View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Available online at www.sciencedirect.com
SC IEN CE

ELSEVIER

DIRECT*

Journal of Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

Journal of
MONETARY
ECONOMICS
www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase

The quest for prosperity without inflation^
Athanasios Orphanides
Division o f Monetary Affairs, Board o f Governors o f the Federal Reserve System, Washington,
DC 20551, USA
Received 15 November 2000; received in revised form 12 July 2002; accepted 9 September 2002

Abstract
In recent years, activist monetary policy rules responding to inflation and the level of
economic activity have been advanced as a means of achieving effective output stabilization
without inflation. Advocates of such policies suggest that their flexibility may yield substantial
stabilization benefits while avoiding the excesses of overzealous discretionary fine-tuning such
as is thought to characterize the experience of the 1960s and 1970s. In this study I present
evidence suggesting that these conclusions are misguided. Using an estimated model, I show
that when informational limitations are properly accounted for, activist policies would not
have averted the Great Inflation but instead would have resulted in worse macroeconomic
performance than the actual historical experience. The problem can be attributed, in large
part, to the counterproductive reliance of these policies on the output gap. The analysis
suggests that the dismal economic outcomes of the Great Inflation may have resulted from an
unfortunate pursuit of activist policies in the face of bad measurement, specifically,
overoptimistic assessments of the output gap associated with the productivity slowdown of
the late 1960s and early 1970s.
Published by Elsevier Science B.V.
JEL classification: E3; E52; E58
Keywords: Great inflation; Arthur Bums; FOMC; Activist monetary policy; Taylor rule; Prudent policy
rule; Real-time data; Potential output; Full employment

*1 have benefited from presentations at the Bank of England, Reserve Bank of Australia, Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Camegie-Mellon University, meetings of the NBER and the Econometric
Society, and conferences organized by the Sveriges Riksbank in Stockholm, the European Central Bank
and Center for Financial Studies in Frankfurt, and the Swiss National Bank in Gerzensee. I would also
like to thank Milton Friedman, Jordi Gali, Paul DeGrauwe, Thomas Jordan, Don Kohn, Yvan Lengwiler,
Dave Lindsey, Ben McCallum, Allan Meltzer, Dick Porter, Bob Rasche, Bob Solow, Lars Svensson, John
Taylor, and Raf Wouters for useful comments. The opinions expressed are those of the author and do not
necessarily reflect the views of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
E-mail address: athanasios.orphanides@frb.gov (A. Orphanides).
0304-3932/03/$-see front matter Published by Elsevier Science B.V.
doi: 10.1016/S0304-3932(03)00028-X



634

A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

1. Introduction
In his 1957 lectures on Prosperity Without Inflation, Arthur Burns eloquently
explained that economic policies since the enactment of the Employment Act of 1946
had introduced an inflationary bias in the US economy which had “marred our
nation’s prosperity in the post-war period” (Burns, 1957, p. v). By promoting
“maximum employment”, the Act encouraged stimulative policies which, by
prolonging expansions and checking contractions, resulted in an upward drift in
prices. Bums called for an amendment to the Act, “a declaration by the Congress that
it is the continuing policy of the federal government to promote reasonable stability
of the consumer price level” (p. 71). Such an amendment, he thought, would lead to a
greater policy emphasis “on the outlook for prices and on how reasonable stability of
the price level is to be sought” (p. 72). And a reasonable price stability objective
“could go a considerable distance in dissipating the widespread belief that we are
living in an age of inflation and that our government, despite official assertions and
even actions to the contrary, is likely to pursue an inflationary course over the long
run” (p. 71). With the appropriate policies, Bums concluded, “[Reasonably full
employment and a reasonably stable price level are not incompatible” (p. 88).
Bum’s proposed price stability amendment was never enacted. Instead, with the
beginning of the 1960s, economic policy was further refined placing even greater
emphasis on achieving and maintaining full employment. As Arthur Okun later
explained: “The revised strategy emphasized, as the standard for judging economic
performance, whether the economy was living up to its potential rather than merely
whether it was advancing” (Okun, 1970, p. 40). The resulting activist stabilization
policies were not meant to be inflationary. “Ideally,” Okun added, “total demand
should be in balance with the nation’s supply capabilities. When the balance is
achieved, there is neither the waste of idle resources nor the strain of inflation
pressure” (p. 40).
Despite the best of intentions, the activist management of the economy during the
1960s and 1970s did not deliver the desired macroeconomic outcomes. Following a
brief period of success in achieving reasonable price stability with full employment,
starting with the end of 1965 and continuing through the 1970s, the small upward
drift in prices that so concerned Burns several years earlier gave way to the Great
Inflation. Amazingly, during much of this period, from February 1970 to January
1977, Arthur Burns, who so opposed policies fostering inflation, served as Chairman
of the Federal Reserve. How then is this macroeconomic policy failure to be
explained? And how can such failures be avoided in the future?
Many excellent studies have identified a number of contributing factors to this
experience.1 By several accounts, blame for the failure is to be attributed to the
discretionary management of the economy during the period.2 One potential
1Any short listing of studies on this question is bound to be incomplete. The fascinating recent historical
accounts provided by De Long (1997), Hetzel (1998), and Mayer (1999) provide extensive bibliographies.
2An alternative is to point towards unfavorable supply shocks, especially in energy prices. Barsky and
Kilian (2002), present convincing evidence that such shocks cannot account for the inflation experience.




