41

Section 2.

Outlook for the Economy

47

The Relationship of the Federal Reserve's
Plans to the Administration's Goals
Section 1.

The Administration's Short-Term
Goals

Section 2.

The Administration's Goals and the
Federal Reserve's Plans for Monetary
Growth

55

INTRODUCTION

The Problem Posed by Accelerated Inflation

The performance of the economy this year has been distinctly
unsatisfactory.

Starting from a base of rapid inflation and the lagged

effects of the 1977-78 dollar depreciation, a series of unexpected
events this year has disrupted economic activity and intensified inflationary pressures.

These events have included labor disputes, severe

weather, and adverse agricultural supply conditions, but the most
disturbing development, in terms of its implications for future economic
performance, has been an enormous increase in the price of imported oil.
The adjustment to this oil price shock poses major problems for governmental policy and represents a serious setback to progress toward the
longer-range goals enunciated by the Full Employment and Balanced Growth
Act.
Increased energy costs have greatly aggravated our inflation
problem.

In February, when the Board submitted its first report to the

Congress under the Humphrey-Hawkins Act, it was anticipated that oil
prices would rise moderately this year, entailing some small upward
pressure on the general level of prices.

However„ the developments

since then—including the effects of the Iranian revolution and the
latest OPEC decisions—are generating major increases in the prices of
imported oil and, consequently, in the prices of other energy sources
as well.
The inflationary effects of the energy price increases could,
in principle, be offset if other prices on average declined or at least
rose less than they otherwise would have.




There will be some tendency

10
in this direction as the diversion of a larger share of spendable income
to energy results in a reduction in demand for other goods and services.
In recent years, however, nominal wages and prices have not generally
exhibited much flexibility in a downward direction; rather, relative price
adjustments typically have occurred in the context of an overall rise in
the average level of prices as economic units attempted to avoid losses
of real income.
It also must be recognized that the rise in the relative price
of imported oil involves a transfer of real income and wealth from the
U.S. public to foreign oil producers.

This loss will, in turn, have at

least temporarily depressing effects on domestic economic activity as
the demand by foreign countries for U.S. exports expands only with a
lag.
Thus, over the next year or two, it appears that exogenous
forces will be causing both intensified inflationary pressures and downward adjustments in the demand for goods and services.

Clearly, the

problems confronting monetary policy, and macroeconomic policy generally,
have been made much more difficult.

If monetary policy encourages a

more rapid expansion of money and credit in an attempt to strengthen
aggregate demand, it risks building even greater inflation into the
economic system through the aggravation of the price-wage-price spiral.
On the other hand, if no account is taken of added upward price pressures in the formulation of policy, the risks are increased of deepening
or lengthening the transitional downward adjustments in real economic
activity that now appear in train.




2

The Federal Reserve remains firmly resolved to direct its
policies toward a reduction in the rate of inflation.

But in the

current circumstances, a combination of added inflationary

pressures,

a slowing of economic activity, and a probable increase in unemployment may delay progress toward price stability.

This problem high-

lights the need to solve some of the major structural defects in our
economy.

It is important that we begin to break down the barriers,

both private and governmental, that inhibit innovation and competition
and thereby contribute to the inflationary bias of the economy.

We must

ensure that our system of taxation does not discourage the saving and
capital investment necessary to reverse the deterioration of productivity
performance observed in recent years.
And it is absolutely essential that this nation develop an
energy program that reduces its reliance on foreign sources of energy.




3

12
CHAPTER 1

"a review and analysis of recent developments
affecting economic trends in the nation"




Section 108(a) Full Employment and
Balanced Growth Act of 1978

13
SECTION 1. ECONOMIC ACTIVITY DURING THE FIRST HALF OF 1979

Official Commerce Department data for the second quarter of this
year have yet to become available, but it appears likely that they will
indicate that real gross national product declined somewhat after advancing
only marginally in the first quarter.

The sluggishness of overall economic

activity thus far in 1979 stands in marked contrast to the 4-1/4 percent
gain in real GNP registered in 1978.

Although the events of the first

half do not in themselves compel a conclusion that the economy has entered
a recession, the pause in growth does represent a significant interruption
of the relatively long cyclical upswing that began early in 1975.
The sluggishness of economic activity since the beginning of the
year is partly a consequence of the rising inflationary pressures of 1978
but is also traceable in considerable measure to special exogenous
factors—as distinguished from such problems as widespread inventory overhangs or other fundamental imbalances or distortions, which have characterized the terminal stages of previous cyclical expansions.

During January

and February, production in many parts of the country was disrupted by
unusually inclement weather; the construction industries were especially
hard hit, but other sectors also were affected.

In the early spring, labor

contract disputes in the trucking> airline, and rubber industries interfered
with activity in many areas of the economy.

However, a more pervasive—and

less transitory—influence on the course of the economy this year has been
the sharp rise in energy and food prices.

The resultant acceleration of

inflation has had a serious impact on real disposable personal income and
has had a broadly adverse effect on consumer spending attitudes.




5




14
Change from previous period,
annual rate, percent

REAL GNP

1975

1977

1976

REAL GNP
AND MAJOR SECTORS
First half of 1979

1978

1979H1

Change from '78Q4 to '79Q2,
annual rate, percent

Business
Fixed
Investment
Jllllli
GNP
Personal
illlll
Consumption
Gov't
Expenditures Purchases

Residential
Structures

Data for the first half of t97» are partially aalknatatf. .__

6

15
Personal Consumption Expenditures
Personal consumption expenditures account for almost two-thirds
of GNP, and their weakness during the past two quarters has been an important
element in the flatness of overall economic activity.

Some softness in

consumer demand was not unexpected following the surge in spending during
the final months of 1978.

However, retail sales in real terms exhibited a

clear downward trend through the first six months of this year, with the
June level sharply depressed by a drop in auto sales. Rising gasoline
prices and uncertainty about gas supplies initially had a mixed impact
on auto sales: sales of large, fuel-inefficient cars plunged, while sales
of smaller domestic and foreign cars recorded an offsetting increase.
Most recently, however, the weakness in auto sales has broadened; this
may in part reflect supply constraints as domestic makers shift facilities
to the manufacture of small cars, but there appears to have been a general
falloff in demand during June.
The weakness in consumer spending has extended beyond the market
for motor vehicles, and it appears symptomatic of broader pressures on
household finances.

The personal savings rate reached historically low

levels last year, so that a further rise in the spending propensities
of households seemed unlikely. Moreover, the record indebtedness and
debt repayment burdens of the household sector suggested that consumers
might manifest, on the whole, a more cautious spending behavior.

These

influences have been substantially reinforced this year by the effects of
accelerated inflation on the real disposable income of households. The
budgets of many families have been squeezed by the upsurge in the prices
of food, fuel, and other basic necessities. This has increased their
uneasiness about their personal financial positions and contributed to a
noticeable deterioration in consumer sentiment, as measured by most surveys.




7




16
CU REAL PERSONAL
CONSUMPTION EXPENDITURES
• REAL DISPOSABLE
Change from previous period,
annual rate, percent
PERSONAL INCOME

J_
H1

1975

1976

1977

1978

H2

1979

SAVINGS RATE

Percent

10

1975

1976

1977

1978

HOUSEHOLD DEBT REPAYMENT RELATIVE TO
DISPOSABLE PERSONAL INCOME

Percent

— 21

20

1975

1976

1977

Data for the first half of 1979 are partially estimated.

1978

1979

17
Residential Construction
As noted above, adverse weather depressed building activity during
the opening months of 1979.

Private housing starts, which had consistently

run at an annual rate of just over 2 million units since a similar weatherrelated disruption the previous winter, fell to a 1-1/2 million rate in
January and February.

However, as construction picked up again in subsequent

months, the rate of housing starts remained below the 1978 pace, averaging
about 1-3/4 million units in the March-May period.

Thus, there has been a

moderate, but significant, downturn in residential building since the end
of

1978.
Several fundamental economic and demographic factors have continued

to bolster the demand for housing—especially single-family dwellings and
condominium apartments.

One of these is the widespread view, based in

large part on the actual experience of the past several years, that houses
are a good hedge against inflation and therefore an attractive investment
apart from the shelter services they provide.

Another is the movement of

a large portion of our population into the age group in which the rate of
initial home purchases historically has been relatively high.
Nonetheless, other underlying supply and demand influences have
acted to constrain the construction of new housing units.

The rise in

interest rates and the general tightening of credit markets over the past
year have been particularly important factors.

Homebuilders have found

that lenders are charging substantially higher rates for land development
and construction credit, and that they are showing greater selectivity
in the projects they will finance.

At the same time, potential builders

and homebuyers have been affected by increasingly stringent terms on
mortgage loans and, in some localities, by shortages of mortgage credit




9

18
PRIVATE HOUSING STARTS
Annual rate, millions of units

Total
2.0

1.0

1974

1972

1970

NEW HOME PRICES
AND CPI

1976

1978 1979

index MONTHLY CARRYING COSTS
197601=100 AND PERSONAL INCOME

Single Family
Home
Price Index

lndex

1976Q1=100

Monthly
Carrying Costs,
Mortgages on
New Homes

140

120

Personal Income

Consumer
Price Index

I

1976




I

J_

1977

100

1978

!

I

1979

1976
10

1977

1978

1979

19
caused by usury ceilings.

The combination of inflated house prices and

record mortgage rates implies costs of homeownership that bulk large
relative to the current incomes of many families.

This fact has deterred

some potential homebuyers and caused lending institutions to reject some
credit applications.

It also has given impetus to the development and use

of graduated payment mortgages, which are designed to alleviate the cashflow problems encountered in the early years of the traditional level
payment loan in an inflationary environment; however, these instruments
have not thus far attained an important role in the mortgage market.
In recent months, localized shortages of gasoline and generally
uncertain prospects about 'future fuel prices and supplies likely have been
another factor deterring home purchase and prompting a reassessment of
building plans.

Still, unit sales of new and existing

single-family

houses have declined only moderately this year from the record pace of
1978.

Stocks of unsold single-family units, while perhaps less comfortable

than a few months ago when demand was stronger, do not appear to be a
significant depressant on new building activity.

Nor, in major contrast

to the last—and severe—housing cycle, is there a substantial overhang
of multifamily rental and condominium units for rent or sale.

Business Investment
Business firms have continued to pursue generally cautious
spending policies, but their investment in inventories and fixed capital
nevertheless appears to have expanded significantly in real terms during
the first half.

Despite this further advance in business spending, there

is little evidence to date of the development of broad imbalances between
stocks or productive capacity and final sales that might seriously impede
the resumption of economic expansion.




11

20
The surge in final sales in the last quarter of 1978 drew down
stocks in many lines to the point where it seemed quite likely that some
rebound in inventory investment would occur in ensuing months.

However,

the book value of business inventories increased very rapidly in the early
part of 1979, causing some concern that the unexpected strength of demand
at year-end and the acceleration of inflation might have prompted a speculative hoarding of commodities—perhaps reminiscent of 1973-74.

These

concerns abated as it became clear that the accumulation of inventories
was relatively well balanced across sectors and across levels of processing
and that much of the acceleration in the rise of book values reflected
nothing -more than the replacement of merchandise bought earlier at lower
prices with stocks acquired at current, inflated prices.

GNP accounts

data for the first quarter in fact indicate that, while there was an
appreciable pickup in real inventory investment, the rate of accumulation
remained moderate.
Inventory data for the second quarter are fragmentary.

Book-

value figures showed exceptionally high rates of accumulation in April—
especially at manufacturing concerns—but this evidently was attributable
in part to delays in shipments caused by the labor dispute in the trucking
industry.

Inventory growth, again on a book-value basis, slowed in May;

however, it appears likely that real inventory investment for the second
quarter as a whole was considerably above the pace of the first quarter.
Nevertheless, inventories appear generally to have remained in
reasonably comfortable alignment with sales.

There are, of course,

exceptions, the most notable being in the motor vehicle sector.

With the

drop in demand for large cars this spring, dealers' stocks became very
sizable in relation to the current pace of sales.




12

Stocks of smaller

21
MANUFACTURING AND TRADE
INVENTORIES

Annual rate, billions of dollars

Change in Book Value
3-Month Moving Average

1974

1975

1977

1976

CHANGE IN BUSINESS INVENTORIES
Quarterly, 1972 Dollars

1978

1979

Annual rate, billions of 1972 dollars

20

1974

1975

1976

1977

1978

1979

RATIO OF BUSINESS INVENTORIES TO SALES

Ratio

Quarterly, 1972 Dollars

1.75

1.65

1974




1975

1976

1977
13'

1978

1979

22
cars, in contrast, have been very lean in recent months, and customers
desiring particular models and features sometimes have encountered long
delivery lags. On balance, the aggregate ratio of real business inventories to real sales in the first quarter was well in line with recent
norms, but there probably was some deterioration in the picture during
the second quarter.
Business spending for new plant and equipment rose strongly
during the first quarter, providing substantial impetus to overall economic
activity; however, available evidence suggests that some decline occurred
during the second quarter. The first quarter surge reflected a sharp
rise in equipment purchases.

Outlays for transportation equipment—

especially airplanes and automobiles—accounted for a good deal of the
strength. During the spring, outlays for equipment apparently retraced
their earlier advance, owing in part to delays in shipments caused by the
labor disputes in trucking. In contrast, spending on nonresidential
structures lagged in the first quarter, as the adverse weather conditions
interfered with building activity, but then snapped back smartly in the
spring.
An important factor bolstering demands for fixed capital has been
the higher rates of industrial capacity utilization that have prevailed
since the latter part of 1978.

Slower growth of industrial production

has resulted in a slight decline in utilization rates, but the rates have
remained at levels that have been associated in the past with periods of
strong investment demand. Despite deep cutbacks in auto production, capacity utilization in manufacturing last month averaged about 85 percent—only
three percentage points below the peak of 1973 and a fairly high level
historically. Capacity utilization rates in the materials producing




14

23
REAL BUSINESS FIXED INVESTMENT
EQUIPMENT




' DURABLE

annual rate, percent

1972 Dollars
15

10

JIT

10
j_

1975

1976

1977

NONRESIDENTIAL STRUCTURES

1978

1979H1

Change from previous period,
annual rate, percent

1972 Dollars
15

10

10

1975

1976

1977

Data for the first half of 1979 are partially estimated.

15

1978

1979H1

24
industries are not, on average, as close to the 1973 peaks*

However,

that period was marked by extraordinary pressures on production facilities
caused by a worldwide boom in demand for basic commodities, and by normal
standards operating rates currently are quite high in some materials
sectors.

Government Spending
Budgetary policy at both the federal and state and local levels
of government has continued to be characterized by restraint in spending.
Indeed, government outlays for goods and services declined in real terms
during the first half of 1979.
Federal purchases had fallen slightly, after adjustment for
inflation, during 1978, and declines were recorded in each of the first
two quarters of this year.

Total federal expenditures—including transfer

payments as well as outlays for goods and services—have been running
just a bit higher in nominal terms than had been anticipated in the
administration's budget plans.

However, the impact of inflation on incomes

has resulted in considerably stronger tax receipts than were projected, so
that the budget deficit has been substantially smaller than expected.
At the state and local level, weather-related curtailments of
construction reduced spending in the first quarter.

However, the

subsequent rebound in building activity was sluggish and may be indicative
of a tendency to defer further capital expenditures following a surge last
year.

Moreover, states and localities also have been limiting spending

by holding down employment: the number of workers on their payrolls in June
was about the same as one year earlier.




16




25
Federal Government
Purchases of
Goods and Services

Change from previous period,
annual rate, percent

1972 Dollars

State and Local Government
Purchases of
Goods and Services

Change from previous period,
annual rate, percent

1972 Dollars

1975

1976

1977

Data for the first half of 1979 are partially estimated.

17

1978

1979

26
The growth of the economy after 1975, combined with tax rate
increases enacted earlier, had led to the development of sizable surpluses in the budgets of many states.
past year.

This pattern was reversed in the

Numerous tax cuts were passed in 1978, and as a result per-

sonal tax receipts were 5 percent lower in the first quarter of this year
than in same period last year—even though the tax base had increased
16 percent.

With nominal expenditures therefore rising relative to

receipts, the operating surplus of state and local governments fell to
$3.8 billion, at an annual rate, in the first quarter; it appears that
the operating budgets may have moved into slight deficit in the second
quarter.

International Trade
The large decline in the exchange value of the dollar in 1977
and 1978 has enhanced foreign demands for U.S. exports.

This, along with

a relative strengthening of economic expansion abroad, has brought about
a distinct trend of improvement in the U.S. trade position.

The nation's

merchandise trade deficit—although quite variable from month to month—
has been considerably smaller this year than on average during

1978.

Moreover, the current-account balance edged into modest surplus in the
first quarter for the first time since 1976 as receipts from overseas
investments remained strong.
Total exports advanced further in real terms during the first
quarter despite a falloff in shipments of agricultural products.

The

impact of the 1977-78 dollar depreciation was also evident in continued
relatively slow growth of non-oil imports.

On the other hand, the volume

of oil imports averaged about 9.3 million barrels per day (MMB/d) during




18

27
WEIGHTED AVERAGE EXCHANGE VALUE
OF THE U.S. DOLLAR*

March 1973=100

95

90

85
^Weighted average against other G-10 countries plus Switzerland
using total 1972-1976 average trade of these countries.

1973

1974

1975

1976

1977

U.S. MERCHANDISE TRADE AND
CURRENT ACCOUNT BALANCES

1979

1978

Seasonally adjusted, annual rate,
billions of dollars

Quarterly Data
40

20

Current Account Balance
+
o
20

Trade Balance
60

I

I
1973




1974

1975

1976
19

1977

1978

1979

28
the first three months of the year as compared to an average of 8.7 MMB/d
during 1978.

In April and May the trade deficit widened as exports

remained at about their first-quarter level while the value of both oil
and non-oil imports advanced.

A fall in the quantity of oil imported

to 8.7 MMB/d in April and May was more than offset by price changes
that began to reflect the OPEC price increases and surcharges.

The unit

value of imported oil in May was 22 percent above its level in the fourth
quarter of 1978.
The improvement in the U.S. trade and current accounts this
year has helped to bolster the private demand for dollars in foreign
\
exchange markets. The dollar rose almost 5 percent, on a trade-weighted
average against other major currencies, during the first five months
of 1979—even while the United States and other governments unwound
the heavy official intervention of late last year.

Over the past month,

however, the dollar has come under downward pressure; despite official
support, it has lost much of the earlier gain.

A relative firming of

money market conditions abroad has been a factor in this recent weakness,
but is not likely in itself a full explanation.

Foreign exchange market

participants seem to have been questioning whether the United States
will be able to deal successfully with its inflation problem, particularly
in light of the recent oil price jolt.




20

29
OPEC CRUDE OIL:
AVERAGE OFFICIAL SALES PRICE

Dollars per barrel
7/1/79^

1973

1974

1975

1976

Note: Average price includes surcharges.
Data are quarterly through 1978 and daily for selected dates thereafter.
*




21

1977

1978

1979

30
SECTION 2.

EMPLOYMENT AND UNEMPLOYMENT

Almost four years of exceptionally rapid growth in employment
had, by the end of 1978, given rise to considerable tautness in labor
markets.

Although businesses reportedly were encountering increasing

difficulty in finding workers with the desired experience and skills at
prevailing wage rates, the overall unemployment rate, at just under 6
percent, was well above past cyclical lows.

This seeming paradox

reflects in part longer-run changes in the composition of the labor
force and in the output mix of the economy; in addition, the increased
availability of unemployment compensation and other income maintenance
programs may have altered the incentives to seek or accept employment.
Despite a leveling off in production during the first quarter
of the year, monthly increases in payroll employment averaged .330,000—
well above the 280,000 per month average gain during 1978.

Gains in the

manufacturing industry were quite large, and the average factory workweek
remained at a high 40-3/4 hours.

Some easing in labor demands has become

perceptible since March, however, with employment gains averaging only
one-third of their first quarter pace.

Manufacturers have been reducing

employment levels by about 35,000 per month—with the auto industry accounting for the bulk of the decline—and the average workweek has dropped
to about 40 hours due to a cutback in overtime.

Outside of manufacturing,

hiring has continued in recent months, albeit at a reduced pace.

Still,

the unemployment rate has changed little since year-end, and such indicators as the average duration of unemployment and labor turnover rates
have remained at levels typical of fairly tight labor markets.




22

31
NONFARM PAYROLL
EMPLOYMENT

Change from previous period,
annual rate, millions

Q1Q2
I

1975

I

1976

I

1977

MANUFACTURING
EMPLOYMENT

1979

1978

Change from previous period,
annual rate, millions

Q1Q2

_L
1975

1976

1977

1978

1979

UNEMPLOYMENT RATE




Percent

I
1975

1976

I

1977
23

1978

1979

32
SECTION 3: WAGES, PRODUCTIVITY, AND PRICES

The pace of inflation has accelerated markedly this year.