A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

635

explanation relies on the possibility of a built-in inflationary bias in monetary policy
either because of political concerns or a fundamental dynamic inconsistency
problem. Another explanation suggests incorrect economic analysis which may have
led to a futile attempt to exploit a non-existent long-run inflation-unemployment
tradeoff.3 Both arguments lead to a simple and direct conclusion. Had monetary
policy followed a rule focused towards maintaining reasonable price stability, the
Great Inflation would have been averted. A concern, however, is that such policies
may result in undesirable employment and output volatility.
Along these lines, simple activist monetary policy rules have been advanced as a
means of achieving effective output stabilization consistent with near price stability.
These rules prescribe that policy respond to inflation and the level of economic
activity. Advocates of such policies suggest that these rules provide a flexibility that
yields substantial stabilization benefits but simultaneously maintain a discipline
which avoids the excesses of overzealous discretionary fine-tuning such as is thought
to characterize the U.S. experience of the 1960s and 1970s. (See, e.g. Taylor, 1999a,
b). A critical aspect of these activist rules is the emphasis they place on the level of
economic activity in relation to a concept of the economy’s potential when resources
are fully employed. Unfortunately, as a practical matter, the measurement problems
associated with the concept of full employment present substantial difficulties. Thus,
while the strategy of attempting to stabilize the economy at its full employment
potential could be highly successful if the full employment objective were properly
measured, in practice, these activist strategies may not yield the desired results.
In this paper, I use the historical experience of the United States economy from 1965
to 1993 to examine the quantitative significance of this concern. Using an estimated
model, I contrast the performance of the economy under the assumption that
policymakers could have implemented activist stabilization rules with perfect
information with the performance under the realistic alternative that policymakers
could have relied only on the information available to them in real time. The
experiment suggests that the stabilization promise suggested by activist policy rules is
indeed illusory. As I demonstrate, the apparent improvement in economic performance
that these rules suggest over actual experience can be attributed to unrealistic
informational assumptions regarding the knowledge policymakers can reasonably have
about the state of the economy at the time when policy decisions are made.
Although these results might appear paradoxical at first, upon reflection they
should be rather obvious. The emphasis on the output gap in activist policy rules
suggests that the premise underlying these rules does not to differ fundamentally
from the rationale underlying the activist discretionary policy of the 1960s and
1970s. Elaborating on the importance of the output gap at that time, Okun observed
that “the focus on the gap between potential and actual output provided a new scale
for the evaluation of economic performance, replacing the dichotomized business
cycle standard which viewed expansion as satisfactory and recession as unsatisfac­
tory. This new scale of evaluation, in turn, led to greater activism in economic policy :
As long as the economy was not realizing its potential, improvement was needed and
3Sargent (1999) presents a novel interpretation which brings together elements of both explanations.




636

A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

government had a responsibility to promote it” (1970, p. 41). Despite outward
appearances, the activist discretionary policies advocated and practiced during the
1960s and 1970s and the activist policy rules advocated more recently share
fundamental similarities.
The problem leading to the Great Inflation, then, was not necessarily that policy
relied on discretion rather than a rule but that policy was inappropriately activist,
much like an inappropriately activist policy rule would have suggested at the time.
Examination of the information available to policymakers at the time clarifies the
source of the problem. The bulk of the error can be traced to the mismeasurement of
potential output. Examination of the evolution of estimates of potential output and
resulting assessments of the output gap during the 1960s and 1970s suggests that the
problem could be attributed in large part to the productivity slowdown which,
though clearly seen in the data with the benefit of hindsight, was virtually impossible
to ascertain in real time.
In retrospect, this danger should perhaps have been given greater attention. After
all, the information problem was and remains one of the most significant
impediments to successful stabilization policy. Further, the information problem
has been central in monetarist arguments favoring non-activist policy rules over
activist discretionary policies long before the Great Inflation. As early as 1947,
Milton Friedman (1947) had sharply criticized reliance on unrealistic informational
assumptions for Keynesian prescriptions to maintain “full employment” . More
recently Allan Meltzer (1987) has again illustrated how lack of information limits
short-run stabilization policy. As Karl Brunner summarized: “Discretionary
management ultimately fails to deliver, even with the best of intentions, on its
promise. The information problem separates the reality and the rationale of
discretionary management by an unbridgeable gulf.” (Brunner, 1985, p. 12).
The likely policy lapse leading to the Great Inflation, therefore, can be simply
identified. It was due to the overconfidence with which policymakers believed they
could ascertain in real-time the current state of the economy relative to its potential.
The willingness to recognize the limitations of our knowledge and lower our
stabilization objectives accordingly would be essential if we are to avert such policy
disasters in the future.

2. Policy rules
Over the past several years, a number of authors have examined the stabilization
performance of simple rules for monetary policy.4 A characteristic family of such
rules prescribes that the short-term nominal interest rate, R t, be set so that its
deviation from a neutral setting, R*, responds linearly to the deviation of a variable
serving the role of an intermediate target, X u from a predetermined desired path, X f.

R ' - ] $ = e(x, - xf).
4McCallum (1999), Taylor (1999a), Clarida et al. (1999) provide surveys of this literature.




(i)

A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

637

Starting with the large-scale model comparison studies reported in Bryant et al.
(1993), many authors have investigated rules of this type in depth. A strategy that
was found to yield particularly promising outcomes in the Bryant, Hooper and
Mann volume was to target the sum of inflation and output deviations from their
desired levels. A number of later studies confirmed the advantages of such a strategy
and also examined the performance of a more general family of rules which allows
for possibly different responses to inflation and output deviations from their desired
levels. These rules respond linearly to the output gap, y h defined as actual minus
potential output expressed as a fraction of potential output, and deviations of the
annual rate of inflation,
from a desired target, 7c* : 5
R t - R * = y (n ° -n * ) + Syt.

(2)

As is well known, the family of rules (2) nests an intriguing parameterization due
to Taylor (1993) which describes the contours of actual policy in the United States
since the late 1980s reasonably well. Taylor’s rule uses the sum of the annual
inflation rate, 7r?, and the natural real rate of interest, r*, as a proxy for the neutral
nominal interest rate,
=

+<

(3)

and substitutes the parameters r* = n* = 2, and y = S = 1/2.
Taylor rule:
R t = 2 + nat + 0 . 5 « - 2) + 0.5*.

(4)

Subsequent research, importantly many of the studies in Taylor (1999c), has shown
that a modified version of this rule with a stronger response to the output gap may
have even better stabilization properties. This modification is:
Revised Taylor rule:
R t = 2 + v* + 0 . 5 « - 2) + 1.0*.

(5)

A detailed description of the historical performance of the original and revised
parameterizations of the Taylor rule is provided by Taylor (1999b).
The macroeconomic performance of the U.S. economy over the recent period
when Taylor’s rule successfully describes the contours of interest rate settings has
been remarkably good by historical standards. As a result of both this apparent
success and the promising findings from the simulation studies, it has been tempting
to associate good macroeconomic performance with setting policy based on the
Taylor rule and even associate deviations of the federal funds rate from such rules as
policy “mistakes” . Taylor (1999b) identifies two episodes of such policy “mistakes”
since the mid 1960s: the “excessive monetary ease of the late 1960s and 1970s”, and
the “excessive monetary tightness of the early 1980s” (p. 321).
5A number of authors, including Ball (1997), Clarida et al. (1999), Orphanides and Wilcox (1996),
Rotemberg and Woodford (1999), Svensson (1997) and Woodford (1999), have shown how reaction
functions related to (2) can be reconciled with optimizing central bank behavior in the absence of
informational problems.




638

A. Orphcutides I Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

A potential difficulty in assessing the validity of such conclusions is that the
retrospective policy evaluations upon which they are based rely on unrealistic
informational assumptions. One problem, in particular, is that, as specified,
these rules incorrectly assume that the policymaker has accurate information
regarding the current values of inflation and the output gap when setting the interest
rate. In fact, however, both inflation and the output gap are measured with
considerable noise that should be taken into account in constructing an accurate
depiction of realistic policy alternatives. Most importantly, the measurement of the
economy’s productive capacity—a necessary element for computing the output
gap—presents notoriously complex problems whose understanding is absolutely
critical for evaluating activist stabilization strategies.6 To address this issue, let ft%
and y t denote the policymaker’s observations regarding the annual inflation rate and
the quarterly output gap, respectively, when decisions are made. In practice,
policymakers recognize that the information they possess in real-time is imperfect
and subject to revision. Following Orphanides (2003a), let x t denote the noise in the
observation of the true rate of inflation, ift , and z t the noise in the observation of the
true output gap, y t\
%at = ftat + x t,
y t = y t + ztRewriting (2) to conform to what is actually known at the time the policy decision is
made about inflation and output gives:
R t - R * = y (ft°-n * ) + 8yu

(6)

where R* = r* + ft?. Written in terms of the true measures of inflation and the gap,
the interest rate policy corresponding to rule (6) is:
Rt -R * =