The

Consumer Price Index rose at an annual rate of 13-1/2 percent through May
compared with the 9 percent increase over the course of 1978*

There has

been a comparable stepup in the advance of prices at the producer level.
Although the relatively high level of resource utilization has been a
factor sustaining the momentum of inflation, supply developments specific
to the food and energy sectors have accounted for much of the acceleration
this year in inflation.
Food prices played a substantial role in the increase in inflation
that occurred last year, and agricultural supply developments have continued
to be unfavorable.

In particular, beef production has remained on a down-

trend, leading to sharp increases in meat prices.

In addition, to rising

farm prices, the rapid increase in costs of nonfarm inputs involved in processing and marketing has contributed to the acceleration of food price
inflation.

The further rise of the federal minimum wage, for example,

was an important ingredient in the faster increase of prices for restaurant
meals in the first half.
Energy prices have risen dramatically this year.

Enormous

increases in the prices charged by the OPEC cartel, occurring against a
backdrop of significant worldwide pressures of demand on available supply,
contributed to a 37 percent annual rate of increase in the energy component
of the Consumer Price Index during the first five months of 1979.

The rise

in petroleum fuel and feedstock prices has in addition intensified cost
pressures across a broad range of U.S.




24

industries.

33

CONSUMER PRICES

Change from previous period,
annual rate, percent

TOTAL

10

FOOD

10

ENERGY
35

25

15

I

I

TOTAL EXCLUDING FOOD AND ENERGY




10

1975

1976

1977

25

1978

Dec. 1978May 1979

34
The acceleration in the rise of other prices has been less
striking than that for food and energy, but it has been appreciable.
Exclusive of food and energy items, the Consumer Price Index rose at an
annual rate of 10 percent through May, 1-1/2 percentage points faster
than the average pace throughout 1978.

Pressures placed on prices of

final products by rising materials costs have played some role in the
broad pickup in inflation.

Prices of nonferrous metals and of other

actively traded nonfood commodities rose sharply early in the year when
the year-end strength of the economy apparently led to some upward revision
in expectations of future production levels and fears of consequent commodity
shortages.

In subsequent months, however, prices of many basic nonenergy

commodities weakened as the slackening of economic activity became evident.
In addition to materials prices, labor costs have been a source
of pressure on prices this year.

The rise in wage rates generally does

not appear to have accelerated, and surveys conducted by the Council on
Wage and Price Stability indicate broad compliance with its wage standard,
especially among large firms.

However, total labor costs were boosted

by enlarged employer contributions for social security and unemployment
insurance, and compensation per hour (including private fringe benefits)
in the nonfarm business sector rose at a 10-1/4 percent annual rate in
the first quarter of the year.

Meanwhile, output per hour dropped

markedly in the first quarter, so that the unit labor costs of nonfarm
businesses increased at an annual rate of more than 15 percent.

Labor

productivity apparently declined again in the second quarter, and while




26

35
UNIT COST INDICATORS

Change from year earlier,
annual rate, percent

Nonfarm Business Sector




Compensation per Hour

10

J

I

m

—

2

12

J

1975

I

1976

1977
27

1978

1979

36
the rise in unit labor costs likely was not quite so rapid as in the
first three months of the year, it probably was fast enough to raise
the first-half advance to a rate exceeded only in 1974.




28

37
SECTION 4:

FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS

Growth of the monetary aggregates was considerably slower
during the first half of 1979 than in 1978.

At midyear, all of the

major monetary measures—M-l, M-2, and M-3—were within the expected
ranges of expansion reported by the Federal Reserve to the Congress in
February.

Commercial bank credit at midyear stood slightly above the

path implied by its projected growth range, but the pace of overall credit
expansion in the economy had moderated appreciably.

Although businesses

stepped up their borrowing somewhat during the first half of the year,
there were more than offsetting declines in borrowing by other nonfinancial
sectors.

Interest Rates
The general level of interest rates on market securities has
changed relatively little since the beginning of the year after rising
markedly during 1978.

The federal funds rate—established in trading of

immediately available funds on an overnight basis—remained around 10
percent until late April when it edged upward about one-quarter percentage
point as the Federal Reserve moved to restrict bank reserve availability
somewhat further in light of a surge in the monetary aggregates.

Despite

the small increase in the federal funds rate^ other short-term market
ratefe generally have declined somewhat on balance since December.

This

apparently is primarily a reflection of changing expectations about future
interest rate movements as economic activity gave evidence of weakening.
In long-term securities markets, bond yields reached new cyclical
highs during the first half, but retraced much of their advance in the latter




29

38
INTEREST RATES
SHORT-TERM

Percent

4-6 Month Prime
Commercial Paper

3-Month
Treasury Bill

I

I
1973

1974

1975

1976

I
1977

I
1978

LONG-TERM

1979
Percent

Home Mortgage
Interest Rate

10

Aaa Utility Bond
New Issues

1973




_L

1974

JL

I
1975

1976
30

1977

1978

1979

39
part of the spring as many investors became convinced that the peak in
money market rates had been reached.

Mortgage interest rates have continued

to rise, however, reaching record levels and prompting liberalization of
usury ceilings in many states in order to sustain lending activity.

Monetary Aggregates
After expanding rapidly earlier in 1978, M-l—demand deposits
and currency—leveled off in the fourth quarter and continued virtually
flat through the first quarter of this year.

Growth in this monetary

aggregate resumed in the spring, but the rise over the first half of 1979
was at only a 2.7 percent annual rate—considerably slower than the
7.9 percent and 7.2 percent increases registered in 1977 and 1978,
respectively.

With nominal GNP increasing at about a 9 percent rate thus

far this year, the very moderate expansion of M-l represents a substantial
shortfall from what might have been expected on the basis of historical
relations among money, GNP, and interest rates.
As was noted in the Board's February report to the Congress,
some weakness in the public's demand for M-l was anticipated because of
the introduction last November of automatic transfer services (ATS) nation- .
wide and of NOW accounts in New York State.

The Board staff had projected

that transfers from demand deposits to savings accounts associated with
these innovations might reduce M-l growth by roughly 3 percentage points
over the year ending in the fourth quarter of 1979.

The impact of such

transfers on M-l growth was about that much early in the year, but it
apparently has dropped off in recent months.

Over the past two quarters

it appears that the impact of ATS and NOWs on M-l growth has been about
2-1/4 percent, at an annual rate.




31

40

MONEY SUPPLY GROWTH
M-1

Change from previous period, annual rate, percent

12

I

1975

I

I

I

1976

I

I

I

1977

I

I

I

1978 1979H1

M-2
12

I

I
1975

1976

1977

1978

1979H1

M-3




12

I

1975

1976

1977
32

I I

I

1978 1979H1

41
Even after taking account of ATS/NOW effects, the demand for
M-l was unusually weak in the past half year, especially in the first
quarter.

It appears that, again as suggested in the February report,

the high level of interest rates reached in late 1978 prompted greater
than normal efforts to economize on non-interest-earning

cash balances.

Individuals evidently have shifted demand balances into a variety of
interest-bearing assets, including small denomination time deposits,
Treasury securities, and shares in money market mutual funds.

The

growth of the money market funds this year has been quite striking:
over the past six months, the total assets of these funds rose from
less than $11 billion to almost $26 billion.

While these funds are an

imperfect substitute for checking accounts for transactional purposes,
they have provided many individuals with a high-yielding liquid asset
that may be purchased in small denominations.
The relatively high level of interest rates this year has also
had an appreciable impact on the interest-bearing component of M-2—that
is, commercial bank time and savings deposits other than large CDs.
Deposits subject to fixed interest rate ceilings have been weak since
last fall.

Inflows to six-month money market certificates (MMCs) provided

an offset to this weakness in the fall and winter.

With a change in

regulations in mid-March that eliminated the one-quarter percentage point
differential between MMC ceilings at thrift institutions and commercial
banks when the six-month Treasury bill rate exceeds 9 percent, MMC growth
at banks accelerated and provided the impetus for a pickup in the expansion of the time and savings deposit component of M-2.

Over the first

half as a whole, this component expanded at a 7 percent annual rate




33

42
and brought M-2 growth to a 5.2 percent rate, substantially below the
8.4 percent average rate of 1978.
Growth of M-3 also has moderated in recent quarters, averaging
6-1/4 percent, at an annual rate, during the first half.

This deceler-

ation was partly a reflection of the slower growth of the narrower monetary aggregates, but reduced deposit inflows at nonbank thrift institutions
also played a role.

The slowing in thrift deposit growth was especially

noticeable after mid-March when a share of the MMC market was lost to
commercial banks, but inflows in the second quarter still exceeded the
very low rates of past periods when high market interest rates caused
serious disintermediation.

Savings and loan associations made increased

use of large-denomination time deposits, which are not subject to regulatory rate ceilings, to offset some of the weakness in other accounts.

Credit Flows
Net funds raised in credit markets by nonfinancial sectors of
the economy during the first half totaled about $355 billion, at an annual
rate, according to preliminary estimates.

This is well below the $393

billion figure for 1978 and reflects the combined impacts of monetary
restraint and a number of other factors.
One of these other factors was the diminished size of the
federal budget deficit.

With a very large year-end 1978 cash balance

further reducing the Treasury's needs for new money during the first half,
federal government borrowing fell off sharply from the 1978 pace.

In

contrast with the pattern in late 1978, when they effectively financed the
Treasury's deficit with the proceeds of dollar-support operations, foreign
central banks sold a large volume of Treasury securities in the first




34

43

FUNDS RAISED BY
NONFINANCIAL SECTORS

Billions of dollars

400

Total

300

Foreign

200

100

1975

1976

1977

Source: Federal Reserve Flow-of-Funds Accounts.
Data for the first half of 1979 are partially estimated.




35

1978

1979

44
half.

A part of the sizable private capital inflow to the United States

during the first half was channeled through the Eurodollar market to the
U.S. banking system, which acquired a substantial volume of Treasury
securities.

Households were important buyers of Treasury securities, as

they responded to the enlarged gap between rates on such instruments
and those available on deposits subject to regulatory ceilings.
State and local governments have borrowed at a reduced pace in
1979.

This decline reflects the absence of advance refundings since

last August when more restrictive regulations were promulgated by
Internal Revenue Service.

Tax-exempt bond issuance for new capital in

first half was maintained at about the 1978 level, owing largely to a
sharp increase in sales of revenue bonds for mortgage financing purposes;
the pace of such housing-related financing slowed markedly in the second
quarter, however, as a consequence of congressional proposals to curtail
the use of tax-exempt bonds to fund low rate single-family mortgages.
Casualty insurance companies and commercial banks have absorbed the bulk
of tax-exempt bonds sold this year.
Household borrowing in the consumer installment and mortgage
credit markets has leveled off this year.

Although interest rates on

consumer loans have risen during the past year, the moderation in growth
of installment debt appears to be primarily a consequence of other factors
tending to reduce consumer spending.

The flattening in mortgage flows, on

the other hand, does appear more directly a consequence of rising interest
rates and the tightening of mortgage credit supplies.
On the demand side, households have deferred home purchase or
scaled down expenditure or borrowing plans in light of the higher cost
of mortgage credit.




On the supply side, even where usury ceilings have

45
HOUSEHOLD BORROWING

Billlons of

STATE AND LOCAL GOV'T.

dollars BORROWING

NONFINANCIAL BUSINESS

BORROWING BY
dollars NONFINANCIAL BUSINESS

Billions of

Capital
Expenditures,

220

180

1975

1977

1979

Source: Federal Reserve Flow-of-Funds Accounts.
Data for the first half of 1979 are partially estimated.




Billions of dollars

46
not been a constraint, depositary institutions have pursued more cautious
loan commitment policies because of concerns about current or prospective
liquidity pressures.

Thrift institutions have reduced their mortgage

lending considerably this year as their deposit flows have diminished;
although the aggregate liquidity ratio of savings and loan associations
has remained well above the regulatory requirement, that liquidity
cushion has shrunk somewhat and the associations have borrowed heavily
from Federal Home Loan Banks and other sources.

Commercial banks, too,

have expanded their residential mortgage portfolios at a slower pace
this year, but there have been partial offsets to reduced depositary
institution lending in the form of credit flows from state and local
governments, life insurance companies, and federally sponsored agencies.
In the nonfinancial business sector, the growth of outlays for
inventories and fixed capital has outstripped that of internally generated
funds, and firms have increased their borrowing substantially.

An increased

share of the credit flow to businesses has been accounted for by commercial
banks, as many bigger firms have preferred—at current interest rates—
short- or intermediate-term bank loans to long-term bond issues with lengthy
call protection.

Commercial mortgage flows have remained large, however,

in reflection of the strength in nonresidential construction activity.

Life

insurance companies have provided a large portion of these mortgage loans
and, with pension funds, absorbed the bulk of a reduced volume of bond issues.
Commercial paper issuance was an increased source of short-term credit for
businesses in the first half, and finance company business loans continued
to grow rapidly, with much of the credit being extended to automobile dealers
to finance inventories.




38

47
Foreigners, who had borrowed in U.S. credit markets when the
dollar was weak in 1978, apparently did not expand their debt during
the first half of 1979.

This change was a significant element in the

overall decline in funds raised by nonfinancial sectors.
Financial sectors increased their borrowing in credit markets
during the first half.

Government-sponsored credit agencies stepped up

security issuance to finance assistance to the residential mortgage market.
Commercial banking firms and finance companies sold substantial volumes of
commercial paper and of bonds, including a number of floating rate issues
that offered investors a hedge against future interest rate fluctuations.
Savings and loan associations, after receiving approval from the Federal
Home Loan Bank Board, issued commercial paper for the first time; toward
midyear there were also a number of mortgage-backed bond issues by S&Ls.




39

48
CHAPTER 2

"the objectives and plans of the Board of Governors and the
Federal Open Market Committee with respect to the ranges of
growth or diminution of the monetary and credit aggregates
for the calendar year during which the report is transmitted,
taking account of past and prospective developments in employment, unemployment, production, investment, real income, productivity, international trade and payments, and prices"




Section 108(a) Full Employment and
Balanced Growth Act of 1978

49
SECTION 1.

OUTLOOK FOR MONETARY GROWTH

In February the Federal Reserve reported to the Congress on the
growth in the monetary aggregates that it expected would occur during the
current calendar year.

Expressed as ranges, and measured from the fourth

quarter of 1978 to the fourth quarter of 1979> the increases indicated were:
for M-l, 1-1/2 to 4-1/2 percent; for M-2, 5 to 8 percent; for M-3, 6 to 9
percent.

The range for M-l reflected an expectation that shifts of funds

from demand deposits to newly authorized ATS and NOW accounts would reduce
M-l growth by about 3 percentage points.

In addition, bank credit was

projected to expand by between 7-1/2 and 10-1/2 percent.
At its most recent meeting, the Federal Open Market Committee
reassessed the ranges for monetary expansion in 1979 and formulated preliminary .monetary ranges for 1980.

With respect to 1979, the Committee

decided that it was appropriate to retain the previously established
ranges for the aggregates.

In reaching this decision, particular attention

was focused on the uncertainties surrounding the behavior of M-l.

As

was noted in the preceding chapter, the estimated impact of ATS and NOW
accounts on M-l expansion has been somewhat smaller to date than had
been expected when the range was initially adopted.

However, the future

extent of shifts to these accounts cannot be predicted with precision,
especially in light of the April court decision barring ATS and certain
other payments services as of January 1, 1980.

Thus, while the Committee

retained its original range for M-l, it expected growth to vary in relation
to the range to the extent that the actual ATS/NOW impact deviates from
the 3 percentage point figure projected earlier.




41

50
Even greater uncertainties faced the Committee in its consideration of monetary growth ranges for 1980.

Apart from the question of

possible judicial or legislative action that might affect the menu of
transactions accounts available to the public, the economic circumstances
and financial requirements of a period extending 18 months into the future
obviously cannot be foreseen with much confidence.

The Committee tenta-

tively decided that the ranges for 1980 should be the same as those for
1979, with the understanding that adjustments might be necessary in
response to legal or legislative developments affecting M-l and, more
generally, in light of emerging economic conditions.

In any event, it

was recognized that the current re-examination of the definitions of the
monetary aggregates, which is being undertaken in light of the major
institutional changes that have occurred in the payments system, might
in the near future lead to a new and improved set of money stock measures.
The ranges for the broader monetary aggregates, M-2 and M-3,
allow for continued moderate growth of the interest-bearing components
of those aggregates.

In past periods of high market interest rates,

inflows of deposits subject to regulatory interest rate ceilings weakened
markedly.

Investors "disintermediated," shifting their funds from banks

and thrift institutions into higher yielding market securities.

In the

past year, however, inflows to such accounts—though smaller than in
1975-77—have been fairly well maintained.

The six-month money market

certificate, with a rate linked to Treasury bill yields, has permitted the depositary institutions to compete successfully for savings
against money market mutual funds and other instruments.
The growth ranges for the broader monetary aggregates imply
that the depositary institutions will experience adequate inflows of




42

51
lendable funds over the remainder of 1979 and in 1980.

The projections

for bank credit reflect an expectation that loan demands at commercial
banks will begin to moderate in the months ahead.

Business loan demands,

in particular, should diminish, with the corporate financing gap likely
narrowing and firms probably desiring to fund short-term debts in longerterm credit markets.
The monetary ranges established by the FOMC are consistent
with a policy of gradual reduction in rates of increase of the monetary
aggregates in order to curb inflation.

As shown in the charts on the

following pages, growth in the aggregates slowed in 1978, and a further
deceleration should occur this year.

A further deceleration in M-l

is likely to develop even in the absence of any shifting of funds from
demand deposits to ATS savings and NOW accounts.

The ranges tentatively

adopted for 1980 would permit continued slowing in monetary expansion.
However, there is considerable variability over time in the behavior
of the monetary aggregates, owing in part to financial innovations and to
changes in the public's asset preferences.

Since satisfactory economic

performance remains the basic objective of the Federal Reserve, monetary
policy, from time to time, may have to permit growth rates in the aggregates that temporarily interrupt the downward trend.




43

52
GROWTH RANGES AND ACTUAL M-1
M-1

Billions of dollars

370

. Actual
• Adopted Range
1978Q4-1979Q4

<-.^-

360

I

O

N

D
1978

J

F

M

A

M

J

J

I

A
1979

I

S

O

M-1

N

D

Billions of dollars

360

340

Percent Change
From Q4 to Q4

1975




1976

1977

44

1975

4.6

1976
1977

5.8
7.9

1978

7.2

1978

320

1979

53
GROWTH RANGES AND ACTUAL M-2
M-2

Billions of dollars

.x 8%

— 940

*'

— ———-Adopted Range
1978Q4-1979Q4

— 920

„-*• 6%

— 900

— 880

O

N

D

J

F

M

A

M

1978

J

J

A

S

O

N

D

1979

M-2

Billions of dollars

950

900

850

800

Percent Change
From Q4 to 04

1975




1976

1977
45

1975
1976
1977

8.4
10.9
9.8

1978

8.4

1978

1979

54
GROWTH RANGES AND ACTUAL M-3
M-3

Billions of dollars
. Actual
• Adopted Range
1978Q4-1979Q4

'* 9

— 1620

1580

1500

O

N

D

J

F

M

A

M

1978

J

J

A

S

O

N

D

1979

M-3

Billions of dollars
—11650

1450

1975
1976
1977
1978

1975




1976

1977

46

1978

11.1
12.7
11.7
9.3

1250

1979

55
SECTION 2.

OUTLOOK FOR THE ECONOMY

As noted in the introduction, the economy faces a difficult
adjustment to this year's oil price increases, which are aggravating
inflationary pressures and intensifying forces likely to depress
aggregate demand.

It now appears that economic activity may well

decline somewhat over the next few quarters, before turning upward
in

1980.
In the near term, real disposable income is likely to show no

more than modest gains, and consumers probably will spend cautiously.
Business spending may decline in real terms, reflecting the correction
of inventory imbalances—particularly in the auto industry—and a mild
retrenchment in fixed investment occasioned by the sluggishness of
consumer demand.

Housing construction activity can be expected to

decline somewhat further this year in response to the recent tightening
of credit conditions and to the weakness in income flows.

Export demand

should, however, tend to support activity.
During this period, industrial production and employment are
likely to edge downward.

The resulting easing of demands on productive

resources should help to contain inflation.

Pressures on credit markets

may abate and lay the groundwork for an upturn in homebuilding during

1980.
Moderate growth in real GNP should resume next year as the
initial effects of the oil shock abate and consumers begin to expand
their spending.

The completion of the inventory correction should

lead to a resumption in the growth of orders and production.

Employ-

ment growth would pick up in this environment, but it seems probable




47

56
that the pace of hiring will not be strong enough to cut into unemployment.
Inflation should edge lower, though progress may be quite gradual owing
to the strong upward momentum of unit labor costs, the continuing relatively tight supplies of some agricultural commodities, and the further
adjustment of the system to higher energy costs.
The economic outlook currently is obscured by exceptional
uncertainties, and the range of possible outcomes appears quite wide.
However, In order to improve understanding of the monetary objectives,
an economic projection representing the consensus of the Board members
at this time has been summarized in the table below and in a series
of charts on the next several pages.