- 7i*) + 6yt - ((1 + y)xt + Szt) .
^

1 V ...
noise

*

(7)

This equation reveals the nature of the information problem. Setting the federal
funds rate in reaction to the output gap and inflation, as the rules in (2) suggest,
introduces inadvertent deviations into policy choices from what the policymaker
would have liked to do had the policymaker known the true underlying measures

6Several authors, including Estrella and Mishkin (1999), Orphanides (2001), McCallum (1999) and
McCallum and Nelson (1999) have recently discussed this problem at length. Orphanides (2003a) and
Smets (2002) have shown explicitly how the efficient choice of the response coefficients y and 6 in a policy
rule such as (2) is distorted once the uncertainty regarding the measurement of the output gap is
incorporated in stochastic simulation comparisons. Orphanides and van Norden (2002) detail the
pervasiveness of the output gap measurement problem across alternative estimation methods. A number
of other issues, including model mispedfication and parameter uncertainty may pose additional related
difficulties that could also complicate retrospective evaluations. Several recent papers including, Levin
et al. (1999), Sack (1998), Onatski and Stock (1999) and Williams (1999), have illustrated aspects of these
problems.




A. Orphanides I Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

639

of inflation and the output gap. The resulting undesirable movements in the interest
rate that feed back to the economy through the noise terms could adversely influence
macroeconomic performance. For instance, a policymaker attempting to follow the
Taylor rule may at times inappropriately ease policy in response to a perceived
opening of the output gap only to discover, perhaps many years later and after
inadvertently fueling inflationary pressures in the economy, that the perception upon
which the original policy easing was based was false.
Consequently, a proper examination of the historical performance of the economy
that evaluates outcomes had the Federal Reserve counterfactually followed
the activist stabilization policies prescribed by rules (2), needs to take into account
the noise in the underlying data. Only after accounting for the presence of such
informational limitations and only if the properties of activist policies such as
the Taylor rule continue to obtain once these practical limitations are accounted for
can the conclusions regarding the desirability of such policies be confidently
entertained.

3. An estimated model of the U.S. economy
In order to perform the counterfactual simulations necessary to compare
policy outcomes under alternative informational assumptions we need a structural
model of the economy. To some extent, the comparisons are conditional on the
specification of the model as well as the underlying assumptions regarding
its structure. And for the results to be informative, the model should fit the
historical data reasonably well. With these considerations in mind, I rely on a three
equation system of the economy which can be interpreted as a mildly restricted
structural vector autoregression (VAR) estimated with four lags using quarterly
data. The two key variables describing the state of the economy are the quarterly rate
of inflation, nt, and the output gap, y t. The third variable is the policy instrument, the
federal funds rate, f u but since in my simulations this is determined by an imposed
policy rule, only the equations for inflation and output require estimation. I estimate
the following process for the output gap:
4

4

/= i

i= i

4

(8)
and the following process or inflation:
4

4

i=i

i= 0

(9)
In estimating these equations, I impose two additional restrictions in order to
enforce the classical dichotomy. First, to ensure that only sustained changes in real
interest rates (and not nominal rates) can have a sustained influence on output, I




640

A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

impose the restriction
V\ +
t/f = 0. Second, I impose the accelerationist
restriction Y^= \ a? = l.7
Finally, as with any empirical model of this nature, the Lucas critique of
econometric policy evaluation is a source for concern. This would hinder
comparisons of alternative policies that are drastically different from the actual
historical policy. Fortunately, as will become evident, the alternative policies we need
to consider are such that it would not be implausible for the public to consider them
as stochastic realizations from a fixed distribution of policies. Therefore, as Sims
(1998) explains, counterfactual simulations of a model of this nature remain useful
for policy evaluation.
I estimate the model with quarterly data from 1960:1 to 1993:4 using data
available as of 1994:4. Inflation reflects the quarterly change of the GDP deflator, in
percent. The output gap is the difference between actual real output and potential
output measured as a fraction of potential output, also in percent. Although more
recent data on output and the output deflator are available from the Commerce
Department, 1994:4 marked the latest series for historical potential output data that
was publicly available from the Federal Reserve when this study was completed. As
one of my central objectives is to rely exclusively on information available to the
Federal Reserve for comparisons, I restrict attention to this data.8
The estimated model is similar to the semiannual model in Orphanides (2003a)
and the quarterly model in Rudebusch and Svensson (RS) (1999). Two important
properties of the model for monetary policy are the cost of disinflation and the
sensitivity of output and inflation to changes in the federal funds rate. The implicit
sacrifice ratio is about three and a half, which is similar to the ratio in the RS model
and also to that reported by Mauskopf (1995) for the Federal Reserve’s MPS
model.9 To examine the interest sensitivity of output and inflation, I computed the
dynamic responses of these variables to a two-year tightening of the federal funds
rates by 100 basis points. By the end of the second year, output is about a percentage
point below a baseline that does not reflect the tightening, and inflation about half a
percentage point lower. Finally, implicit in the output equation specification is an
estimate of the equilibrium real interest rate, r* = —&o/(2i=i
The point estimate
of 2.1 percent is close to the average ex post interest rate for the estimation sample,
7Imposing these two additional restrictions serves two useful purposes: It greatly simplifies the
evaluation of alternative policies by separating the choice of a long-run inflation target, n*, from the
evaluation of alternative policy rules which influence the stochastic performance of the economy. And,
perhaps more importantly, it conforms with views central bankers express in discussing the formulation of
monetary policy. See e.g. Blinder (1996), Yellen (1996) and Meyer (1998). There are, however,
longstanding theoretical and empirical issues regarding the classical dichotomy that have not yet been
resolved. Orphanides and Solow (1990), and King and Watson (1994), respectively, present some of these
theoretical and empirical issues.
8In a sense, I treat the data available at the end of 1994 as reflecting the “truth” regarding historical
inflation and the output gap. Of course, I recognize that this is only approximately correct.
9Direct comparisons with the new Federal Reserve model (FRB/US) are not immediate. The FRB/US
model allows a wide range of implicit sacrifice ratios which span the point estimates in the MPS, RS and
the model I employ here. Reifschneider et al. (1999) present some illustrative simulation results based on
the FRB/US model.




A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

641

2.2, and conveniently close to the two percent equilibrium real interest rate
assumption reflected in the Taylor rule.

4. The promise of activist stabilization policy
To demonstrate the stabilization promise of following activist policies under the
heroic assumption of perfect information regarding the state of the economy, I
perform dynamic counterfactual simulations of the model starting with 1965:4 and
ending in 1993:4. To perform a simulation with the Taylor rule, I recursively use the
rule (4) and the estimated Eqs. (8) and (9), with the historical values of all variables
up to 1965:4 serving as initial conditions. That is, for each quarter t, I use the lagged
simulated values of/ , n and y together with the estimated residuals for the quarter, ut
and eu to obtain simulated values for f u nt and y t. Similarly, to perform the
simulation with the Revised Taylor rule, I repeat this process using rule (5) instead of
rule (4).
The results are shown in Fig. 1. The top and middle panels show the results for
inflation over four quarters, and for the output gap, respectively. The bottom panel
plots the federal funds rate minus the annual rate of inflation shown in the top panel.
This proxy for the real federal funds rate conveniently summarizes the stance of
monetary policy. In each panel, the solid line denotes the actual historical evolution
of the variable shown from 1966 to 1993. The dashed line indicates the
counterfactual alternative if policy were to follow the Taylor rule with perfect
information and the dotted line the counterfactual alternative corresponding to the
Revised Taylor rule.
The figure unambiguously confirms the promise of following these activist rules.
From the top panel, had either of these rules been followed (assuming always that
this could be done), the problem visible in the actual path of inflation would have
been avoided. To be sure, the commodity price shocks and oil shocks of 1973 and
1979 are still visible in the simulated counterfactual paths of inflation. But inflation is
successfully stabilized around the two percent target and only exceeds five percent
briefly at the end of 1974, compared with the eleven percent rate in the actual data.
Comparing the two activist rules, the revised version performs marginally better but
the difference is small relative to the improvement in performance that either of the
two activist rules indicates relative to the actual history of inflation. As well, the
simulations confirm that actual inflation since the late 1980s has been nearly identical
to what the simulations based on the Taylor rule would imply.
Equally impressively, the middle panel confirms the promise of these activist rules
with regard to stabilizing output. The two simulated paths are clearly less volatile
than the actual output gap. Only in 1975 and 1976 would the counterfactual policies
have induced more severe contractions than actual history, and this would have been
an entirely appropriate response to the inflation situation resulting from the
unfavorable shocks in 1973 and 1974. As well, had either variant of Taylor’s rule
been followed, the recession of 1982 would have resulted in an output gap smaller
than three percent (in absolute value) whereas in reality the output gap was more




642

A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663
Inflation

Output Gap

Fig. 1. Promise of activist stabilization rules. Dynamic simulations assuming no misperceptions in the
measurement of inflation and the output gap. All data in percent. Actual reflects information at the end of
1994. The output gap is the difference between real output and potential output, measured as a fraction of
potential output. Inflation is the rate of change in the implicit output deflator over four quarters. The solid
and dashed vertical lines denote NBER business cycle peaks and troughs, respectively.




A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

643

than twice as large. And the bottom panel confirms the two policy “mistakes” during
this period: Actual policy was systematically easier during the 1960s and 1970s and
tighter during the early 1980s than either of the two rules would have suggested in
the simulation.
Indeed, based on such promising results, it is rather tempting to conclude that
activist stabilization policies following a rule such as Taylor’s perform remarkably
well. But are these apparent remarkable outcomes real?