Actual
1978

Projections
1979

1980

Change from fourth quarter
to fourth quarter, percent
Nominal GNP

13.1

8 to 10

8-1/2 to 11-1/2

Real GNP

4.4

-2 to -1/2

Implicit price deflator

8.3

9-1/2 to 11

8-1/2 to 10-1/2

5.8

6-1/4 to 7

6-3/4 to 8-1/4

-1/2 to 2

Average level in fourth
quarter, percent
Unemployment rate




48

57
Ratio scale, billions of dollars

NOMINAL GNP

2700
2500
2300

2100
1900

Percent Change
From Q4 to Q4
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974

4.5
9.5
11.7
11.1
7.2

1975
1976
1977
1978

10.0
9.5
11.9
13.1

1979
1980

I

1970




I

J_

1972

1976

49

1978

1500

1300

1100

8 to 10

S'/z to 11
I

I

1974

1700

I
1980

58
REAL GNP

Ratio scale, billions of 1972 dollars

1300

1200

I

1970




I

1972

I

1974

1976
50

1978

1980

59
QNP IMPLICIT PRICE DEFLATOR

Ratio scale, index, 1972=100

180

160

140

Percent Change
From Q4 to Q4

1970
1971

5.1
4.7

1972 4.2
1973 7.5
1974 11.0

1970




1972

1974

I

I

1976

51

1975

7.5

1976

4.7

1977

6.1

1978
1979
1980

8.3

100

8%to10!4
I

I

1978

1980

60
UNEMPLOYMENT RATE
Percent
Annual
Averages Q4 Levels

1970

4.9

1971
1972

5.9
5.6

1973

4.9

1974

5.6

5.9
6.0
5.3
4.8
6.5

1975

8.5

8.3

1976

7.7

7.7

1977
1978

7.0
6.0

6.6
5.8

1979

—

6'/4to7

1980

—

1970




1972

1974

1976
52

J

1978

L

1980

61
CHAPTER 3

"the relationship of the [Federal Reserve's] objectives
and plans to the short-term goals set forth in the most
recent Economic Report of the President"




Section 108(a) Full Employment and
Balanced Growth Act of 1978

62
SECTION 1;

THE ADMINISTRATION'S SHORT-TERM GOALS

The administration has recently announced its forecast_' of
key economic variables in association with the midyear budget update.
This forecast, which assumes no major new fiscal initiatives, contains
some significant changes from the figures contained in the January
Economic Report of the President.

In particular, real economic growth

through 1980 has been reduced and inflation has been raised.

The Administration's Forecast

1979

1980

9.2

10.3

Change from fourth quarter
to fourth quarter, percent
Nominal GNP
Real GNP

-0.5

Implicit price deflator

9.8

2.0
8.1

Average level in fourth quarter,
percent
Unemployment rate

_!/

The January Economic Report equated the 1979-1980 forecast with
short-run goals.




54

63
SECTION 2.

THE ADMINISTRATION'S GOALS AND THE FEDERAL RESERVE'S PLANS FOR
MONETARY GROWTH

The monetary ranges set by the Federal Reserve should be adequate
to finance the amount of spending in current dollars projected by the
administration.

However, the administration's forecast does seem to

envision a somewhat more favorable combination of real output and inflation
than that suggested by the Board's consensus projection.

The actual price-

output mix will be determined primarily by supply conditions and by other
structural or behavioral characteristics of the economy.

These relation-

ships are not known with certainty, of course, and thus many different
price-output combinations must be viewed as possible for given rates of
monetary growth.
Monetary growth rates are much more closely related in the
short run to nominal GNP than they are to the division of nominal GNP
between output and prices.

The tradeoff between output and price might

be improved, however, through the use of other policy tools.

Govern-

mental action to eliminate regulatory or market impediments to price
competition could be helpful in tempering inflationary pressures.

So,

too, could a continuing program of voluntary wage-price guidelines,
which may help in restraining the anticipatory actions that have made
the wage-price spiral so intractable.

The nation's ability to avoid an

escalation of inflation over the next year or so—without serious recessionwill depend in considerable degree on whether a means is found to overcome
the tendency for workers and businesses to seek higher wages and prices in
an effort to offset the effects of the income transfer associated with
the rise in oil prices.

Over the longer run, the ability of the nation

to achieve sustained growth of real income will depend importantly on
whether it can solve its energy problem.




55

64

The CHAIRMAN. Thank you, Mr. Miller.
We will now inquire, under the rule. You have said before this committee many times—and I take it you would say again—that in the
event that action is necessary to shorten and gentle whatever recession
we may be getting into, that the way you prefer doing that is by not
using the fiscal approach, that is to say, large tax cuts or large increased
budgetary expenditures which add to demand, but instead to provide
whatever ease is needed by modest monetary ease, because that is what
makes investment possible and investment produces greater productivity and greater productivity fights inflation.
As a general principle, and not in the context of today's events necessarily, but as a general principle, do you still, I hope, hold that view ?
And if Congress will help you set the stage by not being panicked into
precipitating tax cuts or expenditure increases, will you find it easier
to carry out that scenario than you would otherwise ?
Mr. MILLER. Mr. Chairman, as a matter of policy preference, I would
reiterate my feeling that the mix of policies for business cycles would
be better achieved by use of flexible monetary policy and more stable
and disciplined fiscal policy.
We must, as you point out, measure that preference in policy to the
particular circumstances at any moment. One of the particular reasons
that I favor that policy is that, looking at the past, our responses to
business downturns quite often has been to add on another layer of
Federal Government spending, This is very hard to unwind when the
economy turns in another direction, so that you are caught with a constant building up of layer upon layer, just as the paint on a ship's hull
keeps getting layered until the paint gets so heavy that the ship sinks.
This is what we need to avoid.
The other aspect of fiscal policy—the taxing side—of course, is less
subject to that criticism, because in an inflationary environment
incomes move up into higher tax brackets and there is a natural draining that occurs from fiscal policy even without action. So, from time
to time, it is appropriate to begin to adjust appropriate tax factors.
But I want to reiterate that my preference would be to use the more
flexible monetary policy to accommodate business cycles and to adjust
the direction of the economy, giving due recognition not only to the
condition of the domestic economy and the position and pasture of fiscal
policy, but also to the way in which foreign exchange markets and the
value of the dollar impact upon our domestic economy and contribute
to our inflation problems.
So, I believe we are still of one mind in this. Our skills in implementation will be tested in coming months. I would like to reemphasize your
view, which is that it is important that we continue to base our decisions, in the Congress, the Federal Reserve, and the administration, on
facts and realities, and that we not take precipitous, premature actions
about supposed concerns that have not yet appeared.
The CHAIRMAN. Thank you.
Now, both I, in my question, and you in your answer, have made
reference to international matters, and, of course, anything we say
about anything always ought to have that footnote and caveat in it.
I notice that as of now, for instance, the U.S. dollar in international
exchange markets is down 1.2 percent against the British pound, 1




65
percent against the Swiss franc, and so on. And the market, as somebody once observed, will continue to fluctuate.
Having said that, however, I would ask you one other question, and
that will be perhaps my last question, and it is this: It is sometimes said
that in our domestic monetary policy we should be governed by the
interest rate structure in this country and in other countries. It is said,
for instance, that if we, to combat a recession, other things being equal,
have a monetary policy which modestly lowers interest rates, that
American money will then fly over to London, Frankfurt, or wherever
it is going, and our international capital accounts and our exchange
position of the dollar will be hurt.
I would ask you whether one doesn't need to be very careful in
handling that thesis, whether it isn't true that, in fact, there are many
things other than interest rate differentials which cause capital to move
about, and whether it isn't true that in the recent past, in the last couple
of years, in the face of quite disparate interest rate structures, shortterm capital has not inevitably moved in a rush toward the higher interest rate; and ask you further whether wouldn't adherence to the
policy of always adjusting our own interest rate structure to what
other central banks may do, may not in the end do more inflationary
and imbalance-of-payments harm than good ?
Thus, in the instance, if we sought to keep here or to lure here capital from London, Frankfurt, Tokyo, or Basel by raising American
interest rates, might we not end up gaining a few bucks on short-term,
bank deposits and Treasury bill purchases, but lose much more by
creating a deep recession which would cause stock prices to fall and
foreigners to dump their equities in Wall Street ?
In short, aren't there so many imponderables that a steady-asyou-go, sensible domestic monetary policy, while always one wants to
take the international situation into account, is really a pretty good
pole star by which to guide ?
Mr. MILLER. Mr. Chairman, in the regime of floating exchange rates,
it seems to me that the currency valuations are affected in the classic
way: currencies go up when there are more buyers than sellers, and
thev go down when there are more sellers than buyers.
Therefore, it seems to me that one must look at why peo'ple buy or
sell currencies. Is it to close a transaction ? Is it to take a position ?
To the extent that we have had some erratic markets, it has been
more position-taking than covering transactions. In that regard, I
think you are correct that interest rates are only one of a series of
complex factors. We have had periods when interest rate differentials
were narrow and the dollar was strong; and we have had periods
when it was wider and the dollar was weak. You have to look at other
conditions at the same time you look at relative interest rates. It is
necessary to look at relative inflation rates.
It is also important to look at the direction of change. Are the trade
accounts going into balance, or is there a greater surplus or a greater
deficit? Our current account deficit, for pxample, has been quite large
in recent years—last year, about $14 billion. The direction'of change
in our current account deficit will brine: us to about half that level this
year and into surplus next vear. So, that change is positive.
All of these factors, I think, have to be taken into account. I believe
it would be a little unwise not to look at the interest rate matters as




66

they relate to the other factors, and particularly to the direction of
change and the expectations of those who deal in currencies. Here
again, their expectation as to our action in dealing with our domestic
economy will be an important factor. If we can do a good job with
our domestic economy in wringing out inflation, the dollar will be
supported.
The CHAIRMAN. Thank you very much. My time is up.
Mr. Stanton?
Mr. STANTON. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. Miller, I don't know whether or not—maybe I misinterpreted—
I don't know if they were your prepared remarks, or your opening
colloquy in regards to the subject of the rate of inflation and your
prediction, but what I thought I heard you say is it was your best
estimate that the rate of inflation would rise at 2 percent this year
and an additional 1 percent next year.
Would you interpret that ? I thought we were at 13 ?
Mr. MILLER. Thank you for catching that, Mr. Stanton. What I
hoped I said was that the oil price shock this year will increase inflation 2 percent more than it would otherwise have been.
If we end up this year with a 10- or 11-percent inflation rate,
that will be 2 percent higher than what it would have been had we
not had this special effect of increased oil prices.
Recall that when I testified in February, the outlook for the year
was roughly a 10-percent increase in world oil prices for the year.
Now we're talking about a 60-percent increase. It will be scaled in,
so that you are talking about a 30- or 40-percent change. This is much,
much higher than what we projected before the recent OPEC action
and before the general shortages that developed.
I was merely pointing out the delta effect. If we had gone on what
we expected in oil pricing last February, we would have X percent
inflation. From what has actually happened, we will have 2 percent
more than X this year from the increases.
Mr. STANTON. I just wanted to be sure on that.
Mr. MILLER. As a matter of fact, while we are doing it, I can just
repeat for the record that the estimate of the Federal Reserve Board
of Governors isan(that, using the implicit price inflator, inflation will
be between 9y2 i H percent this year.
If you subtract the 2 percentage points, then you could say that,
without this oil price shock, inflation would have been between T1/^
and 9 percent.
Mr. STANTON. I think it is at an annual rate now of about 13 percent.
Mr. MILLER. That is the CPI. The implicit deflator tells what is
actually going on in the whole economy, not just the consumer sector.
And, that rate you mention represents the CPI rate of annual change
in the first 4 months, or 5 months.
We are expecting some moderation in factors such as food. And we
are expecting the negative impact of energy. All of this balances out
to a much higher rate than we would have expected.
Mr. STANTON. Do you see any inflationary impact on the President's
propsals on energy ? I was reading last night of a,n estimate cost of $142
billion. Do you expect that the President's program would require in
any way special treatment ?




67

Mr. MILLER. Mr. Stanton, we don't have the details of how this will
be handled, but one would suppose from the President's proposal that
using the excess profits tax funds to pay for the energy development
activities will not add a level of inflationary spending, but will mean a
reallocating of resources. That means other sectors in the economy
will have to grow less in order to provide the funds to finance energy
projects.
If you took the $140 plus billion over 10 years, and assumed that it
was spread evenly and that you could start it up full-blown, you are
talking about six-tenths of a percent of GNP, a figure that I would
think could be handled, if it were financed properly, without excerbating the inflation problem which is already very severe,
Mr. STANTON. Mr. Miller, you are a recognized expert in the private
sector. Would you expect that the excess tax that the President is counting on will be anywhere near the cost of the energy program ?
Mr. MILLER. I would suspect that what might be the ultimate outcome of this program is to use some tax funds to stimulate core projects,
and that there should be a series of incentives that would bring the
private sector into play with its own initiatives and investments that
would supplement this.
If the program works, I would think there would be supplemental
expenditures by the private sector that would finance some of the energy expansion and sources that we need.
I don't believe it should all be left to the Government. Nor do I foresee that these expenditures will be in Government operations entirely.
I see the prospect that a good deal of the President's program will end
up being funded in the private sector, and merely supported, or given
protection by the Government against the technological risks of developing new and untried sources.
Mr. STANTON. Mr. Chairman, my time has expired.
The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Mitchell ?
Mr. MITCHELL. Thank you.
Mr. Chairman, it's almost impossible to convey to you and to the
members of this committee my growing sense of frustration—and
Sometimes I think it is going to turn to fury—over what we have done
to the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act.
It was to be a two-pronged piece of legislation. The original
emphasis was to fight unemployment and the added emphasis was to
fight inflation. We are now pursuing monetary and fiscal policies that
are maintaining black unemployment rates across the board at a level
that is absolutely unconscionable. And apparently we intend to pursue
fiscal and monetary policies which will increase the rate of unemployment, some economists say, to as much as 8 percent. There is no doubt
in my mind that that increase in the rate of unemployment is going to
fall disproportionately on those who have already suffered enough.
There is nothing I can do about it. The course has been charted.
I take this opportunity to express my growing sense of frustration
that a bill which was designed to accomplish two things has been
bastardized to the point that it now emphasizes only one.
That is my feeling. I want to convey it to you and to the members of
this committee, and now I want to raise a question with you—unless
you have some comment to make on my feelings before I ask the
question.




68

Mr. MILLER. Chairman Mitchell, may I make some comment on that,
because I don't think there is anyone who wouldn't agree with you that
the levels of unemployment that we face are, from every point of view,
unacceptable. And it is absolutely correct that the purpose of the Full
Employment and Balanced Growth Act is to achieve full employment
objectives.
The sad, unfortunate reality is, because of external events, that we
cannot control yet as a Nation, we have had a tax imposed upon us; we
have had a withdrawal of resources that gives us the impossible
dilemma. Until we bring together all of our policies, we can neither
achieve the inflation goal or the unemployment goal of the HumphreyHawkins bill within the timetable set by Congress, because of events
outside this Nation.
Therefore, our response must not be despair, but to take every action
to target in and to avoid the hardship to those who will be temporarily
unemployed, and to fight the core causes, including unleashing the
spirit and capacity of this Nation to get itself independent again and
make its own decisions again.
Mr. MITCHELL. I am sympathetic with your position, and I obviously
can't speak for all blacks or any other minorities in this country. My
bone of contention is that, even prior to the time that this new crisis
emerged because of the latent OPEC price increase, little or nothing
had been done to reduce minority unemployment. And that is a fact.
That is my concern, and I am afraid that that failure to act is being
justified by this new energy crisis. And when the energy crisis diminishes I am not at all certain that we will address the problem of minority unemployment.
Mr. MILLER. I don't think it is justifiable under any circumstances.
And I believe that the energy actions in 1973 and 1974, together
with the actions this year ended up in a 1,000 percent increase in the
price of oil, have laid an enormous burden on us.
Some of the policies, followed in the past have not been up to the
task. And I think the only real thing this Nation can do is to renew
and expand its commitment to shelter from harm the people you are
talking about—those who are disadvantaged, black or white.
Mr. MITCHELL. May I interrupt, because I am afraid my time is
going to end.
Mr. MILLER. Excuse me. I may be getting off the subject.
Mr. MITCHELL. I want to get back on the subject, too. But before I
do, I want to say that I think everyone is willing to make a sacrifice.
God knows, I am, and my constituents are. But the unfair part about
this is the sacrifice that is now being imposed comes on top of a prior
sacrifice demanded of minorities because the Government did not reduce unemployment in any significant fashion for minorities after the
original OPEC price increases.
Now may I raise my question, please. You have allowed the Mt money
supply growth as part of your policy of getting to a course that you
are sroing to pursue no matter what happens.
My concern is with the sharp rate of deceleration of M± adjusted for
ATS accounts that has already taken place this year. The staff on the
Domestic Monetary Policy Subcommittee has designed a chart, which
I will share with you. That chart makes it very clear to me that each




69

time we have decelerated Mi growth sharply, even adjusted for ATS
accounts, that quickly we have set the stage for another recession. It
is graphically clear. And my specific question is: Did not the most
recent sharp deceleration—beginning last October—contribute to the
recession that we are now in ? And if we continue to reduce Mi growth,
will this not prolong the recession that is now just beginning ?
Mr. MILLER. Mr. Mitchell, I am looking at the chart you have just
mentioned. It is the first time I have seen it, but it is similar to ones
I have seen before.
Mr. MITCHELL. That is a part of a study we have shared with you
before—it was a part of a study done by my Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy.
Mr. MILLER. You have got a dotted line here, which is apparently
adjusting Mx for ATS.
Mr. MITCHELL. That is correct.
Mr. MILLER. What you will see from that, I think, is that, on an
adjusted basis, the Federal Reserve was charting a course which
would be restraining but would be above the level that would trigger
a recession. It was my judgment, and still is my judgment, that the
monetary restraint factor would not have brought us into a recession.
The additional impact and drain-off of purchasing power by this
large oil increase has brought on the recession, in my opinion. Our
whole course of action in monetary policy has been to apply this restraint to dampen inflationary pressures, to control growth but not to
eliminate it, and to avoid a recession.
I believe we would have succeeded but for this event that we could
not control.
Mr. MITCHELL. My time has expired; however, I want to indicate
that the chart of MI growth is adjusted for ATS accounts.
The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Wylie?
Mr. WYLIE, Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
On page 55 of your statement, you say:
The Nation's ability to avoid an escalation of inflation over the next year or
so without serious recession will depend to a degree on whether a means is
found to overcome the tendency for workers and businesses to seek higher
wages and prices to offset the effects of the income transfer associated with the
rise in oil prices.