5. The reality of activist stabilization policy
5.1. Information in real-time
The greatest difficulty associated with attempting to reconstruct counterfactual
simulations based on realistic information is the need to recover the information
upon which policymakers could actually base their decisions in real-time. Using this
information, the counterfactual simulations can then be designed to provide the
parallel simulated paths of both the actual and perceived inflation and output had
policy actions followed a different path from historical decisions.
From 1965 to 1993, the period of interest, the FOMC held regular scheduled
meetings either two or three times in every quarter and occasionally had additional
unscheduled conference calls to discuss possible policy actions. To simplify the task
at hand, and since the frequency of my data is quarterly, I concentrate on just one
FOMC meeting per quarter, the one corresponding as closely as possible with the
middle month of the quarter. For each of these meetings, I rely on information that
was available from the production of the Board of Governors staff analysis of the
economic situation just prior to the meeting. The Greenbook, which is distributed to
FOMC members by the staff a few days before each meeting, provides a valuable
source for this information. As explained in Orphanides (2003a,b), all the necessary
information to reconstruct inflation and the output gap in real-time for the 1980s
and 1990s is available from Federal Reserve documents. For the earlier period,
however, reconstructing the data is somewhat more involved. While the Greenbook
provides real-time information on nominal and real output from which I can
complete a time-series of real-time inflation measures, I have not been able to recover
a complete time-series for potential output estimates from Federal Reserve sources.
This limitation is not a reflection on the availability of the series at the Federal
Reserve, however. Indeed, in discussing the process employed in the analysis of the
economic outlook while he was Governor at the Federal Reserve during the late
1960s and early 1970s, Maisel (1973) lists the potential output series as one of the key
macroeconomic variables associated with the development of the staff forecasts.10
Further, discussion of output gap measures appears in the FOMC Memorandum of
Discussion throughout this period.
10 Governor Maisel’s account is particularly valuable in this regard as he joined the Board in June 1965
and was instrumental in the introduction of formal forecasts at the Federal Reserve later that year.




644

A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

From those occasions when quantitative measures of the output gap appear in the
Memorandum of Discussion or the Greenbook, I was able to confirm that
throughout the 1960s and 1970s these measures were based on the Council of
Economic Advisers estimates of potential output. Indeed, from 1961 until 1981 the
Council regularly produced and updated estimates of potential output and for a
number of years these estimates were considered (in fact referred to) as the “official”
estimates. The starting date for the availability of these data was not accidental.
Data on the gap between actual and potential output were first presented by the
Council of Economic Advisers during the first appearance of president Kennedy’s
Council before the Joint Economic Committee on March 6, 1961.11 (Heller et al.,
1961). By June 1961, the Council’s measures of the output gap had already been
employed in staff presentations regarding economic developments at the Federal
Reserve and appeared in FOMC discussions.12 Indeed, from 1968 to 1976 the
Council estimates were “officially” treated as data, updated and published every
month by the U.S. Department of Commerce together with actual output data.
Further, for 1980 and 1981 when I can compare records of the real-time output gap
from the Federal Reserve to the “official” measures published by the Council, the
two series match, as expected. Based on this information, I rely on the real-time
Council potential output estimates to complete my time-series of the real-time output
gap available to policymakers.
The top and middle panels of Fig. 2 show the real-time and final data for inflation
and the output gap. These data provide time series of estimates for x t and zt9 the
noise in inflation and the output gap measures faced by policymakers in everyquarter from 1965:4 to 1993:4 and form the basis for the realistic policy rule
simulations that follow.
As is evident from the figure, the mismeasurement in these series is not trivial. For
inflation, deviations between the real-time and final data often exceed one percentage
point, especially in the first half of this sample. As well, the real-time data appear to
understate the final inflation estimates somewhat during the 1970s. But the
mismeasurement of inflation appears to be a relatively minor issue when compared
to the mismeasurement of the output gap. Comparing the real-time and final series
on the output gap reveals systematic one-sided measurement errors. Output gap
mismeasurement, of course, reflects two types of errors. The first source is errors in
the measurement of actual output. Although such errors are at times substantial,
they are comparable in magnitude to errors in the measurement of inflation and
cannot account for the magnitude of the mismeasurement shown in the figure.
Rather, the bulk of the problem is due to errors in the measurement of potential
output. As is now evident, real-time estimates of potential output severely overstated
11 The 1962 Economic Report o f the President provided a comprehensive discussion of the data. Okun
(1962), detailed the underlying methodology.
12Okun’s (1962) methodology for estimating potential output and the resulting Council estimates were
adopted rather quickly by many, including Federal Reserve economists. Characteristic of this is the fact
that the only other paper in the session of the 1962 American Statistical Association Meeting where Arthur
Okun presented his analysis was an investigation of the full employment budget surplus using the Council
concepts by Robert Solomon of the Board of Governors (Solomon, 1962).




A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

645

Inflation

Output Gap

:
A/nv

1 V.
i

i

i

1

/
1

~

,J

1
[ikM--'

1

1

/
/ /
\ J fj
\\
i
\ i
>/

------'
i
i

1
1
1
1
X L X J U__ 1__ 1__ 1__ 1__ 1__ 1__ L

i i i i i r r

\ 1
\*

/
/

itt

/ ' \ \f
\ Y

\\

^

=

1
1
1
1
1
i ii

* /
/

*

r v
\ !

:
_

-1.................... M l 1 1 1 LU..LLI 1

_

>
v

“

1“
1
1
1
1
1
.1

i i i i

1
1
1
1
1
L 1
\
1
V1

Real-Tiime
Final

111111111

--------I --------

1966 1968 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994
Output Gap Change

Fig. 2. Real-time misperceptions. Real-time data reflect information as of the middle of the quarter
shown. Final data reflect historical information with data available at the end of 1994. See also notes to
Fig. 1.




646

A. Orphanides I Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

the economy’s capacity relative to the recent estimates, in this sample. The resulting
error in the measurement of the output gap, although already substantial at the
beginning of the sample in 1965, worsened significantly during the early and mid
1970s before gradually improving later on. (In Section 7, I provide a detailed
accounting of the forces that contributed to this massive error.)
An important element in the mismeasurement of the output gap is that it is highly
serially correlated. As a result, errors in estimates of the level of the output gap are
more pronounced than corresponding errors in the difference of the output gap. To
illustrate this, the bottom panel of the figure plots the annual difference of the output
gap (Aay t = y t - y t- 4 ) using real-time and final data. The figure confirms that the
mismeasurement of this difference is considerably smaller than the mismeasurement
of the level of the gap. At the same time, the change is also correlated with the
business cycle suggesting that it may also serve as a simple real-time filter of the state
of the economy.

5.2. Simulations with noisy data
Next I reexamine the simulated performance of activist policy rules taking into
account the mismeasurement reflected in the actual data in Fig. 2. In parallel with the
earlier simulations, the counterfactual simulations based on the real-time data employ
the historical values of all variables up to 1965:4 as initial conditions and the
estimated residuals from Eqs. (8) and (9) from 1966:1 to 1993:4. But here, the
simulations keep track of two parallel concepts for inflation and the output gap:
The true simulated paths, obtained as in the simulations without noise from Eqs. (8)
and (9), and the perceived simulated paths which are obtained from the true simulated
values by substracting the historical mismeasurement, x t, and zt, shown in Fig. 2 as
the difference between the final and real-time series of inflation and the output gap.
Keeping track of the perceived simulated paths of inflation and the output gap is
needed because, by assumption, in these simulations the policymaker sets the interest
rate responding to the mismeasured perceived simulated paths of inflation and the
output gap, and not the true paths which would not be available in real-time.
Implicit in the simulations is the assumption that for the range of alternative policies
examined, the specific choice of policy would not significantly influence the
mismeasurement pattern in the data. This assumption exactly parallels that regarding
the usual invariance of the structural shocks of the model to the choice of policy.
The realistic simulation results for the two activist rules are shown in Fig. 3. Once
the real-time data imperfections facing policymakers are incorporated into the
analysis, the promising results regarding stabilization policy based on the Taylor rule
vanish. In particular, inflation in the 1970s is as high with the Taylor rule as actually
occurred. With the revised Taylor rule, inflation becomes significantly worse than
actual experience. But while the Volcker disinflation at least brought inflation under
control in the early 1980s, if policy had followed the Taylor rule, inflation would
have remained high for considerably longer and, with the revised Taylor rule, would
have remained in double digits into the 1990s. Not only would these activist policies




A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

647

Inflation

Output Gap

1966 1968 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994
Fig. 3. Reality of activist stabilization rules. Dynamic simulations incorporating real-time misperceptions
in the measurement of inflation and the output gap. See also notes to Fig. I.




648

A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

in a sense have produced the inflation of the 1970s, they would have greatly inhibited
the disinflation of the 1980s as well.

6. The great inflation
6.1. Two suggested interpretations
The counterfactual simulations based on the Taylor rule appear surprisingly useful
for understanding the path of inflation in the United States since 1965. Fig. 4
compares the path of actual inflation to the two counterfactual simulations based on
the original specification of the Taylor rule. Each of the two counterfactual
simulations offers a distinct interpretation of monetary policy since the mid 1960s.
The first interpretation, based on the simulation without noise, suggests that
inflation accelerated in the late 1960s and 1970s because policy must have deviated
from the sensible prescriptions suggested by the Taylor rule and was instead
systematically too easy. Following an abrupt reversal, policy became exceedingly
tight and engineered a harsh disinflation in the first half of the 1980s. Since then, it
appears that the economy has been more or less successfully stabilized much as it
would have been under the Taylor rule.
The second interpretation, based on the simulation with noise, suggests instead
that inflation accelerated in the late 1960s and 1970s because policy must have
actually followed a strategy indistinguishable from the Taylor rule! Belatedly
recognizing the inflationary consequences of this strategy, policymakers adopted a
policy that was appropriately tighter than the prescriptions suggested by the Taylor
rule in the first half of the 1980s.