Mr. NEAL. We can't hear you, Mr. Wylie.
Mr. WYLIE, If we stop the rise in wages and prices in the United
States, is there any reason to believe that OPEC would stop increasing
their tax on Americans through the rise in price of crude oil?
Do you understand the thrust of my question ?
Mr. MILLER. Yes, Mr. Wylie. We have, I think, several answers, but
I think the realistic answer is that the ability and willingness of
Americans to recognize the peril to their Nation from this danger of
inflation and make personal sacrifices and forego some real income
for a period of time in order to gain more real income in the future,
that recognition, that reaction against the peril cannot guarantee us
that those who control the sources outside our borders will adjust
their behavior.
The only way we can bring about an adjustment of their behavior
is to reduce our dependence upon their product. And as soon as we




70

have less demand for what they sell, that is when they will stop
raising the prices; that is when they will start lowering their prices.
Therefore, there is nothing more urgent for this Nation than to find
a way, through a combination of policies so that we don't ride just
one horse, to reduce our dependence upon petroleum as a fuel and to
reduce our dependence upon imported petroleum as fast as we can.
Mr. WYLIE. Well, I couldn't agree with you more, and I agreed with
the President the other night in his emphasis on the need to reduce our
dependence on OPEC oil.
There are probably going to be secondary or ripple effects from the
OPEC price increases. I think that if inflation is increased as it has
been, and as you say it has been, because of our dependence upon
OPEC oil and the fact that they are raising their prices, then the
prices in the United States for other commodities are necessarily
going to rise, and wages are going to rise as well.
On page 21 of your statement you have a chart which indicates the
rise in the average official sales price of OPEC crude oil. Have you
made any estimates on what might happen as far as the OPEC crude
oil prices are concerned in the next 12 to 18 months?
And I think that is important in a prognosis as far as monetary
policy is concerned and what happens as far as inflation is concerned.
Mr. MILLER. Yes; we have assumed not that we will just plateau
at this number, but that we will have an OPEC price increase to
roughly $21 a barrel in mid-1979 and an increase of about $2 a barrel
additionally through 1980 on the average. That is what we have assumed. We have assumed a 60-percent increase that will be a bit stable
for a while—just as the large increase in 1974 was for a while—but
that then we are going to have a drift upward.
That of course is, at this moment, an assumption. If we should move
more rapidly to reduce our dependence on imported oil, that might
change. If we move more slowly or other events take place in the
world—some interruption of oil supply, another revolution somewhere—then we could have a worse outcome.
So we are merely, at this moment, basing it on more or less the
expectation and outlook based on experience.
Mr. WYLIE. Thank you.
You have a committee staff report in front of you there now, I think:
Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy. I think it was just supplied to you.
[The report referred to may be found in the appendix.]
Mr. MILLER. Yes.
Mr. WYLIE. Would you please refer to a chart, exhibit 4 it is called.
Mr. MILLER. Which chart ?
Mr. WYLIE, Chart 4A.
Mr. MILLER. Yes.
Mr. WYLIE. You will notice there it says "year-to-year percentage
change inflation as reflected by M V1
The lower chart includes in M repurchase agreements and Fed
funds. It seems to give a more accurate appraisal of the situation as
far as inflation is concerned than the upper chart. I wondered if you
could comment as to the amount of inflation which might be attributed




71
to money growth. Is it more pronounced, or does it show up more if
repos and Fed funds are included in the money supply? And why
shouldn't we include them in Reserve requirements?
I think that you have that specific issue out for comment right now,
and you might also at the same time indicate what the comment has
been. It is appropriate, since we are talking about a Federal Reserve
membership tomorrow.
Mr. MILLER. This is a very pertinent and important subject. There
are several comments I would like to make.
One is, of course, that the very process of financial development of
institutions, in terms of the new experience with inflation, has resulted in an incentive to create and innovate and find new techniques
to economize on the source of money, and therefore to avoid the Reserve
requirements.
We have seen this in terms of the development of such things as the
repurchase agreement markets that you mentioned and a lot of other
techniques.
At the same time, we have seen nonbank financial institutions also
become active in a different way as to the nature of their deposits.
It is for this reason that we have looked upon monetary improvement and H.R. 7 not only as a need to have a legal structure, but also
to make the decisions about redefining the aggregates we are tracking so that we relate to the realities of today and not to the conditions
of the! 1960's or the 1950's.
So, as you know, we have a project underway throughout this year to
look at the definition of all the monetary aggregates, to have inputs
from all those who are interested, to have experts from all walks of
life comment. From this we hope to synthesize a proposal this fall,
which we will then put out for further comment, so that by the first
of the year we can have more perfect aggregate definitions that are
related to the function of money and deposits more than to where they
exist.
We don't know what those decisions will be. We have had two important seminars with outside economists and experts and congressional staff participating, and we're hoping that all of this process
will help us address the kind of problem you are bringing to our
attention.
Mr. WYLIE. Thank you very much. My time has expired.
The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Neal.
Mr. NEAL. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Miller, I am delighted
to see you here. Just to follow up on the point made by Mr. Wylie,
if I am reading his chart correctly and your report, on page 21, there
was only a relatively slight increase in the price of oil between early
1974 and early 1979; and yet prices increased over 50 percent during
that same period of time.
My point is, if this chart is right, and I am reading it correctly, I
just don't think that we can blame recent increases in the rate of
inflation entirely on oil prices.
Mr. MILLER. May I just comment on that particular point?
Mr. NEAL. Yes, sir.
Mr. MILLER. As you will recall, there were, in 1973 and 1974, even
higher inflation rates than we are experiencing today as a result of this




72

same kind of oil shock. And you will recall that one of the consequences, for whatever reason, including policy actions, was that we
had a severe recession, the most severe recession we have had since
the Great Depression. And in that process, we did wring out some
inflation, bringing it down to about a 6-percent level entering that
period. Because of this worldwide recession, the demand for oil
dropped and the capacity of OPEC to put in price increases abated.
So we went througn a period of low activity, high unemployment—
9 percent unemployment—and we got inflation down somewhat. But
we didn't address the fundamental policies adequately, and we came
back on a reflation program. JN'ow we have seen ourselves in a condition
with a high demand lor oil; we have not curtailed our appetite. The
result is we are once again exposed to this market action of tight
supplies and a cartel supplier who can impose price increases upon
us.
Once again, whatever may have been the natural cycle as a result
of the retlation, we have added another layer on top of that, just as
we did in 1974.
Mr. INEAL. I couldn't argue with that. I did want to point out,
though, that we did have accelerating inflation in 1977 and 1978.
Mr. MILLER. That is absolutely correct.
Mr. NEAL. And no very large increase in the price of oil. So I am
just trying to point out that in my own opinion, we cannot blame that
inflation on the price of oil."
Mr. MILLER. May I speak to this again ?
The effect of the recent change in me price of oil is not to bring about
the 8 percent inflation that we were experiencing, but to add 2 percent
on top of that. We can't blame that for the 8 percent.
Mr. NEAL. Well, if I may, I want to get to two questions. It is my
understanding of the way our economy works, that if the Federal
Reserve creates money at a rate faster than the economy is growing,
that is inflationary. And we can try to quantify that. We have tried
before, and I think it is about 60 percent of the rate of inflation measured year to year, but that is really not important. It is just sort of a
basic statement that, in fact, if money growth exceeds the rate of
growth in the economy, that is inflationary.
In March of this year, the House Banking Committee passed a resolution, with only one dissenting voice, and that report called for a
rate of growth in the money supply of about 6 percent for this year, 5
percent for the next year, 4 percent for the next year, 3 percent for
the next year, and then to be essentially left at about 3 percent. And my
questions are these:
No. 1: Do you agree with this general understanding I have of the
way our economy works ? And No. 2, if you do agree, why wouldn't it
be a good idea to follow this sort of steady, moderate reduction in the
rate of growth of the money supply instead of the rather erratic
pattern that we have gone through recently ?
Mr. MILLER. Mr. Neal, may I call your attention to the charts starting
on page 44.
Mr. NEAL. What page ?
Mr. MILLER. Page 44. Before we look at them, I just want to try to
make one distinction. Perhaps I will oversimplify in order to make the
distinction, but I will try it.




73

Let's divide inflation into monetary inflation and other inflation.
I_don't think the OPEC price increase was brought about by the change
of money supply. Once you take that out and look at monetary inflation, then we certainly agree, and it has been our posture to fight
inflation by bringing down the rate of growth in money and credit over
time, thus wringing out the inflationary pressures while doing the
least damage to the overall economy.
On page 44, you will see, in the bottom panel, that in the recession
of 1974-75, money was growing at a low rate. It picked up, as the
economy recovered, to a 7.9 percent in 1977.
My first testimony before this House committee was on March 9,
1978. We said then we needed to bring down the rate of growth in
money. Let's look at the record. The record is 7.9 percent in 1977; 7.2
percent in 1978; and so far this year, on an adjusted basis, less than
6 percent.
If you look at M2, which does not have the ATS problem, you
will see for 1976, 10.9 percent; 1977, 9.8 percent; 1978, 8.4 percent,
and this year so far, 6 percent. Our effort is going to be to continue
that process, with some adjustment for things like OPEC that we can't
deal with through monetary action alone, until we win this "war."
Mr. NEAL. Well, I quite agree with what you are doing, and I am
personally very happy to see that it is just under 6 percent. My question, though, was: Why go from 8% percent to 4 percent, in a very
short period of time, and then back up to some higher percent, between
6 and 7, to arrive at that rate of growth of about 6 percent? Why not
just go slow and easy?
Mr. MILLER. You may be getting on a touchy point. I have decided
the best policy for me, is to have no memory of monetary policy
before March 8, 1978.
•Mr. NEAL. Let's see. I believe it was—in March of 1979 that the
Banking Committee
Mr. MILLER. In March 1979,1 year after I joined the Fed, the growth
rate of the monetary aggregates was slower. Even the staff is nodding.
Mr. NEAL. Mr. Miller, I have the greatest respect for you, I know
you have a difficult job, and I think you are an outstanding individual.
Let me just ask this, though: Would you agree that if we would follow
the course of moderate, slow decline in the rate of growth of the
money supply over several years, until it reaches about 3 percent, that
that would be a big help in our war against both inflation and
recession ?
Mr. MILLER. I agree completely. And let me just restate what I hope
this report says, namely: that we set these ranges at the beginning of
the year for M1? M2, and M 3 ; we have been living within them after
the original downward adjustment, because of the restraint we took
last year; we have kept within the ranges; and those ranges contemplate the slow growth that you talk about. Tentatively, we have set
the same ranges for next year, but there are so many uncertainties
right now we don't know.
But that continues to allow us room to accomplish what you were
saying, Mr. Neal, and I think your general philosophy is exactly the
same as ours. I don't want to be defensive and I don't want to look
back at past policies and be critical. All I can say is, our effort is to




accomplish just what you are talking about; to try to do it year after
year, without wrenching the economy; and to change back to more
of the market system in the process. You must remember that you have
to look at all of this against a background that not long ago adjusted
economy activity not by monetary restraint, but by closing the window
on credit in housing.
From 1966, in every cycle we have shut down the window on housing; that left everybody off the hook on the monetary aggregates,
because you could just shut down an important part of the economy.
In 1972, fourth quarter housing was at an annual rate of 2% million
starts. At the end of 1974, 8 quarters later, it was at a rate of 90,000.
Financing was not available.
Mr. NEAL. I am very much aware of what happened. I just hope we
don't do that again. That is my concern.
Mr. MILLER. We are trying to get back to a market decision. Don't
shut the window; put in the restraint on money and credit and let
monetary policy work uninhibited within a market economy. In such a
case, I think we will accomplish what you want, and we will be more
perfect in our own performance.
Mr. NEAL. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. We will recess the committee
for a few minutes to record our votes.
[Brief recess.]
The CHAIRMAN. The Chair will recognize Mr. Evans.
Mr. EVANS of Delaware. Mr. Miller, in a recent regulatory interpretation, the Fed reversed itself to allow small savers to pool their
funds in order to obtain money market certificate rates of return on
their deposits that would be higher than what they might ordinarily
receive. But member banks were prohibited from soliciting pooled deposits or from soliciting deposits on the basis that they would be pooled
by the bank.
I wrote you requesting an end to this ban on soliciting pooled funds.
You advised me that the lifting of the ban on soliciting pooled funds
would have an adverse effect on the administration of the deposit
interest rate ceiling structure.
I recognize that you may have a problem from that standpoint, but
I also have some great concern, Mr. Miller in light of the first amendment provisions, as to whether or not the Fed can legally prohibit
member banks from advertising this type of pooling provision.
And my caveat would be: I understand your problem, but I think
there is a concern from a constitutional standpoint.
Mr. MILLER. I am not a constitutional authority, but let me describe
to you what I think is the common interest we share. We all need to
return to a market system where the rates paid to small savers would
be competitive, and small savers would be entitled to the kind of
market rates that are available to others.
Our problem is that we have built a number of major institutions,
intermediary financial institutions, whose portfolios are now locked
in to long-term mortgages. I am talking about thrift institutions.
And the possibility of adjusting upward their average portfolio yield
is a very slow process. If they suddenly were required to pay full current market rates on what have been ceiling regulated over the years
they would all be in a loss position and we would threaten the finan-




75

cial viability of very important institutions. So we have to balance
the strong equity demand of small savers against the practicality and
the essential need of this society for financial intermediaries.
The money market certificates were issued as a means of turning
back to the marketplace, as much as we could, without triggering that
economic problem for the thrifts, and the ceiling rate was set at
$10,000 to be the same as the ceiling rate for an individual buying a
Treasury bill.
Suppose an institution says "We now have $10,000 certificates, but
we will hold them here and give you pieces of them for $100". Then
small savers would take all their money to the institutions that did
that, which means you would destroy money for housing or you would
bankrupt the institutions who have to raise interest rates to hold their
funds. We have to weigh that problem against the problem of equity
and try to pursue the phasing out of regulation Q ceilings over a time
that allows adjustment, as is being proposed to the Congress.
Now, on the question of "Why, then, do we permit funds to be
pooled at all," the answer is simple. I don't know how to enforce a
regulation that prevents you or your neighbors or your children from
putting your name on an account, buying a certificate, and agreeing
that you will divide it up among you. I think to put in a regulation
unenforceable against individuals merely creates a public attitude
of disrespect for law. They won't abide by it; therefore, they disrespect
it.
So we recognize the practicalities; you really can not enforce that
law upon individuals; you can't find a way to do it. It would take an
enormous number of investigators, and it just isn't worth it.
This is a nationally important problem. We have to go through an
adjustment process, and no one institution should try to take advantage of this and defeat the very purpose of the ceiling by breaking
down this whole structure.
While I am not really aware of it, it seems to me that to allow institutions to imply that "if you come in, we will act through subterfuge to violate the law," is carrying the concept of freedom of speech
too far.
Mr. EVANS of Delaware. I am not too sure, Mr. Miller, that there is
any subterfuge if you do act in the open.
Mr. MILLER. The other choice, Congressman Evans, would be to
prohibit all pooling, which I guess we would have to do to avoid
the other extreme consequences. This includes prohibiting pooling by
individuals, in which case we would have a lot of people violating the
law.
Mr. EVANS of Delaware. I understand your dilemma. Mr. Chairman,
if I may, just a couple of very quick questions in the interest of time,
and the fact that we are here under the lights.
I listened to the gentleman from Maryland, Mr. Mitchell, speak
of the unemployment problem that is attendant with a mild recession,
or a mild depression, as well as the types of restraints that are necessary to combat inflation, which hurts everyone and I agree that
inflation hurts the poor the most.
But I go back to a question that you answered several months ago,
and that was: Isn't it a good idea to roll back the minimum wage as it




70

relates to teenagers, because the teenage unemployment problem in
this country is so great ? Wouldn't that have the effect of giving more
teenagers jobs? And wouldn't a job be better than no job at all, particularly in view of the fact that if you get the first job, you can go
on to a second, and so on ?
Mr. MILLER. You are absolutely correct. One of the greatest problems in developing more employment opportunities for all Americans
is the transition from youth to adult, transition from preparation
for work to work; that transition is very difficult.
When you start with many who, for whatever reasons and whatever
disadvantages, aren't well prepared and aren't skilled, the process of
learning a skill and learning the world of work is extremely important to their long-term well-being. Anything that would allow them
to make that step, we ought to encourage, including a youth differential, or elimination of the social security tax on young people for
a certain period of time.
Any of those kinds of methods that would get them into jobs, and
get them experience with work, with learning skills, learning and
moving on, as they always do, to better jobs, would be very important
for society; I would highly support it.
Mr. EVANS of Delaware. I thank you very much. One more question,
Mr. Miller. It seems to me that we have had a rather precipitous decline
in savings in America, particularly in light of the savings in the developed nations of the world; we probably have the lowest rate of capital
formation of any of the industrialized nations of the world.
Would you be in favor of some type of legislation that would exempt
from taxation a portion of interest gained on savings ?
Mr. MILLER. Your general premise is one of a high order of importance; that is, that we have a problem of capital formation and
we have a problem of investment. I have not yet brought myself to
believe that the preferred action, of all the possible choices of using
tax dollars, would be to shelter savings. My reasoning goes something
like this: those who need to be encouraged to save, those who have
small savings and don't have the opportunity to find high yields or
tax shelters, are those who have the lowest income tax rates; so tax
relief has the least value to those who are most needy. To those who are
in the highest income tax brackets, such relief as you speak of has
greatest value.
Therefore, my preference—I am not saying that yours isn't a
worthwhile idea—but my preference would be for more direct action,
using whatever tax dollars we can allocate for the purpose to liberalize depreciation. This relates tax expenditures directly to the capital
investments we so badly need to get productivity and technology
gains.
Mr. EVANS of Delaware. You still feel, Mr. Miller, that we need to
accelerate depreciation, and that it would be a substantial effort?
Mr. MILLER. I don't reject others. I just think it is the most effective.
Mr. EVANS of Delaware. Thank you.
The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Blanchard ?
Mr. BLANCHARD. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and welcome, Mr.
Miller. There are some economists, I think, even within the administration, that believe that we are on the verge of a more serious recession
than we had in 1975.1 take it you would reject that kind of prediction?




77

Mr. MILLER. I don't see the case for it. One of the fundamental
policies we have been pursuing, one of the fundamental objectives
of monetary policy and other economic policies, is to bring about restraint in the economy, to wring out inflation while maintaining
balance within the economy. Serious recessions usually will have to
be triggered by some sort of imbalance.
Now let's look at the economy today. Consumer spending is being
retarded, both by the drain-off of income to higher prices of energy
which leaves less money for other purchases, and by psychological
concern about whether gasoline will be available and whether certain activities should be engaged in. But consumer spending isn't being destroyed; it still has a solid base.
If you look at business spending, you will find a slight increase in
capital expenditures. There is nothing in the outlook that would cause
businesses to fly from new investment in the capacity modernizations,
and cost reductions they need.
One of the most volatile parts of the economy is usually the inventory sector. There, we have an extremely good position of stocks
even though, as sales fall, the ratio between inventory and sales will
climb up a bit. But inventories are very clean in relation to past experience, and you don't have that imbalance.
Government spending isn't showing major signs in one direction
or another that would bring about this deceleration. If you look at
housing, we are expecting a moderate decline, but nothing like the
60-percent decline we saw in 1973-74.
So I think, if you look at each of the components of the economy
and the overall picture, you don't find a case for a serious recession.
Mr. BLANCHARD. That is good to hear. You hear beginnings of a
notion that Congress might well, next year, want to enact some form of
tax cut or tax change to lessen the effect of a recession everyone is
talking about. I think that may be based on the assumption that the
Fed will not do anything different than it has done before.
I have several questions. One: Given the fact that OPEC has inflicted upon us what you estimate to be perhaps 2 percent additional
inflation, what is the Fed doing in response to that? I am not sure
I read your testimony clearly.
And two: If that helps not only fan inflation but perhaps induce a
recession, or guarantee it, do vou think it would be wise for Congress
to respond on the fiscal side ? Or is there something you are going to do
through the monetary policy approach to help fight a recession ?
And finally, I would like to know what your feeling is on real wage
insurance. I notice you indicate we need to continue to work on the
price/wage problem. Congress dropped the ball on that proposal. I
thought it was a good one. I am wondering how you feel about that.
Mr. MILLER. Let me take the first question, if I may. One of the
things we must resist is the temptation to finance the oil price increase
and thereby merely add more inflation in order to maintain final demand. The purchasing power that is pulled away from other goods
and services because of the oil price increase, if put back into the economy to generate the same demand, is going to produce even more
inflation. The hard reality of the situation is that the Federal Reserve
should maintain firmness and continue to be diligent in its effort to
maintain the growth of the monetary aggregates within the ranges




78'

that have been established and not be tempted, prematurely, to finance
this sort of increase.
That means that the difference comes out of real growth; that is
why we get a recession instead of just having a slowdown; that is
what all of us in the country have to pay because of this event.
Now, what happens in the future? I agree with Chairman Reuss
that we should not be panicked into precipitous action. We should be
prepared to see this adjustment, unpleasant as it is, and get ourselves
back on the track for the renewed growth within sustainable levels
that we have been attempting. That is, of course, what we see; we see
a moderate recession running through this year and early next year
from which, without tax cuts, we will be able to begin to grow back.
We should hold our decision on that and keep a watch. There will
be a time when we may want to make tax adjustments, because inflation rates do drive people's incomes into higher tax brackets and do
represent an additional drag. When we make that adjustment, I hope
we will concentrate on those kinds of tax cuts for individuals—such
as a reduction in payroll taxes, which directly affect prices, provided
we can take action which will keep social security funding sound—
that not only give them appropriate relief, but also help us fight
inflation.
I also hope we will take a look at tax consideration^ we have just
discussed that would help us with our capital formation and investment. Therefore, I would hope that we would look at individual
payroll taxes and accelerated depreciation for businesses. The combination of helping individuals with payroll taxcuts and helping
businesses with incentives for investment that will get us the productivity and technological improvements we need, would both be
the anti-inflation kinds of actions we need.
Mr. BLANCHARD. What do you think about the real wage insurance
proposal ?
Mr. MILLER. I think the idea of a self-operating system that uses
the tax structure has a great deal of appeal. It is very attractive.
So far, Congress has been examining it but has not been convinced
that the mechanics work. Because of Congress view of it, I have
tended to think of other kinds of tax reductions, and IVe tended to
move my thinking toward these two that I have just mentioned.
I have given preference to these others over trying to solve the problems that Congress has had with the TIP-type tax.
The CHAIRMAN. The gentleman's time has expired.
Mr. Cavanaugh ?
Mr. CAVANAUGH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. Miller, first of all, I would like to commend you for this report^
I think it is the finest that IVe seen, the most explicit and comprehensive since I have been a member of this committee, and the first
one from my perspective that actually complies with the aspirations
of the committee and the Congress in the passage of HumphreyHawkins, and I thank you for that.
I particularly commend you for including, as jrou do on page 48,
a consensus of the Board of all of the economic indicators that led
to the monetary aggregates that you have presented us with here
today. I think that that is a goaf that this committee has had and
that the Congress and indeed the country has had, to have some sort




79

of a broader understanding of the goals and aspirations of the Federal Eeserve in setting their monetary targets.
I think that at long last we have finally arrived at that, and I think
it is beneficial. The picture that you paint is an excessively gloomy one,
I think, not excessively in terms of reality, but extremely depressing,
at any rate.
First of all, I would like to ask a little bit about tax cuts. Last week
Lyle Gramley of the Council of Economic Advisers recommended
cutting corporate income taxes and allowing writeoff for plants and
equipment and raising the investment tax credit as the best way to
regain productivity. If the administration decides that a tax cut is
necessary to combat a recession, would you favor placing emphasis on
these kinds of cuts, on payroll taxes or on general income taxes?
Mr. MILLER. For the business side, for investment incentives, Mr.
Cavanaugh, I would favor the accelerated depreciation. Very quickly,
my view is that if you ask business what they would prefer, they would
prefer a general corporate tax cut. But the trouble with that from the
point of view of our national policy right now is that it would not
guarantee any particular reaction.
A tax cut could merely improve cash flow. It could increase dividends. It could increase cash in the bank for the corporation. But it
wouldn't necessarily go into the kind of spending and modernization
that we need.
An investment tax credit is an approach that is directly related to
investment and therefore is a direct incentive or an offset to the risk of
investment. But because it is a forever forgiveness of tax, and because
the tax reduction all happens in the first year, it is expensive from the
Treasury's point of view.
Accelerated depreciation, on the other hand, does make the formula
for calculation of discounted cash flow, which a corporation uses to
decide the risk of its investment, more attractive. From the Treasury's
point of view, it does not forgive the tax; it merely defers it. And it
doe's spread it. So it gives a bigger bang for the buck from the Treasury
point of view. It is what I prefer.
As to individual cuts, I think I would prefer something along the
lines of the payroll tax reductions we just mentioned. I would think
that the thing to do is to keep the retirement features of social security
actuarially sound and funded with contributions. But such things as
medical benefits under the social security umbrella—which is not a
question of putting money aside now to pay a pension 30 years from
now; they are current expenses for current illnesses—these might be
funded by general revenues to allow us to take pressure off the direct
payroll revenues.
That is the kind of approach that might be worth looking at.
Mr. CAVANAUGH. I agree with you particularly on the social security
area.
In terms of your economic projections, you are projecting, and the
consensus view of the Board of Governors seems to be, that we are
entering, and will be experiencing, a worse recession than the 1978-74
' period. Your real GNP projections are minus two to minus one-half for
1979 and minus one-half to plus two for 1980. In 1973-74, the GNP
was minus 1.4 in 1973 and minus 1.4 in 1974 and 1.3 in 1975.




80

Are we in fact embarked upon a worse recession than the 1974r75 recession ?
Mr. MILLER. Mr. Cavanaugh, let me get you the correct figures. I
believe we have some discrepancy in our figures. The recession we are
now looking at is considerably milder.
Mr. CAVANAUGH. I am on page 48 of your report.
Mr. MILLER. Look at the fourth quarter to fourth quarter on page
50; it is very important. This is the line of real GNP growth, including our range. If you look in the little inset you will see the actual figures; you will see that, fourth quarter 1973 to fourth quarter 1974,
there was a minus 3.5 percent real growth. In 1979 we are expecting
somewhere between a minus two and a minus one-half. Even if you took
the most pessimistic view, you can see how much milder the dip would
be.
There may be some discrepancy that I am not familiar with.
Mr. CAVANAUGH. The 1974-75 figures I was citing were from the economic indicators, June 1979, prepared for the Joint Economic Committee by the Council of Economic Advisers.
Mr. MILLER. The difference is looking at figures year over year or
fourth quarter over fourth quarter. The difference, Mr. Cavanaugh,
is between fourth quarter-fourth quarter and average for the year.
If you look at our figures on the average basis, it would be even less negative.
Mr. CAVANAUGH. I understand the difference. So you are not
then
Mr. MILLER. We are looking at a milder situation. I hope that chart
on page 50 shows graphically the kind of drop-down and trend toward
recovery that is quite different in its characteristics from the one in
1973-75.
The CHAIRMAN. The time of the gentleman has expired.
The Chair will now recognize Mr. Kelly and ask him if he will preside for the 5 minutes of his questioning and then recess briefly, by
which time I hope that Ms. Oakar and Mr. Leach and others would
have returned, so we won't have to impose upon Mr. Miller much
longer.
Mr. KELLY [presiding]. Mr. Chairman, for the first time, the country is now in good hands. [Laughter.]
Mr. MILLER. You better change the nameplates. It won't look good
on television.
Mr. KELLY. Well, it may help my social standing. [Laughter.]
I would like to inquire of you, what kind of impact do you believe
the OPEC increases have had during the portion of 1979 that has expired? What percentage or what portion of the inflation would you
attribute to OPEC 2
Mr. MILLER. Mr. Kelly, we are expecting that the oil price increase
in 1979 will contribute 2 percent to the implicit price deflator, which
we expect to be in a range of 9i/£ to 11 percent. Our staff points out to
me that about a third of this has already impacted us. So I would, say
we have already received probably seven-tenths of a percent more inflation from that factor.
Early in the year, of course, the very high levels of inflation were
mainly caused by two things. One is food, where the very high in-




81
creases have now dropped off. In the first quarter, food was more of a
factor than energy. But energy was the second very big factor.
Now the biggest factor is energy, and it will increasingly be energy.
Mr. KELLY. Here is my question. It would be just a little bit less than
intellectually honest to say that inflation has been caused by OPEC ?
Mr. MILLER. It would be improper to say inflation has been caused
by OPEC. It would be proper to say that the already severe inflation
we had for the year has moved to a new plateau, about 2 percent
higher, as a result of OPEC.
Mr. KELLY. Now, there is another influence in the economy that I
would like to ask you about. Do we have a food shortage in the United
States, as far as you know ?
Mr. MILLER. There is not. There are certain kinds of food that are
in short supply.
Mr. KELLY. Wheat, corn?
Mr. MILLER. No; there is a decreasing supply of beef, and that has
resulted in very high beef prices.
Mr. KELLY. But as far as the subsidized commodities, the feed grains
and cereal grains, there is no shortage of those ?
Mr. MILLER. No. There is, however, pressure upon those commodities
right now because of some worldwide tightness in supply.
Mr. KELLY. But that is something that has developed very recently.
Mr. MILLER. Very recently.
Mr. KELLY. I wonder if you have any thoughts on why it is beneficial, when we have an overabundance of a commodity, for the Government to use the taxpayers' money to stimulate the production on the
one hand, and then to have a reserve program where we are encouraging the farmers not to produce, so that at the same time we are encouraging them to produce more and encouraging them not to produce quite so much. And then we move to a commodity such as energy,
oil, and we are discussing now that we are going to add a new tax on
the production of oil, that is, the companies that produce oil will be
taxed more when we are in short supply of domestic production.
Is there some symmetry to that in economics ? Or would it be better
to reverse that and stop the stimulation of farm production and start
stimulating the production of domestic oil ?
Mr. MILLER. I think there are always analogies that can be drawn.
We ought to be careful, however, in drawing an analogy between
agricultural products which depend upon soil, weather, all kinds of
other factors, and energy, which exists in the ground. Because of the
cyclical nature of agricultural products, there is, I think, a wisdom
to our policy: We have learned from biblical admonitions that we
should set aside our grain stores in good harvest times because there
will be famine times.
I think the idea of reserves in products that depend upon weather
and climate is quite different from the question of whether we should
build reserves in energy. I don't mean to duck your question, because
there are certainly reasons why we should use every market incentive
we can to help create conditions where we will search for, find, develop, and produce, more indigenous sources of energy.
Mr. KELLY. I have run out of time. I have to go vote. And I am
going to relinquish the chair to my colleague from New York.




82
Mr. GREEN [presiding], I would like to return to the question that
Chairman Keuss mentioned during his opening remarks, relating to
the statement on page 41 of your report that the impact of the ATS
and NOW accounts on Mx expansion has been smaller to date than
expected but that the FOMC is retaining its original range for ML
Does this mean in essence that the FOMC has somewhat tightened
up its target for MI ?
Mr. MILLER. Mr. Green, our intention is to maintain the same posture. Let me try to explain using the chart on page 44; we may have
to refer a little more to M2 this time to avoid confusion. Those red
lines on the top panel on page 44 represent—using the "old" basis
of M! unadjusted for ATS—4fy 2 to 7y2 percent growth. Our growth
targets would be brought down toward 6 percent on average unadjusted for ATS. If you adjust for ATS—assuming 3 percent ATS
effect—our midpoint is 3 percent. If we only have iy2 percent ATS
effect, then this chart could show a 4^/2 percent midpoint and still be
within the range for monetary control purposes.
We only ask you to bear in mind that we are within the range when
you look at our performance this year. We won't know until the end
of the year what the final impact of ATS is.
Mr. GREEN. If you were originally allowing 3 percent ATS effect
and there has only been
iy2 percent ATS effect, then this range, instead of being a 4i/2-71/2 range is really a 3-6 range.
Mr. MILLER. To date the ATS impact has actually been 2^4, so, therefore, you could look at this figure as being 4; it seemed to us better
not to confuse you. This is a difficult problem, which I apologize for
this year, caused by that technical change. Perhaps we should
have
shown it differently. Perhaps we should have shown 41/2 and 71/£, and
then made a "phantom" change of the figures using the old basis.
But we started off on this path and we thought it best not to shift
on you in midstream.
Mr. GREEN. In other words, you are saying it is three-quarters of 1
percent off ?
Mr. MILLER. At the moment. We don't know what will happen for
the rest of the year.
Mr. GREEN. Let me turn to this committee's report. After the February hearings, my understanding is that this committee recommended
that the Fed plan on dropping its targeted rate on monetary growth
slightly each year, and specifically on dropping the midpoint of the
M! range by 1 percentage point. Yet I gather from your report that
tentatively you do not plan to drop your ranges next year, but instead
plan to keep them the same as this year.
Mr. MILLER. I would like to clarify that. If you look on page 44, at
the bottom panel, you will see that in 1977 the fourth-quarter-tofourth-quarter change in M t was 7.9 percent. We brought it down in
1978 to 7.2 percent. And if you look at today's figures, it would be
less than 6 percent on a comparable basis.
Our ranges for next year have not been changed, because things are
so uncertain. Our policy posture is one of continuing on that gradual
decline. But we are not able at this point to identify just how that can
be accomplished until we see the working through of the recent economic shocks in our economy.




83

If you look on page 45, you see the same sort of change in M2 in the
bottom panel; going from 10.9 percent in 1976, to 9.8 percent in 1977,
to 8.4 percent in 1978, and so far this year to only about 6 percent.
So we are accomplishing, in this broader (aggregate, quite a sharp
reduction over a number of years. This is the third year of reduction.
Our hope is that we will be able to come back to you in February and
tell you that we are still on that kind of a path. What degree and how
far, we're not quite sure.
Mr. GREEN. I guess what troubles me is that the Humphrey-Hawkins
legislation did call for setting the next year's targets at this time, and
the report as rather vague on that. And your testimony now emphasizes
the tentativeness with which you are talking about next year's numbers.
Mr. MILLER. Yes. In different times perhaps we could be more precise.
But the last 6 weeks have brought on such interesting changes, and the
President's initiatives have not been quantified yet, and our own redefinition of the aggregates is waiting this year. It is one of those times
when, to be honest with you, we must tell you that we don't want to see
any change in the long range objective as you have' suggested and we
agree with. But we are not able to quantify it at this stage, because of
these events. We might, from time to time in the future, have additional
midyear problems.
I hope next year, at midyear, that we will be able to come to you with
a more precise outlook for 1981 and give you something a little more
concrete. We are extending the same bands, which means we have room
to accomplish the target you have in mind.
Mr. GREEN. Let me turn to another subject which concerns me, and
that's the status of the international banking facility. As you know,
for us in New York that has important economic impacts, and it is
esimated 5,000 to 10,000 jobs could be involved. I appreciate the concerns you have, but I would suggest that it may be easier to regulate
these activities and make sure that they are not leaping back onshore
when the paperwork is available readily onshore to begin with, instead
of on some obscure Caribbean islands.
I was wondering what you see as the status of that and the timing
of your making a regulatory decision on that.
Mr. MILLER. Mr. Green, the Board was struggling with a series of
issues. We have quite adverse comments, as you know, and a good deal
of concern and opposition to the IBF concept. We think it has sufficient merit that we should not abandon it. Therefore, our decision
yesterday was to not approve the present application, but to review
it and reconsider it within 6 months, with the additional knowledge
we gain as we carry through the International Banking Act; that
act is on factor. We haven't yet implemented it.
Another factor is the pending legislation, H.E. 7, that could affect
the whole area. Another possibility is what is going to happen with
Edge Corporations and the rights of banks out of New York to have
equal access to this facility. Another issue is the McFadden act report
that is due very soon, and we don't want to fly in the face of that.
Because of these considerations, it seemed better neither to reject the
proposal nor to move forward with it at this point, but to let some of
these changes be digested and to let us get a handle on this issue
before we move ahead in any way.




84
I know you have a concern about this, and we want to assure you
that we are not trying to kill by delay, but we are trying to be responsive to some of these broader issues which we think are getting resolved
as weeks go by.
Mr. GREEN. Let me yield to Mr. Leach.
Mr. LEACH. Mr. Miller, on page 19 you present a chart showing
the decline of the dollar since President 'Carter took office. The decline
is interrupted by a plateau which has lasted from the beginning of
the dollar support program last November until today.
Can you tell the committee what has been the total cost of the dollar
support program? And in this regard, it is interesting to note that
as of today the dollar has declined almost to the point reached before
President Carter's announcement on the first of November, which at
that time was intended to restore world confidence in the American
economy, as well as world respect for leadership in the White House.
Mr. MILLER. Mr. Leach, as you know, the figures on this are published on a quarterly basis, and I will give you the figures through
the last public report. I believe—and the staff will correct me if I am
wrong—that the total cost for this whole operation in terms of the
exchange rate losses suffered by the Federal Eeserve were about $10
million. This involved very large intervention activities; in relation
to size of the activities, this was quite a modest cost especially in terms
of importance of the contribution of that action to reducing our inflation.
The decline of the dollar—this is on page 19—from September 1977
through October 1978, contributed 1 percent to inflation last year. As
it works its way through contracts and prices, we will have 1 percent
more inflation this year. One percent last year, and 1 percent this year
have cost consumers in America $30 billion.
Mr. LEACH. Does the $10 million loss include the loss of the trading
value of the gold which has now reached about $296 an ounce ?
Mr. MILLER. The loss that I mentioned was to the Federal Eeserve
only; that was for the whole period. The Treasury has an exchange
stabilization fund; I don't know what their loss, if any, was. But no,
these figures do not include any effect of gold one way or the other.
As to the gold sales, one has to determine at some future date whether
the choice to sell gold was made at the right time and whether the
intervening use of resources and savings
Mr. LEACH. Certainly, at the present time, we ean:
Mr. MILLER. The Treasury got less for gold than it could have sold
it for now, but if we succeed in our anti-inflation program in 5 years
the costs could be different.
Mr. LEACH. Given your new projected inflation rates, it would appear that the overall program of the Fed, of the Congress, and of the
administration, has been somewhat of a failure. Having said that, I
would point out that the Eepublican Party, through the Eepublican
Policy Committee, came out last week with an alternative economic
plan which included a $36 billion tax cut. The plan called for an immediate and permanent personal income tax reduction of about 10
percent; the indexing of personal income taxes; the freezing of social
security taxes at their present level; and the speeding up of the depreciation rates for structures, equipment, and vehicles.




85
Several of these points you have touched upon in answering earlier
questions. However, would you support the Republican alternative,
particularly in light of the fact that during the last 3 years we have
seen the ineffectiveness of a higher tax program and this would be an
alternative based on lower taxes.
Would you comment on the Republican alternative?
Mr. MILLER. Let me first comment on the statement that our antiinflation program hasn't worked. I have been in Washington less than
a year and a half. In that period of time, a whole array of policies has
been put into effect which represents a comprehensive strategy to wage
a war against inflation. I think you have not given yourself, Mr.
Leach, adequate credit for the role of Congress in putting these policies together. They are important and fundamental policies; they are
effective. They cannot, at this point in time, control an OPEC situation; that involves^, longer term transition in terms of alternate
sources of supply of energy.
But let's tick off the policies that have been put into effect in this
period of time. One, a complete redirection of fiscal policy from larger
deficits to smaller deficits and toward a balanced budget and a lower
percent of GNP represented by Federal expenditures. I give Congress
reat credit for that. It was a courageous and important decision, and
would not want in any way to overlook the importance of it. I
wouldn't want to reverse it; I would not want to have an $80 billion
deficit next year. We have heard from Republicans and Democrats,
since I have been in Washington, of the importance of fiscal discipline
to avoid repeating what was done with whatever intentions in the past.
When we entered this decade, this Nation, almost 200 years old, had
then built up a Federal debt of about $375 billion. It is now over $800
billion.
I think Congress ought to be given great credit for fiscal direction
to counter that trend.
The second policy is an incomes policy
•
Mr. EVANS of Delaware. Mr. Miller, if we might recess for about
7 or 8 minutes. We have to answer a call to vote.
[Brief recess.]
The CHAIRMAN [presiding]. Mr. Watkins.
Mr. WATKINS. In regard to the trade deficit, our biggest purchases
have been in foreign oil, roughly around $50 billion. Now, what,
in your opinion, is the effect of our large foreign oil purchases?
According to numerous reports, a lot of this money is coming back into
the flow of our country's money market, increasing the supply of
our ^ dollar, creating more demand for our products, and basically
having the effect of driving the cost of those products up.
Is that a significant factor, or is that a variable which you see is also
playing havoc with our policy ?
Mr. MILLER. The reflow of petro dollars has, of course, been a major
event Since the oil embargo of 1973. I would again oversimplify for a
moment by saying that, if we held our economic output stable and
there was the kind of change that we have recently had in OPEC
prices, the effect of that would be somewhat like a tax. You pay more
money for the same product; you don't change the quantity, the volume
of the oil, or the amount of output of the economy as a result of that.

f




86

That money flows overseas and out of oi^r economy and no longer
represents domestic purchasing power. It goes to foreigners instead
of Americans. They buy the products that Americans would have
bought had we kept that money here and to that extent output is kept
up. To the extent that it isn't used to buy goods and services in the
United States, it becomes a financial asset, a future claim for goods and
services. It may be invested here or it may be creating instability in
exchange markets as it is converted to some other currency to make a
demand on some other economy, either as a claim or as actual purchasing power.
The impact of that, short term, as we try to point out in the report,
is to transfer real resources overseas, away from Americans, into the
hands of foreigners either to purchase goods and services or to create
claims on us for the future.
Mr. WATKINS. I was looking for a justification for the effect of what
I have been indicating. Also, I wanted to talk to you about consumer
credit and the purchasing power of the consumer. Today we have easy
purchasing power for the consumer, where just a few short years ago
we had to put money down to purchase an appliance, clothing, or
any other depreciable item. Now it seems like we are making greater
use of the credit card and the repayment period is being extended over
a longer time period.
Do you foresee this as having an effect also ? And do you think there
is something that might be done ?
Mr. MILLER. I have been concerned about the general level of debt
of households—consumer and other debt—because it has risen to relatively record levels.
Kecently, we have seen the amount of money required by households
to service their debt rise to a record level in relation to disposable income, so that 23 percent of disposable income—the highest percent
ever—has been devoted to debt service, which means that consumers
are heavily burdened by debt. There has been less in the mortgage area
than you would expect from the level of activity in housing; a great
deal of the family debt increase has been in installment debt.
That has concerned us, and I would say to you the good news is that,
even before the recent shock, our policies had already begun to dampen
consumer demand and there had been a downturn in that statistic.
We were moving down from that high commitment of family income
to debt service and lowering it; it was already beginning to attenuate.
But I might point out, before any of us can carefully evaluate what
is the right level of family debt in today's circumstances, we have a
demographic factor: We have had the wave of World War II babies
coming to marrying age, and at that age from 25 to 35 there is greater
tendency to accumulate debt—to buy that house, buy that refrigerator,
buy that first family car—than there is for people 55 to 65. When a
greater percent of society is shifted into a different age bracket, you
do get a pickup; that may have been a factor.
The second factor has been the movement of women into the mainstream of employment, which is a very positive factor. This has created
many two-family incomes and has increased the capacity of families
to incur debt. This may be a factor.
The credit card may involve an extension of credit, but many credit
cards are not used for credit but merely for convenience in billing. As




87

you know, there are some major cards that are often referred to as
credit cards that aren't credit cards at all; they're charge cards. In
my case, I charge things and at the end of the month I pay for them;
I haven't used any credit, but my charges show up in these consumer
debt statistics.
Mr. WATKINS. Let me see if I am interpreting something correctly.
You said something about family credit. Were you including mortgage payments or appreciable items, as well as consumer credit on
installment payments, which is mostly depreciable items?
Mr. MILLER. We were talking of mortgages on homes; we are talking about installment credit, which will show up in automobiles, durables, and even the purchase of nondurables, and about personal loans
and personal finance.
Mr. WATKINS. Some figures I saw indicated a greater ratio or movement toward consumer depreciable credit than consumer appreciable
credit, which would be found in homes or apartments or things of
this nature.
Mr. MILLER. It was in the installment area that we had this rapid
growth, and it was of concern. I am still concerned. But I just wanted
to explain to you that we were conscious of this before any recent
events. Last September I spoke on this subject and pointed out that
thi,s required very careful attention because if consumers get overloaded and delinquencies move up, you have destabilization. So far,
consumers have handled their payments extremely well. Delinquencies
have not gone up; they have gone down.
But I still am worried, and I am delighted to see that the debt burden
is beginning to come down, which I think is a good trend. Of course,
now, with the recession at hand, it will come down further.
Mr. WATKINS. Very good.
That is all I have, Mr. Chairman.
The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Leach ?
Mr. LEACH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
I apologize for having to leave in the midst of your response. Let
me just repeat the essence of my question.
The Republicans have proposed a four-part alternative to the current economic program. The plan specifically includes a tax reduction
of 10 percent; indexation of taxes; freezing of social security taxes at
the 1979 level; and speeding up of depreciation rates.
Do you support part or all of the Republican package ?
Mr. MILLER. I must confess I have not studied it, but I will give you
several answers.
One is that I believe an immediate tax cut to stimulate the economy
would be unwise. I do not believe it is called for in these circumstances
and it would get us back on the track of big deficits and stimulative
demand and more of the installment debt that we just talked about—
all the things we're trying to get out of.
Second, as to the components—for I believe there will be a time
when we should have tax reduction, in the 1980's—I do not at this
point prefer a direct income tax reduction because I believe we should
keep discipline in our fiscal and monetary policy. If that is true, then
whatever tax relief we can give, I think we should try to give it in the
payroll tax area, where you get both a reduction of tax to the individual and a reduction of cost to business and in turn a reduction of




88
prices which also helps the consumer. The consumer gets two benefits
from one tax cut.
On the business side, I would prefer—and I believe you mentioned
it—accelerated depreciation, which I do think is a very desirable
policy. I don't know just when it should be phased in, Mr. Leach, but
I think we should be looking at it.
Mr. LEACH. The timing would be the issue ?
Mr. MILLER. Yes.
Mr. LEACH. Thank you.
The CHAIRMAN. Ms. Oakar.
Ms. OAKAR. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
First of all, I want to thank you for appearing before our committee once again, Mr. Miller.
I do want to ask you a question relative to the question Mr. Neal
asked you, about the fact that it appears that much of the "blame" for
our economic distress is laid at the doorstep of the OPEC nations. I am
wondering how you feel about the large oil companies in respect to the
astronomical profits that they apparently have been making and what
your concerns are, if any, regarding the decontrol of oil prices ?
Mr. MILLER. The tendency to look for a scapegoat, I think, would be
unfortunate. The condition of inflation that we are suffering from
has built up over 12 or 14 years. For whatever reason, we have pursued a course that has made us vulnerable to action by outsiders. That
outside action hurts us, but we can't blame them for our becoming
vulnerable.
Ms. OAKAR. Well, I am glad you said that, because, frankly, the
tone of your remarks, at least in your introductory remarks and the
report that I have seen, seem to suggest otherwise. So I am glad to
have that for the record.
Mr. MILLER. Congresswoman Oakar, I am glad to have cleared that
up, because I was trying to say there is an oil price shock. It doesn't
have to result in our assessing blame so much as in our becoming much
more realistic, much more aware of the peril to this Nation and how
critical it is that we unite and continue on a steady and effective course
to wring out inflation. There is nothing more important to this Nation.
I do not believe that a political-economic-social system can survive if
we go through 20 more years of this.
I don't want to assess blame. We can blame ourselves collectively.
I don't believe in original sin in the sense that I am responsible for the
policies of 15 years ago, but I would say we are all in this position. My
feeling is that instead of pointing fingers at oil companies or at OPEC
or at the Federal Reserve or at Congress, we should recognize that we
are all Americans and we are all interested in a solution. Oil companies
should not have a disproportionate profit. Cash flow generated from
exceptional profits because of current conditions should be plowed
back into the development of alternate and effective energy resources;
otherwise, they should not be allowed to be retained.
But I don't think any of us gain by finger pointing. We gain more by
recognizing that this is a time for mutual acceptance of restraint,
mutual acceptance of belt tighte$ii*g. I have a sense that Americans
are prepared for that, that tb&j are~p£^pared to give up something if
they believe it is fairly shared a»4:t&»t toere is a direction and a solu-




89
tion which gives them hope for the future and for the prospects of
winning this war.
I hope that this report and anything I have said can be clarified to
indicate my belief that Congress has done many important things in the
1% years of my experience; too little credit has been given to Congress. Perhaps there have been some mistakes. But this is the time to
put that aside and decide where we go from here.
Ms. OAKAR. Would you care to comment on the decontrol of oil
prices or would you prefer not to ?
Mr. MILLER. I will probably surprise you. My personal preference,
if I were the President, would be to decontrol oil prices immediately.
What you do with the money or taxes that might derive from such
action is something else.
The reason I think that might be a desirable policy is that although
it would have a one-time bad effect on inflation, it would also mean
that we would start the process of adjustment much faster and we
would have lower inflation next year. While we would have a quarter
of bad news, we would have many quarters of good news. I think the
change of direction is so important that I would take a shock like that
so as to get downstream to wipe out inflation. That would be my personal preference.
Ms. OAKAR. Mr. Miller, on page 26, you didn't indicate that the
Council on Wage and Price Stability had broad compliance with the
wage standard.
Do you think that their guidelines have been more effective in holding down wages than prices ? And again, I get into the reports of profits, et cetera.
On page 24, you indicate that the Consumer Price Index rose at an
annual rate of 13% percent. I guess my question is: Are workers experiencing, a disproportionate share of the burden ? I feel strongly
Mr. MILLER. They shouldn't.
My view is that these voluntary standards have resulted in less
increases in wages and less increases in prices than would otherwise
have taken place, and that our wage action has been rather commendable overall. It is quite good.
Productivity has been poor, so the unit costs have gone up. But in
terms of wages, it has been a very good program. We must give credit
there, too, to unions and other employee groups who have been willing
to accommodate.
I think businesses have also accommodated. What I don't know is
whether, in the light of events, there should have been a tighter
restraint on price increases because of the volume consideration.
Price increases are related to a level of activity. When you are operating a manufacturing plant and produce 10 percent more than
planned, you don't add 10 percent more total costs; you only add 10
percent more variable costs. Maybe we should have had the standard
a little tighter on prices.
Ms. OAKAR. I think if you have any material in that direction for
the record, that would be very important.
Mr. MILLER. I will see if I can give you something in that regard.
Ms. OAKAR. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
[In response to the request of Cong^esswoman Oakar, the following
information was submitted for the record by Mr. Miller:]




90
REPLY RECEIVED FROM ME. MILLEE
When firms are operating their plants below levels of utilization which provide
the lowest possible total cost per unit of output, an increase in production leads
to a less than proportionate increase in total costs. As output expands, variable
costs associated with the increased use of labor and materials do rise. However,
overhead costs such as property taxes, and insurance and interest payments,
which must be incurred regardless of the level of production, are spread over a
greater amount of output. As a result, total cost per unit of output declines. This
reduction in unit costs, which is based solely on efficiency considerations, could
be passed on to consumers in the form of smaller price increases than otherwise
would have occurred. It must be stressed that the cost of savings are only possible
when output is growing and firms are operating below economic capacity.
There is little direct evidence for individual firms or industries on the operating rates that are associated with producing at the least possible unit costs.
Capacity utilization rates for manufacturing industries, however, are broad
indicators of business operating levels. Over the past year, capacity utilization
rates in most manufacturing industries were below their peak levels experienced
in 1973. This evidence is consistent with the possibility that an appreciable
number of firms were operating below economic capacity and that some reduction in total unit costs could well have accompanied the rise in output levels
seen last year.

The CHAIRMAN. Mr. Vento ?
Mr. VENTO. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
I had some questions. I am sure that I will want to submit some in
writing in addition. Mr. Miller, I paid close attention to your response
to my colleague from Ohio, Ms. Oakar, concerning the increase in
terms of domestic prices.
Now you put an absolute percentage of the OPEC increases at
2 percent.
Is that on the absolute scale that you are talking about, or is that on
the consumer price index scale?
Mr. MILLER. This is on what we call the implicit price deflator, which
measures what really happens in the total economy.
Mr. VENTO. But actually, on the consumer price index, it may be
considerably higher.
Mr. MILLER. ItIt <could be, yes.
Mr. VENTO. I think it is important to note that if it is 2 percent
there, it could be 3 percent or 1 or 2 percent next year.
The difference is important since we are used to dealing with the
consumer price index.
There was a reference to domestic decontrol or phased-in decontrol
and natural gas decontrol, as well as TILT regulations and all other
sorts of things in terms of energy that are not addressed in your 2
percent absolute deflator.
Is that accurate ?
Mr. MILLER. That is correct.
Mr. VENTO. So those are all additional costs. For instance, natural
gas is one of the more significant ones that will be reflected in terms
of costs that apparently have been permitted to go into effect.
Now the only problem in terms of absolute decontrol is the fact that
if we had had absolute decontrol, we would have had an immediate
absolute increase in the price of old domestic oil this year, rather than
a phase in.
So there really is very little control. I mean there is no free market
place in that system.




91
That would actually add to the price and add to the number of
dollars that we are putting into these particular resources and add to
our inflation problem.
So I just feel compelled to point this out because it has not been
discussed here.
At one point, we pegged the cost of each percentage point of inflation, or of unemployment, as costing anywhere from $18 to $20 billion
in terms of the Federal budget.
Aren't we better off converting that into Federal spending ? In other
words, are we better off spending it for unemployment and other types
of welfare benefits, food stamps or whatever, or are we better off spending it on job creation type programs ?
In other words, targeting for specific purposes, whether it is the
National Development Domestic Bank, or an EDA-type of program.
Do you think that we are better off spending for that type of activity ?
Mr. MILLER. We are better off spending it on targeted programs to
improve the employability and skills and upward mobility of those
who are disadvantaged.
Mr. VENTO. So Congress may very well confront an increase in unemployment which you are predicting with such a program. And your
suggestion here would be to put it into the very specific types of programs that are targeted ?
Mr. MILLER. Yes. Mr. Vento, there is, as I understand it, in your
present law, an automatic countercyclical targeted program that comes
into effect when unemployment reaches a certain level.
So the Congress has already built in some automatic targeted efforts,
and I think that is good. I am glad that they are on the books because
you won't have to redo that. That is ready to go, as I understand it.
Mr. VENTO. But the unemployment projections that you have
made, those that the administration has made, I take it, assume the use
of those particular policies.
In other words, that those policies would be in place and hence,
that we would still have the type of unemployment picture that you
are presenting here.
Is that correct ?
Mr. MILLER. The Council of Economic Advisers has taken that
into account. I cannot promise you that every member of the Board
of Governors has taken that into account. They may have.
The CHAIRMAN. I know that you are approaching the end of your
testimony and I see Mr. Eitter going and I see the lights. Did you
have a question, Mr. Hitter, that you could submit to Mr. Miller
for the record ?
Mr. EITTER. Well, I also, like Ms. Oakar, was concerned about Mr.
Miller's view of decontrol. And I was interested in his response.
And what is interesting is that, unfortunately, you are nowhere
near the decisionmaking process when the situations were considered.
And as we were going forward with an enormous energy plan for the
future, multibillions of dollars, did it occur to you that in the recent
speeches of the President, the marketplace or the normal, traditional
forms and structures of the American economy were not even mentioned ?
It almost seemed as if Government is nationalizing the energy
industry.




92
Did that make you worry a little bit? This Energy Mobilization
Board, the security fund, and in the meantime, the allocation system
sits there and the price controls sit there.
As someone from private industry with a long tradition of backing
the concepts of the American economy, did that frighten you at all?
Mr. MILLER. I must say that——
Mr. GONZALEZ. Will the gentleman yield just a minute?
Mr. RITTER. I have to go and vote.
Mr. VENTO. I think it is my time. I want Mr. Miller to respond
to the question of the gentleman from Pennsylvania.
Mr. GONZALEZ. I just" want a unanimous consent to submit my questions in writing.
The CHAIRMAN. Without objection, so ordered.




93
Chairman Miller's responses to written questions submitted by Congressman
Gonzalez in connection with monetary policy hearing on July 17, 1979.

Question #1; On page 2 of your report, you state that "exogenous forces
will be causing intensified inflationary pressures ancf downward adjustments
in the demand for goods and services."
a. Would you state what the level of inflation would have been
without the latest round of OPEC increases, all other things being equal?
b. How much deeper a recession can be expected, owing to the
OPEC increases?
c. On that same sentence, regarding the impact of outside
forces, you aro really saying that monetary policies--at least domestic
monetary policies--are just a very short stick in a very big fight, correct?
d. If domestic policy can only serve to moderate the impacts
of outside forces, doesn't it become more important than ever to coordinate
policy with other central banks? Are you undertaking to do this?
Answer:

Because of the complicated, dynamic inter-relationships

within the economy, it is extremely difficult to separate out the effect of
a factor like OPEC price increases; a rough estimate would be that the OPEC
increases to date, taking into account impacts on prices of other energy
sources and some other indirect effects, will add 2 percentage points to
the rise in the general price level this year and almost another percentage
point in 1980.
It is my view that, had the economy not suffered the oil shock-with its effects both on inflation and on aggregate demand--we would quite
likely have succeeded in avoiding a recession.

Rather, there would have

been a period of moderate growth during which some of the pressures on
productive resources would have eased, thereby helping to slow the pace
of inflation.




94
Monetary policy continues to be an important influence on the
performance of the economy, and there are some exogenous forces whose
effects it might well be able to offset.

However, monetary policy cannot

simultaneously offset the inflationary impulse of the rise in oil prices
and the contractionary impact of the income transfer to foreign oil
producers.

Appropriate monetary—and fiscal--policy responses to this

exogenous shock can minimize the chances that these adverse pressures
would set off cumulative departures from the desired longer-range movements
to full employment and price stability.
Even extensive international coordination of aggregate demand
policy could not overcome the fundamental impact of the OPEC action on
international terms of trade and inflationary pressures.

However, the

cooperative efforts of governments can help to smooth adjustments around
the world, and fortunately there has been good communication at the economic
summit meetings and in the various forums for discussion among financial
officials.




95
Question #2: A few months ago the United States activated its standby
facility at the IMF, to help defend the value of the dollar. Since the OPEC
increases, gold has been zooming up again, but the dollar has not collapsed
or been seriously attacked. Do you attribute this to intervention in the
markets, to a generally stronger U.S. economy, or to what? Are we
fundamentally any better off now than we were then?
Answer:

The effect of OPEC's precipitous oil price increase on

the economic welfare of the citizens of the United States, and the rest
of the world, is unambiguously harmful.

Its effect on the exchange rate

of the dollar is less clear and, among other factors, will depend upon how
successful we are in limiting our oil imports in the wake of those price
increases.
The dollar has come under some downward pressure in exchange
markets in recent weeks and the Federal Reserve and the Treasury, in
cooperation with foreign central banks, have intervened to limit the
dollar's decline.
The fundamental factors that ultimately determine the dollar's
exchange value appear somewhat more favorable now than they were on
November 1.

The slowdown in economic activity in the United States relative

to that abroad is expected to lead to a surplus in our current account by
1980.

And we have made a start in attempting to wind down inflation in

the United States and to limit oil imports.
favorable for the dollar.

These factors are all more

In the long run, the strength of the dollar

will depend mainly on our success in wringing inflation out of the economy.




96
Question #3: On page 8 of the report there is a set of intriguing charts.
The top one shows that personal consumption expenditures actually exceeded
real disposable income in three out of the last four years. The bottom
one shows that in the last four years household debt repayment has
increased from less than 20 per cent of income to 23 per cent or better.
Does this show that people are being forced to borrow in order to sustain
their usual level of living, because inflation has eaten away their real
earnings? And wouldn't this higher ratio of debt actually tend to lengthen
a recession and increase its hardships?
Answer:

The decline in the personal saving rate and the heavy

accumulation of debt may reflect in part an effort to maintain living
standards by households whose budgets have been squeezed by inflation;
another element in the picture is the financing of acquisitions of houses
and other assets expected to rise in price.

Regardless of the cause,

however, it is true that the resultant debt burdens may imply some
reduced resiliency on the part of the household sector in the event of
an economic downturn.

The Board members were mindful of this in arriving

at their projections of the economic outlook.




97
Question #4; You hear nothing more often than the refrain that the
Federal government is the prime cause of inflation.
Cut spending, they
say, and inflation will die. But you say that outside factors are
responsible, and at page 17 you show that real purchases by the Federal
government have shown modest increases since 1975, and in fact are way
down for 1978 and so far this year. Isn't it a fact that the present
level, o-f Federal expenditures is providing very little stimulus to the
economy, and maybe none at all?
Answer:

Federal purchases are just one factor in the overall

impact of the government on economic activity and inflation.

They represent

a direct call on real economic resources and are an important component of
aggregate demand.

However, the other parts of the federal budget—federal

transfer payments and tax revenues--most also be considered in assessing
the influence of the federal sector on the economy.

If one looks back

at the record of the past two decades, one is confronted with the fact
that the federal budget has been in deficit in nearly every year, whether
or not the economy was operating at a high level.

While the past year

has seen some significant progress toward budgetary restraint, there
has continued to be a significant federal deficit which has tended to
boost aggregate demand despite a relatively high level of resource
utilization and unacceptably rapid inflation.




98
Question #5: After the first round of OPEC oil increases there was a
recession, and you seem to think we'll have one this time too. Our
balance of payments problem was compounded by the fact that Europe recovered
more slowly than we did, and this contributed to the sharp fall in the
value of the dollar—a decline of 15% or so in 1977 and 1978. What kind
of action can you take, or do you plan to take, to try and assure that
the industrial world does not fall out of "sync" again?
Answer:

It is generally recognized that our balance of payments

problems were intensified during the last cyclical recovery because our
recovery began earlier and was stronger than the recovery abroad.

An

international pattern of recovery that was more synchronized would have
reduced balance of payments dis-equilibria and would have been desirable
for that reason.

However, one should also realize that a synchronized

upswing carries with it inflationary dangers as pressures are put on
industrial capacity and commodity prices on a world-wide basis.
On balance, it is desirable that cyclical patterns should be
roughly parallel.

With this in mind, the United States and the other major

industrial countries have tried to coordinate their economic policies in
such forums as Summit meetings and the OECD.

Relative cyclical.positions

and external positions were taken account of in the Concerted Action Program
of the OECD.

Thus, economic expansion was encouraged in those countries

like Germany and Japan where the external position allowed them to enjoy
faster growth, while it was recognized that it was appropriate for the
United States to moderate its expansion.

These attempts at coordination

have had some success as witnessed by the increased growth rates of Japan
and Germany, and the reduction of the current account surplus in Japan,
especially.




99
Question #6: Don't you really think that the industrial world should
take concerted action to diminish or break up the power of OPEC?
Answer:

It is imperative that the industrial world take concerted

action to cope with the monopoly power of OPEC. Moreover, in the longer
run the industrial world must face up to the problems connected with its
dependence on a large but diminishing supply of petroleum for its energy
needs, as well as to the special problem that so much of the known supply
is controlled by OPEC.
One line of response is to economize on the use of energy, and
to start down the long road toward the development of better and more
reliable energy sources.

On a multilateral basis, the International

Energy Agency has a role in coordinating the responses of the industrial
countries to OPEC actions. Here at home, the President has just announced
a series of measures to deal with the energy problem.
Another type of response is needed to resist the power of OPEC
countries — or even one or two of them acting alone--to cut off abruptly
the supply of oil for political reasons.

To deal with that problem we

need to go ahead with building a strategic stockpile, even though that will
put additional upward pressure on prices while it is going on.

Once the

stockpiles are in place, however, their existence is likely to help
moderate price increases at times of temporary shortage in the future.




100
Additional Question: Will you provide the Committee with your assessment
of the prospects for the international dollar over the next six months?
Do you anticipate a continued pegging of the Federal Funds rate in the
10 percent range, in order to keep the dollar from falling? Will international considerations significantly limit the flexibility of monetary
policy in dealing with the economic slide that many private economists
now foresee?
Answer:
exchange rates.

The Federal Reserve does not make official forecasts of
In general, however, there are a number of factors which

point toward a relatively stable dollar.

The slowdown in economic

activity in the United States relative to that abroad should lead to a
significant improvement in our current account balance, which is expected
to record a surplus for 1980.

And the President's program for reducing

011 imports will have a favorable long-run impact on the dollar's exchange
value.
The Federal Reserve will continue carefully to weigh international
economic conditions in the formulation of monetary policy. However, that
policy will continue to be directed primarily towards the creation of an
environment that will lead to a sound economy and stable prices at home.
We dojiot anticipate pegging the Federal Funds rate at any particular
level although avoiding sharp shifts in policy will allow us gradually
to wind down inflation without a severe economic downturn.

In the long

run, if the United States is successful in bringing inflation under
control, the dollar's exchange value will reflect this success.




101
The CHAIRMAN. You may continue, Mr. Miller.
Mr. MILLER. My hope, toy advice, if asked, would be that in implementing these energy policies, that we use the private sector, which
has the skills and the organizing ability to carry out these things to
the greatest extent possible.
While I know that some of my business colleagues have been concerned about the aspect that you have mentioned, I also believe that
the President did not foreclose anything you have said, using his
energy security corporation merely as a conduit to help fund private
projects.
I hope that that is what he will choose to do.
Mr. VENTO. I have yielded. I have other questions that I can ask,
too, and I intend to do so.
Mr. MILLER. Perhaps I can drop you a note on that.
Mr. VENTO. One of the points, one of the major things that the Fed
has in terms of its impact on this is the monetary policy, the monetary
restraint, how it translates interest rate increases in the system.
Now one of the things the Council on Wage and Price Stability did
propose, they pointed out three areas. One was in food, 22 percent,
another was in energy, 56 percent increases in terms of cost. And of
course bank profits were up 29 percent.
That is a direct factor in terms of interest rates.
Now interest rates don't suppress credit the way that they are expected to, and I would suggest there was some discussion about their
being overextended, that they do result in these large profits.
And I would just call your attention to that because I continue to
have a concern about the overextension of monetary policy in terms
of what it can and does accomplish.
Mr. MILLER. I appreciate the comments and concerns.
Mr. VENTO. Well, I think that my time has expired.
One other question. There have been parallels drawn, Mr. Miller,
between the monetary policy and the circumstances that existed in
1974 and exist today. Do you think that the Fed is paying attention
to the set of circumstances in which they maintained a tight credit
policy in 1974 in the context of what is happening in the economy
today ?
Mr. MILLER. I believe there was an article yesterday in the Wall
Street Journal suggesting that, in response to the oil price shock in
1974, the Federal Reserve may have been too accommodating and
then, seeing that that policy was unleashing inflation, it may have
put on the brakes too fast.
I think that this is the kind of question that you are getting at. I don't
know whether that analysis is true or false, but I will tell you that
we will do our best to avoid overreacting, shooting from the hip, acting without facts, becolming emotional. We will continue to do our
best to guide the economy on a charted course. That would be best for
all of us.
Mr. VENTO. Do you think that the Federal Reserve policy today
is diffierent from what it was 5 years ago in responding to this oil
price increase? Do you think it is different in terms of the posture
as to where you're headed as opposed to where the Fed was headed
in 1974?




102
Mr. MILLER. I do, because I think that we have a different attitude
on fiscal policy in Congress which is far more helpful to us and more
constructive. Therefore, I think that we have a much more coordinated series of policies, and therefore I think that we can avoid the
sharp amplitudes of swing that were perhaps brought about by the
difficulty of coping anew with this kind of problem.
Mr. VENTO. Well, that sounds like a good note on which to end, so
I will adjourn the hearing with the authority of the chairman.
Thank you very much.
Mr. MILLER. Thank you. I appreciate those last words.
[The following are written questions submitted by Congressman
Jerry M. Patterson of California, with attached answers from Mr.
Miller.]




103
Responses submitted to Congressman Patterson (per his July 19 letter)
in connection with Chairman Miller's testimony of July 17.

Question #1: Consumer installment debt outstanding is at a record high
today--roughly $374 billion.
If the recession worsens, the impact of
loan delinquencies may seriously affect our financial institutions.
What can or is being done by the Fed to counsel institutions on consumer
lending policies and/or general safety precautions?
Answer;

The debt burden assumed by some households

matter of some concern;

it

is a

could represent somewhat of a drag on the

economy should income and employment conditions deteriorate to a greater
extent than anticipated.

Members of the Federal Reserve Board have been

calling attention to this potential problem for some time now, in Congressional testimony and elsewhere.
been helpful in encouraging

Such statements, it is hoped, have

due caution on the parts of both borrowers

and lenders—while not intruding excessively in private decision-making
or creating unwarranted alarm and consequent contractive pressures.
The more direct counseling of lending institutions occurs
through the regular examination process.

Examiners scrutinize loan

portfolios and credit policies to determine whether banks are following
sound practices; where unsound practices are detected, they are specifically
criticized.

Substandard loans are identified, and, when appropriate,

examiners may indicate that a bank should forgo promotion of lending and
undertake greater collection efforts.
off of loan losses.




Examiners also may require charge-

104
Question #2: Section 3 of a Juno 1976 Board publication titled "Improving
the Monetary Aggregates" deals with conceptual and definitional issues
surrounding the various M's. I am particularly interested in the impact
of credit card purchases on the money supply. Let me quote from the report
at page 11:
Credit cards and the "chcckless society"
An increasing volume of purchases is being made on
credit cards, and direct credits of wages and salaries
"to bank accounts and debits to purchasers' bank accounts
by sellers through computer networks will probably
spread in the years ahead, perhaps moving the economy
toward an increasingly "checkless society" in the foreseeable future. Insofar as credit-card purchases and
the elimination of physical bank checks merely provide
more convenient and efficient means of transferring
demand deposits, they do not call for any redefinition
of the money stock--although they may lead to a higher
velocity of circulation.
Insofar as they actually
involve creation of new transferable money by sellers
who temporarily increase the spending power of buyers,
they certainly increase the volume of credit, although
they do not increase MI as now defined or as it might
be defined in response to the financial developments
so far considered.
If credit cards and a checkless society largely
supplant present methods of payment, it will become
desirable to redefine Mj_ and the other'deposit totals
based on it in a more fundamental way.

I would appreciate your clarification of that statement.
Also, I am interested to know whether the Board now recommends
changes in the M-l definition to take into consideration the impact of
credit card purchases?
Answer:

The statement quoted is part of the report of "Bach

Committee," a group of eminent private economists that—at the request
of the Board—examined the monetary aggregates and submitted recommendations
for improvements in concepts and measurement.




These recommendations are

105
being considered in the Board's current examination of the definitions
of the monetary aggregates.

Staff work is continuing and the Board has

yet to arrive at any conclusions, but it appears unlikely that the growing
use of credit cards per se will require changes in the definition of M-l.
As the quotation suggests, credit cards facilitate the extension of credit
but do not themselves represent or create money.

Rather, like many other

financial innovations, they increase the volume of transactions that can
be conducted with a given money stock, i.e., the velocity of money.

In

the case of credit cards, for example, many users find them a way of
better controlling the timing of their payments, so that they need not
maintain large checking account balances at all times to cover unexpected
outlays.

Ultimately, however, a payment must be made in the form of

currency or transference of checking account funds--whether that payment
is made by the consumer directly to the seller or by the consumer
credit card issuer who pays the seller.

to the

Thus credit card indebtedness

or credit lines do not constitute money, but their effect on velocity
must be considered in assessing the impact of monetary policy on the
economy.




106
Question #3: President Carter, in his nationally televised speech on
July 15, touched on several problem areas of the American economy. One,
of course, is our productivity level. The question that interests me
is what are the most effective methods by which productivity can be
improved?
What is your view about approaching the problem in
part by accelerated depreciation of commercial assets?
-

What advantages or disadvantages do you see in terms
of adjustments for inflation by accelerated depreciation?

Answer:

Investment in more modern and efficient plant and

equipment is a major element in the achievement of faster productivity
growth.

I strongly support the liberalization of accelerated depreciation

in order to encourage capital formation.

Such changes in the tax laws

must be made, however, with an eye to the overall fiscal policy stance
of the federal government and should not hinder the achievement of a
balanced budget.

At the present time, with a sizable federal deficit

and strong inflationary pressures, it would not be prudent to initiate
a major tax cut.
With regard to the question of adjustment for inflation,
accelerated depreciation would offset some of the effects of the understatement of depreciation in an environment of rising prices.

Other

techniques, such as replacement cost accounting, could be employed; these
other approaches have their particular relative advantages or disadvantages.
I believe, however, that, in terms of getting the greatest stimulus to
capital formation per dollar of tax revenue reduction, accelerated depreciation has distinct advantages since only firms making new investments
in plant and equipment receive the tax benefit.




107
Question #4: This Congress is well aware of existing budgetary constraints and the commitments we must make to national priorities including
energy, housing, mass transportation, and defense, among others. A
question which I and many of my colleagues share is this: The. recession
may necessitate a tax cut. When should such a reduction occur and what
type of jnix for individuals and small business relief would be most
effective in .your opinion?
Answer:

I do not at this time foresee the need for a tax cut

in order to bring the economy out of the nild recession we appear to be
experiencing.

However, if a tax cut becomes nec-essary at a future time

in order to bolster the economy--or is simply made possible by the growth
of tax revenues related to the rise in incomes--it would be desirable to
focus attention on those changes that would yield maximum benefits in
aiding progress toward price stability.

Prime candidates in this regard

are cuts in payroll taxes, which would have the dual benefit of easing a
regressive tax and reducing labor costs, and liberalized accelerated
depreciation, which would encourage productivity-increasing capital
formation.
all sizes.




These tax cuts would benefit individuals and businesses of




APPENDIX I

THE LIBRARY OF CONGRESS
Congressional Research Service

WASHINGTON, D.C.




20540

BRIEFING MATERIALS FOR MID-YEAR 1979 MONETARY POLICY OVERSIGHT

Prepared for the Committee on Banking,
Finance and Urban Affairs
United States House of Representatives

by
F. Jean Wells
Roger S. White
Specialists in Money and Banking

Carol A. Leisenring
Analyst in Money and Banking
Economics

Division

July 16, 1979

(109)

110
BRIEFING MATERIALS FOR MID-YEAR 1979 - MONETARY P.OLICY OVERSIGHT

This briefing document has been prepared to assist the House
Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs in monetary policy
oversight conducted pursuant to P.L. 95-523.

It includes selected

indicators for the economic setting in which monetary policy operates
as well as presenting indicators of the direction of monetary policy
itself.

Assistance in preparing this report was obtained from Laura

A. Layman, Economic Analyst; Barry Molefsky, Analyst in Econometrics;
and Frances C. Klapthor, Editorial Assistant.

Listing of tables and graphs
I.

Monetary and financial measures and Federal
System targets:

Page
Reserve

Monetary and credit aggregates — actual levels
from fourth quarter 1976, and Federal Reserve
projected growth ranges from fourth quarter 1978
to fourth quarter 1979:
Ml (graph)
M2 (graph)
M3 (graph)
Bank credit (graph)

1
2
3
4

Growth rates for selected reserve, monetary, and credit
aggregates, 1975 through second quarter 1979 (table) ...
Income velocity of money, percent change from same
quarter, previous year, 1973 to first quarter 1979:
Ml (graph)
M2 (graph)




6
7

Ill
CRS - ii

Listing of graphs and tables (cont.)
Interest rates: rates on Federal funds, 6 month
Treasury bills and new home mortgages, 1973 to
date (graph)

8

Selected interest rates, 1973-1979 (table)

9

Funds raised in U.S. credit markets, 1975 to
first quarter 1979 (table)
II.

Page

10

Economic forecasts and economic goals:
1979 economic forecasts and Administration goals
(table)
1980 economic forecasts and Administration goals
(table)
January 1979 summary of Administration's goals
consistent with the objectives of the
Humphrey-Hawkins Act, 1979-1983 (table)
July 1979 summary of Administrations*s long-range
economic goals and alternative economic
assumptions, 1981-1984 (tables)

III. Federal budget data:
Federal budget receipts and outlays, fiscal years
1975-1980 (table)
;
IV.

Selected international statistics:
Exports, imports, trade balance and trade-weighted
exchange value of the U.S. Dollar, 1975 to date
(table)




1?

MONEY SUPPLY (M1)

Actual Levels from Fourth Quarter 1976 and Federal Reserve
Projected Growth Range from Fourth Quarter 1978 to Fourth Quarter 1979
Billions

420
Upper bound of projected
growth range: 4,5%*

400

6.3%*
380

Growth rate range for the period HO 1979
to 1VQ 1979 consistent
with the 1.5% to 4.5%
one-year growth range
announced Feb. 1979.

360
340
320

300 h




IV

1976>

!Q

10

1977-

II

lit

-1978-

IQ

II

III

-1979-

•Growth rates are seasonally adjusted compound annual rates,
'
'
Data Source: Quarterly observations and growth rates are calculated from seasonally adjusted data series of the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System as revised in May 1979.

10

II

III

-1980

IV

'

MONEY SUPPLY (M2)
Actual Levels from Fourth Quarter 1976 and Federal Reserve
Projected Growth Range from Fourth Quarter 1978 to Fourth Quarter 1979

$ Billions
1050

.Upper bound of projected
growth range: 8.0%*

1000




10.8%"
950
Growth rate range for
the period IIQ 1979
to IVQ1979 consistent
with the 5.0$ to 8.0%
one-year growth range
announced Feb. 1979.

900

850

800

750

IV

1976v

I!

Hi

-1977-

IV

IQ

II

III

-1978-

IV

IQ

II

HI

-1979-

•Growth rates are seasonally adjusted compound annual rates.
growth rates
. ...
Data Source: Quarterly observations andjrowth
rates are calcul
calculated from seasonally adjusted
data series of the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System as revised
May 19T"
1979.
~ * d in May

IQ

ri
in
-1980-

FV




MONEY. SUPPLY M)

Actual Levels from Fourth Quarter 1976 and Federal Reserve
Projected Growth Range from Fourth Quarter 1978 to Fourth Quarter 1979
$ Billions

1700

Upper bound of projected
growth range: 9.0% *

11.6%'
Growth rate range for
the period IIQ 1979
to IVQ 1979 consistent with the 6.0% to 9.0%
one-year growth range
announced Feb. 1979.

1600

1500
Lower bound of projected
growth range: 6.0%*

1400

1300

IV

|Q

II

III

-1980•Growth rates are seasonally adjusted compound annual rates.
Quarterly observations
observations and
and growth
growth rates
rates are
are calculated
calcul
.
Data Source:: Quarterly
from
seasonally adjusted data series of the
Board of Governors of- the
Reserve System as revised Jn May 1979.
• » Federal
Federal R

BANK CREDIT
Actual Levels from Fourth Quarter 1976 and Federal Reserve
Projected Growth Range from Fourth Quarter 1978 to Fourth Quarter 1979

$ Billions
1100

Upper bound of projected
growth range: 10.5%*

1050 -

8.1%* fGrowth rate range for
the period IIQ 1979
to IVQ 1979 consistent
with the 7.5% to 10.5%
one-year growth range
announced Feb. 1979.

1000 -




800

IQ

II

III

.1980
* Growth rates are seasonally adjusted compound annual rates.
Data Source: Quarterly observations and growth rates are calculated from seasonally adjusted data series of the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System as revised in May 1979.

IV

'

MONETARY AND CREDIT AGGREGATES
(Seasonally adjusted compound annual rates)
1978
• If
y
I/
I/
I/
_2/
£/
1975
1976
1977
1978
II
III
IV

1979
2/

Federal Reserve
targets: 4th
2j quarter 1978 to 3/
II
4th quarter 1979""

Monetary aggregates:
Ml

4.6

M2

8.4

5.8

10.9

9.5

8.1

4.2

-2 .1

7 .8

1.5 to 4. 5

9.8 , 8.4 8.7

10.1

7.8

1.8

8 .9

5.0 to 8. 0

7.9

7.2

11,1

12.7

11.7

9.3

8.7

10.7

9.6

4 .8

8 .1

6.0 to 9. 0

Deposits at nonbank thrift
institutions
15.7

15.6

14.5

10.6

8.8

11.5

12.2

9 .2

7 .0

NA

4.1

8.1

11.2

12.5

15.9

12.3

11.5

13 .8

12 .0

7.5 to 10 .5

Adjusted monetary
base
7.6
(St. Louis F.R. Bank)

8.4-

8.8

9.6

8.3

9.7

10.0

5.9

6,5

NA

M3

Bank credit

\J

From fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated.

2/

From previous quarter.

3J

Federal Reserve projections as announced in Monetary Report to Congress Pursuant
to the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978, February 20, 1979,

kl

Total loans and investments at commercial banks; revised May, 1979.

Sources:




Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and Federal Reserve Bank
of St. Louis, Accessed from data files of Data Resources, Inc.

INCOME VELOCITY OF MONEY (HI)
PERCENT CHRNGE FROM SRME QURRTER, PREVIOUS YERR

z:
o
a:
ui
a.

•10

8-r

—8

6-

—6

UJ

•4

4h

f
1973

1
1974

1
1975

1

1
1976

1977

1978

1979
7/10/79

gT EaVKi«S!JS BT THE FCOCRHL EE5£RVE SYSTCM
E£PT, 6F CO-UIKCE, CUSERU EK ECBfJSMIC R^HLVSIS

fir cc^s:£sie;a. crcEfwcH SERVICE. LZESF^V er




INCOME VELOCITY OF MONEY (M2)
PERCENT CHRNGE FROM SRME QURRTER, PREVIOUS YERR

•8
~

6

2-

••

_ /^

o-

—0

4UJ

o

n_

-2-

1973

t
t
1974 1975 1978 1977

t
1978 1979

V

7/10/79
DT SSVEB^nS 0F THE FHOflL EEED3VE SYSTCH
KPT. Cf CEKKCSCC* EUCtnU BF ECEfjaTIIC F^nLYSIS
6V C8?^£S5IBT(Ri. R£SCHRCH ££BVIC£. LISniiKY ET




•-2

INTEREST RflTES
FEDERRL FUNDS RflTE (LINE)
RVERflGE YIELD ON 6 MONTH TREflSURY BILLS (DOT)
EFFECTIVE YIELD ON NEW HOME MORTGRGES (DRSH)
14

14

12

12

10

10

LU

o

C£
UJ
0-

8

8

6

6

1973

1974

1975

1976

1977

1978

1979
7/12/79

6383D Bf E0VE(WOSS 0f THE FEDEBRL RESERVE SYSTEM

KPT. or THE; TRWsuar RWD THE reKRS. HBKE LB3N

SV CB£«£S5ISNm. flCSEffiO SERVICE. LianBSY BF CEISSEES




SELECTED INTEREST RATES, 1973-1979

1973

1974

1975

1976

1977

1978

1st half
1979

3-mo. treasury bills
(new issues)

7.03

7.87

5.82

4.99

5.26

7.22

9.37

10-yr. treasury securities
(constant maturity)

6.84

7.56

7.99

7.61

7.42

8.41

9.11

Corporate Aaa bonds
(Moody1 s)

7.44

8.57

8.83

8.43

8.02

8,73

9.34

Prime commercial paper,
4-6 mos

8.15

9.84

6.32

5.35

5.60

7.99

9.98

Prime rate charged by
banks

8.02

10.80

7.86

6.84

6.82

9.06

11.75

Effective conventional
mortgage rate, new homes,
combined lenders

7.95

8.92

9.01

8.99

9.01

9.54

10.50

Federal Reserve discount
rate (N.Y. F.R. Bank)

6.44

7.83

6.25

5.50

5^52

7.52

9.50

8.73

10.50

5.82

5.05

5.54

7.93

10.13

Federal funds

rate

Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Federal Home Loan Bank Board, and
Moody f s Investors Service, Accessed from data files of Data Resources, Inc.




FUNDS RAISED IN U.S. CREDIT MARKETS
[In billions of dollars; quarterly data are seasonally adjusted at annual rates]

Total funds raised,
by instrument:

1975

1976

1977

1978

1978
(ID

1978
(III)

1978
(IV)

1979
(I)

219 .8

301.7

399 .4

490.8

474.4

483.6

518 .5

472.4

-1.9

-1 .2

-1.3

Investment company shares

-a

-1.0

-1 .0

-1.1

-.9

Other corporate equities

10 .8

12.9

4.8

3.6

4.1

5.0

3 .5

2.8

209 a

289.8

395 .6

488.2

471.2

480.5

516 .3

470.9

U.S. Government securities

98 .2

88.1

84 .3

95.2

95.8

96.3

83 .7

70.6

State and local obligations

15 .6

19.0

29 .2

30.1

36.6

38.7

24 .6

19.4

Corporate and foreign bonds

36 .4

37.2

36

a

31.5

35.8

33.8

27 .8

25.5

Mortgages

57 .2

87.1

134 .0

149.2

145.9

154.8

161 .5

142.5

9.4

23.6

35 .0

49.9

56.4

48.5

52 .8

49.8

Debt instruments:

Consumer credit
Bank loans, n.e.c.
Open market paper
and repurchase agreements
Other loans

Source:




-13 .9

6.4

32 .2

53.0

32.1

56.7

59 .5

35.2

-2 .4

13.3

19 .8

42.5

36.9

20.4

61 .6

94.2

8.7

15.3

25

a

36.9

31.7

31.3

44 .8

33.7

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

1979(1) based on incomplete data.

122
CKS - 11

l

1979 ECONOMIC FORECASTS AND ADMINISTRATION GOALS*"
January 1979

July 1979
DRI
••••

Wharl

•-• " " •

Humphrey-Hawkins
Act Goals
Level , fourth quarter 1979
Employment
(millions)

97.5

96.2

96.6

96.7

Unemployment
rate (percent)

6.2

Consumer
prices

Percent change, fourth quarter 1978 to fourth q uarter 1979
3/
7.5
10.6
10.9
10.9
10.5

12.7

Real gross
national product

2.2

-0.6

Real disposable
income

2.8

Productivity
total economy 4/

0.4

6.6

6,9

-0.5

-1,0

7.2

-1.5

-0.3

6.8

6.9

-1.3

'-0.5

0.3

-0.2

-1.2
-2.2

Variables
Money supply (Ml)

3.5

2.1

4.5

Money supply

6.4

4,7

6.9

9.4

9.5

9.8

8.76

8.58

(M2)

Federal funds
rate (percent)
91 Day Treasury
Bill Rate (percent)

5/
8.8

5/
9.0

8.91

I/
~

These forecasts are based on different s ystems, different models, and different
policy assumptions; therefore, their comiparability is limited.

2/

Mid-point of forecast range.

3/

Percent change, December over December.

SOURCE:

4/

Based on total re al GNP per hour worked,
new issues,

1979.

U.S. Council of Economic Advisers. Economic Report of the President. Washington,
U.S. Govt. Print. Off., 1979, p. 109. Mid-Session Review of the 1980 Budget,
Office of Management and Budget, July 12, 1979, p. 4. CBO Current Policy Forecast
in statement by Alice M. Rivlin, Director, Congressional Budget Office, before Che
Committee on the Budget, United States Senate, July 12, 1979, p. 7. Chase Econometric
Associates, Inc., Standard Forecast of June 21, 1979. Data Resources Incorporated,
Control Forecast of June 28, 1979. Wharton Economic Forecasting Associates Inc«»
Control Forecast of June 28, 1979.




123

I/
1980 ECONOMIC FORECASTS AND ADMINISTRATION GOALS
January 1979
Administration

July 1979
Administration

Current
CBO Policy

Curren
Chase

Humphrey-Hawkins
Act Goals
Level, fourth quarter 1980
Employment
(millions)
Unemployment
rate (percent)

3/

Consumer
prices

6.4

Real gross
national product

3.2

Real disposable
income

2.3

Productivity
total economy 4/
private business
private nonfarm

8.3

8.9

7.7

7.9

2.0

Q

1.8

° °

"

10.9

1.0

1.1
-

Monetary Policy
Variables
Money supply

(Ml)

Money supply

(M2)

Level, fourth quarter 1980
Federal funds rate
(percent)
91 Day Treasury
Bill Rate (percent)

6.9
5/
7.6

_5/
8.2

6.40

__
8.8

8.22

II

These forecasts are based on different systems, different models, and different
policy assumptions; therefore, their comparability is limited.

2_/

Mid-point of forecast range.

4/

_3/

Percent change, December over December.

_5/

SOURCE:

See preceding




table.

124

SUMMARY OF ADMINISTRATION'S ECONOMIC GOALS CONSISTENT WITH
I/
THE OBJECTIVES OF THE HUMPHREY-HAWKINS ACT

Goal Forecasts

Goal Requirements

Level, fourth quarter

Employment (millions)
Unemployment (percent)

Real disposable income

97.5

99.5

102.6

105.5

6.2

6.2

3.4

4.6

3/
4.0

108.3

75

64

5 2

4 1

3 0

22

32

46

46

4 2

2.8

2.3

4.4

4.4

4.0

.4

1.1

1.8

2.0

2.0

21
Productivity

\J

"The short-term goals for 1979 and 1980 represent a forecast of how the economy
will respond over the next 2 years not only to the budgetary policies proposed
by the President for fiscal 1979 and 1980 but to the anti-inflation program
announced on October 24. The medium-term goals for 1981 to 1983 are not forecasts. They are projections of the economic performance that would be required
to reach the 1983 unemployment and inflation goals specified in the act."
1979 Economic Report of the President, p. 108-109.

2_l

Based on total real GNP per hour worked.

_3/
~

The Humphrey-Hawkins Act puts the unemployment goal at 4% among individuals
aged 16 and over in the civilian labor force by 1983 and an inflation rate of
3% as measured by the consumer price index, also by 1983.

Source:




U.S. Council of Economic Advisers. Economic Report of the President.
U.S. Govt. Print. Off., 1979. p. 109.

Washington,

JULY 1979 SUMMARY OF ADMINISTRATION'S LONG-RANGE
I/
ECONOMIC GOALS AND ALTERNATIVE ECONOMIC ASSUMPTIONS'"

Table 18.—LONG-RANGE ECONOMIC GOALS, 1981-1984
(calendar years; dollar amounts in -billions)

Major Economic Indicators
Gross national product, .(percent change, 4th quarter over
4th quarter):
Current dollars
;
.........
Constant (1972) dollars....
*
GNP deflator (percent change, 4th quarter over 4th quarter)...
Consumer Price Index (percent change, December over December).
Unemployment rate (percent, 4th quarter)

Assumed for
Budget Projections
.
1981
1982 1983 1984
11.7
• 5.3
6.1
6.0
6.0

10.2
5.5
4.5
4.5
4.8

7.6
4.4
3.0
3.0
4.0

6.1
3.0 .3.0
3.0
4.0

Table 28.—ALTERNATIVE LONG-RANGE ECONOMIC ASSUMPTIONS, 1981-19B4
(calendar years; dollar amounts in billions)

Major Economic Indicators
Gross, national product, (perqeht change, 4th quarter over
4th quarter);
Current dollars
Constant (1972) dollars..,.
GNP d e f l a t o r (percent change, 4th q u a r t e r over 4th q u a r t e r ) . . .
Consumer Price Index (percent change, December over December).
Unemployment rate (percent, 4th quarter)




\J
~*

^
^

Assumed for Alternative
Budget Projections
1981
1982 1983
11.'4
' 4.0
7.1
6.8
6.3

10.3
3.5
6.6
6.5
6.0

9.8
3.5
6.1
6.0
5.7

As noted on pages 54 and 58 of the Mid-Session Review of the 1980 Budget:
"The long-range economic assumptions differ in nature from the short-range economic foreeast presented earlier. These assumptions are not forecasts of economic events, but projections
that assume progress in moving toward lower unemployment rates and greater price stability.
(Continued on page 15.)

9.3
3.5
5.6
5.5
5.5




(Continued from page 14.)
"Two sets of longer-range economic assumptions* and budget projections corresponding to each,
are shown. One set, discussed in this section, assumes the achievement of the medium-term goals
specified in the Full-Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978 (the Humphrey-Hawkins Act).
[Table 18]. These goals ate highly ambitious and may be difficult to achieve. The other set of
assumptions, discussed in a later section, are less ambitious."
"[Table 28] presents an alternative set of economic assumptions and a corresponding set of
budget projections."
"Under the alternative assumtions presented here, the economy is assumed to grow in real
terms by an average of 3.6Z a year for the entire 1981-1984 period. The rate of unemployment
corresponding to this growth projection is 5 1/2% at the end of calendar year 1984. The rate of
inflation is assumed to drop by about half a percentage point a year after 1980, reaching 5 1/2X
a year in 1984. These more conservative assumptions may be more appropriate for budget planning
purposes than those of the preceding sections."
H-A

to
irce:

Mid-Session Review of the 1980 Budget, Office of Management and Budget, July 12, 1979.
pp. 60, 72.

°^

127

FEDERAL BUDGET RECEIPTS AND OUTLAYS
(In billions of dollars) I/

Budget
receipts

Budget
outlays

1975

281 .0

326 .2

1976

300 .0

366 .4

Q1
O1

y^f .->/
Q/L

Budget
surplus or
deficit

-45 .2
-66 .4
—1
1 oJ

1977

357 .8

402 .7

-45 .0

1978

402 .0

450 .8

-48 .8

461 .0

494 .5

-33 .5

466 ^5

496 f 2

-29 ^ 7

509 .0

532 .0

-23 .0

513 .8

542 .4

-28 .7

Fiscal year 1978

247 .5

297 .2

-49 .7

Fiscal year 1979

292 .1

328 .1

-36 .0

1979(estimates)

2/
Third Concurrent Resolution, May 1979

3/

1980(estiraates)

4/
First Concurrent Resolution, May 1979

I/
Mid-session review, July 1979

Cumulative totals first 8 months:

\J

Unified budget basis.

2/

Third Concurrent Resolution on the Budget —

_3/

Estimates from Mid-Session Review of the 1980 Budget, Office of Management
and Budget, July 12, 1979.

47

First Concurrent Resolution on the Budget —

Source:

Fiscal Year 1979, May 24, 1979.

Fiscal Year 1980, May 24, 1979.

Economic Indicators, June 1979, and Mid-Session Review of the 1980
Budget, Office of Management and Budget, July 12, 1979.




I/
EXPORTS, IMPORTS, TRADE BALANCE AND TRADE-WEIGHTED EXCHANGE
i/
VALUE OF THE U.S. DOLLAR

1979

1978
1975

1976

1977

1978

I

II

III

IP

IV

II

(in billions of dollars ; quarterly data seasonally adjusted)
Exports

107 .1

114.7

120.8

141.9

30 .8

35.3

36.5

39.3

41.4

NA

Imports

98 .0

124.0

151.7

176.0

42 .7

43.2

44.5

45.7

47.4

NA

-8.0

-6.4

90.65

87.81 88.14 89.79

Trade balance

9.0

-9.4

-30.9 -34.2 -11.9 -7.9

-6.1

NA

*****************************************************

Index of the
weighted-average
98.34
exchange value
of the U.S. dollar

105.57

103.30

92.39

95.90

95.20

\J

Merchandise, excluding military, on balance of payments basis (adjusted from Census
data for differences in timing and coverage).

J2/

Index of weighted average exchange value of U.S. dollar against currencies of other
G-10 countries (Germany, Japan, France, United Kingdom, Canada, Italy, Netherlands,
Belgium, Sweden) and Switzerland. March 1973=100. Weights are 1972-1976 global
trade of each of the 10 countries.

Sources:




Exports, imports, and trade balance - Economic Indicators, June 1979.
Trade-weighted exchange value of the U.S. Dollar - Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System.

APPENDIX II

SUBCOMMITTEE ON
DOMESTIC MONETARY POLICY
BRIEFING MATERIALS
PREPARED FOR HEARINGS ON
THE CONDUCT OF MONETARY POLICY
BEFORE THE

COMMITTEE ON
BANKING, FINANCE AND URBAN AFFAIRS




JULY 17, 1979
(129)

130
CHART 1.

Exhibit 1 breaks the 1954-1977 period into eight

consecutive 3-year periods: 1954-1956, 1957-1959, etc.

For

each 3-year period, Chart 1A relates average Ml growth to
the average rate of rise in the Consumer Price Index
(inflation);

Chart IB relates average Ml growth to the

average rate of interest on.3-month Treasury bills;

Chart

1C relates average Ml growth to the average rate of
unemployment.
The exhibit shows that there is a close positive relationship
between money growth and inflation (chart 1A) and between
money growth and the rate of interest (chart IB).

It shows

that as money growth increases, so do both inflation and the
rate of interest.

However, it also shows that there is no

relationship between the rate of money growth and the rate
of unemployment (chart 1C).

This belies the Phillips Curve

theory that inflation is inversely correlated with unemployment.
The closeness of these relationships is denoted by the lines
which were fitted in between the points on the graphs.

Note

the straight lines which were easily drawn in charts 1A and
IB.

It was impossible to fit one line into chart 1C.







131
CHART 1(\

AVERAGES IN 3-YEAR NON-OVERLAPPING PERIODS
OF Ml GROWTH & THE RATE OF GROWTH IN
THE CONSUMER PRICE INDEX
7c 77
75 77
1954 - 1977
'

69-71

3.4

7.a

4.6

Ml Percent Growth
CHART IB

AVERAGES IN 3-YEAR NON-OVERLAPPING PERIODS
OF Ml GROWTH & THE 3-YEAR TREASURY BILL
7? 7A
RATE,
1954 - 1977
^"-->*
75-77

5.5 •

£-71
66-68

6?-65

4-5-

3.5
4*6
Ml Percent Growth

CHART 1C

S-7

AVERAGES IN 3-YEAR NON-OVERLAPPING PERIODS
OF Ml GROWTH & '£HJEUB»EMPfirjYMENT» RATE
1954 - \22*~~~^
75-77*^

3.5
4.6
Ml Percent Growth

5.7

132
Chart 2.

Last March, the Committee recommended that money growth

be established at 6 percent this year, then reduced one percentage
point each year until year-over-year money growth is established
at 3 percent in 1982; where it would be maintained in 1983.

The

Committee defined money supply as Ml plus ATS and NOW accounts.
Until April 1979, the growth rate of the Committee's recommended
money supply was substantially less than 6 percent per annum.

As

a result the outstanding volume of money fell short of- the volume
projected by the Committee as necessary if we are to avoid recession
while unwinding inflation.

In the April-June period, growth of

the money soared to an annual rate of 11 percent.

The upsurge in

the Committee's recommended money measure soared to an annual rate
of 11 percent.

The upsurge in money growth in the second quarter

should be regarded as a constructive correctice measure.

However,

it is now important to moderate money growth so as to keep it from
growing more than 6 percent for 1979 as a whole.




CHART 2
ACTUAL MONEY ;SUPPLY
VERSUS

HOUSE BANKING COMMITTEE'S RECOMMENDATION
OF MARCH 1979
PROJECTION LINE IS BASED ON 6% GROWTH FROM NOVEMBER, 1978 THRU NOVEMBER, 1979;
AND 5% GROWTH FROM NOVEMBER, 1979 THRU NOVEMBER, 1980
BASE PERIOD IS OCTOBER, NOVEMBER, DECEMBER 1978 AVERAGE
OF Ml, SA + ATS + NOWs.

• PROJECTION

o

H
I

r^

.-u




38a •
/^•Ml + ATS + NOWs (ACTUAL)

Ml, SA

I

!

|

?V>

I

I

I

I

I

!

I

!

I

flONTMLV PAT A

!

I

[

m

!

I

oo
CO

134
CHART 3.

Ml growth, measured between the same months of adjacent

years (for example, January 1947 to January 1948), cycled down
and up seven times between the end of World War II and 1978; and
now, after a prolonged upsurge, is headed down once more.
Our economy's performance in the post World War II period is
mirrored in this chart of money growth.

Inflation was broken

after World War II and again after the Korean War by sustained
low money growth.

It was rekindled after 1964 by upsurges in

money growth in the late 1960s, 1971-1973, and 1977-1978.
Recessions, which are delineated by the vertical lines on the
time axis, occurred in the wake of decelerations in Ml growth,
as the chart shows.
Last March, based on data through February, we stated:

"The

chart indicates that we are now headed for another recession."
It is now apparent that we were right.
How deep and long the recession becomes depends on how the
Federal Reserve manages the growth of Ml (adjusted to include
ATS accounts) from now on.




CHART 3

NARROWLY DEFINED MONEY SUPPLY, M-1
PERCENT CHANGE, YEAR TO YEAR"
Ml ADJUSTED TO INCLUDE ATS ACCOUNTS

6.W-




00

!

71 !72 '73 '74 '75 '7G *7V *7d '70 '

136
CHARTS 3.1 & 3.2.

These exhibits graph year to year percentage

changes in Mi-plus and M2.

The growth profiles of these two

aggregates also warn that monetary policy again has lain the
groundwork for another recession.




137

M1 PLUS MONEY SUPPLY
PERCENT CHANGE, YEAR TO YEAR|

3-2

U? 148 '43 '581S1 '52 'S3 '54 >SS '56 '57 'S8 '58 T68 '61 (62 '63 '04 '66 '66 '€




MONTHLY DATA
CHART 3.2

|PERCENT CHANGE IN THE M-2 MONEY SUPPLY
!
YEAR TO YEAR

138
EXHIBIT 4.

Exhibit 4 provides another way of looking at the

relationships between money growth, inflation and interest rates.
Exhibit 4A charts the percentage changes in the CPI against
percentage changes in Ml (money supply) which has been lagged
two years.

The exhibit shows that the rate of inflation follows

Ml growth two years earlier fairly closely.
Exhibit 4B charts the percentage change in the CPI against
the percentage change in Ml lagged 2 years, but here adjusted to
include ATS accounts and overnight repurchase agreements.

The

inclusion of these two adjustments picks up much of the recent
inflation which cannot be explained by Ml alone.




139
CHART W

YEAR TO YEAR PERCENT CHANGE
BAR CHART IS C P I
LINE IS M l MONEY SUPPLY LAGGED 2

1

56 ' 57 ' 58 ' 50 ' 68 ' 61 ' 62 ' 63 ' 64 ' 65 ' 66 ' 67 ' 68 ' 69 ' 78 ' 71 ' 72 ' 73 ' 74 ' 75 ' 76 ' 77 ' 78 ' 79 '

YEARLY AVERAGE OF MONTHLY DATA

YEAR

TO YEAR PERCENT CHANGE
BAR CHART IS C P I
LINE IS Ml-ADJUSTED MONEY SUPPLY LA3GED 2 YEARS

56 ' 57 '58 ' 58 T




'61 '62 ' 63 ' 64 ' 6S ' 66 ' 67 ' 68 ' 69 ' 73 ' 71 ' 72 ( 73 '

YEARLY AVERAGE OF MONTHLY DATA

77 ' 78 r79 ' 83 '

140
Exhibit 4C plots the percentage changes in the CPI measured
between the same months from one year to the next and the
Federal funds rate—the overnight inter-bank interest rate.

It

shows that monthly movements in the Fed funds rate occur very
closely together with changes in the inflation rate measured
from the same month a year ago.

This indicates that even short-

term interest rates are very powerfully affected by immediate
past inflation.




CHART 4C

•14

CPI, PERCENT CHANGE YEAR TO YEAR
vs
FEDERAL FUNDS RATE CATJN.Y. BANKS)

13-

-13

12-

-12

11-

-11

10-

6-

-8

7-

-7

S-

4-

-3

66




67

66

78

71

72

'

73

74

76

'

77

78

78

UJ
O
CK
UJ
O.

142
CHART 5.

This chart graphs year over year inflation

(vertical

axis) against yearly unemployment averages (horizontal axis).
The top panel graphs the two concurrently,

the middle panel

lags unemployment 1 year, and the bottom panel lags inflation
one year.
The concurrent panel (5A) reveals that the so-called Phillips
curve is unstable.

On average, the trade-off was highly

favorable from 1954 to 1965 but has worsened significantly
since then.
The middle panel (5B) reveals much the same story.

Specifically,

for an arbitrarily selected unemployment rate, the rate of
inflation the following year is much higher today than it was
in the 1950s and early 1960s.
Finally, the evidence plotted in the lower panel (5C) reinforces
this story.

As indicated here, there is even some tendency for

accelerating inflation to be followed by higher unemployment.
Viewed together with Chart 1, these three panels show that unemployment cannot be reduced by accelerating money growth and
inflation.

The result of faster money growth is higher inflation

and perhaps also a rise, albeit ephemeral, in unemployment.







143
CHART *A

INFLATION vs UNEMPLOYMENT (NEITHER LAGGED)
YEARLY AVERAGE OF MONTHLY DATA
7

12.0 •

1

S.S

1954 - 1978

6.5

UNEMPLOYMENT RATE

INFLATION vs UNEMPLOYMENT (LAGGED 1 YEAR)
YEARLY AVERAGE OF MONTHLY DATA
1954 - 1978

3.S

4.5

5.5
6.5
UNEMPLOYMENT RATE

CHART 5C
SCATTER DIAGRAM
i2.a i
INFLATION (LAGGED 1 YEAR) vs UNEMPLOYMENT
YEARLY AVERAGE OF MONTHLY DATA
1954 - 1978

a.a

S.S
6.S
UNEMPLOYMENT RATE

6.5
CAM

144

[Whereupon, at 5:10 p.m., the hearing was adjourned.]




o