Fig. 4. Inflation with the Taylor rule.

A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

649

Fig. 5. Then and now: Taylor rule with final and real-time data.

The two alternative readings of the history of policy decisions can be reconstructed
by comparing the actual path for the federal funds rate to the Taylor rule
prescriptions based on the real-time and final data for inflation and the output gap.
The results are shown in Fig. 5. Here, for each quarter, the dotted and dashed lines
show what the Taylor rule would have prescribed for the federal funds rate for that
quarter based on the actual historical inflation and output information for that
quarter. The dashed line reflects information available during the quarter the federal
funds rate was set (“then”), the dotted line reflects the final data (“now”). The solid
line shows the actual history of the federal funds rate. Surely, if policy is to be
evaluated based on information that is now available, the Taylor rule appears to
represent reasonable policy and indeed, two “mistakes” are evident by comparing
the dotted and solid lines in the figure. Policy was easier than the rule during the late
1960s and 1970s and tighter than the rule in the first half of the 1980s. But if policy is
to be evaluated based on information that was actually available when policy
decisions were made, a different conclusion emerges. This is evident by comparing
the dashed and solid lines in the figure. If anything, the policy “mistake” of the late
1960s and 1970s is that actual monetary policy “followed” the Taylor rule, too
closely! Rather than “follow” the Taylor rule, policy should have been considerably
tighter. Given the “mistake” of “following” the Taylor rule in the 1970s, the
deviation from the Taylor rule in the early 1980s and the policy tightening associated
with the Volcker disinflation was an appropriate response to the inflation problem
created by “following” the rule.13
13See Orphanides (2003b) for a comparison of policy before and after Volcker’s appointment as
chairman in 1979 drawing on real-time information and the policy record of the FOMC.




650

A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

6.2. A decomposition
The two alternative interpretations suggest that a useful accounting of the sources
of the Great Inflation may be obtained by comparing the actual path of inflation to
the path of inflation from counterfactual simulations based on the Taylor rule using
alternative information assumptions. Fig. 6 provides such an accounting.
Each line in the figure shows the difference in inflation between a baseline
simulation and an alternative path. The baseline is always the counterfactual
simulation based on the assumption that policy could follow the Taylor rule with no
informational limitations. The solid line, reflects the difference between actual
inflation and the baseline. As can be seen, this difference increases almost
continuously from 1966 to 1979. At the peak of the discrepancy, in 1979 and
1980, actual inflation was about 7 percentage points higher than what a policy based
on the Taylor rule with perfect information could have delivered. The dashed line
reflects the difference between the baseline and a simulation that assumes that the
policymaker faced noise only with respect to the measurement of inflation. Based on
this difference, about one and a half percentage point of the discrepancy between
the actual inflation and the baseline Taylor rule simulations during the 1970s can be
attributed to inflation noise. The dash-dot line reflects the difference between the
baseline and a simulation that assumes that the policymaker faced noise only with
respect to measurement of the output gap. At its worst, in the late 1970s, the
mismeasurement of the output gap squarely contributed about 5 percentage points
to the inflation discrepancy.

Fig. 6. Decomposition of simulated inflation differences. The solid line indicates the difference between
actual inflation and the simulation without noise. Each of the remaining lines shows the difference between
the path of inflation from the simulation without noise and a simulation with the noise indicated.




A. Orphanides I Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

651

Finally, the dotted line reflects the difference of the simulation based on the real­
time data, including both inflation and output gap noise from the baseline. That is, it
reflects the discrepancy between the Taylor rule as it could have been actually
implemented and the infeasible implementation that assumes away the noise in the
data. Comparing the solid and dotted lines reveals that only about one-half
percentage point of the inflation discrepancy at its peak in 1979-1980 can be
attributed to policy deviations from the Taylor rule, as could have been implemented
in practice. The rest simply reflects the unintended consequences of policy
responding to noise.
Following the decomposition further into the 1980s is also illuminating. By 1987, a
discrepancy of five percentage points relative to the baseline would have remained,
had policy followed the Taylor rule with the imperfect data. In contrast, by adopting
the strategy associated with the Volcker disinflation actual policy resulted in a path
of inflation that eliminated the discrepancy with the baseline simulation and restored
stability in the economy.
6.3. Avoiding the output gap
As the decompositions above illustrate, the key source of the policy failure during
the 1970s, and flaw in the pursuit of activist policies is that they prescribe that the
FOMC react to the level of underutilization or overutilization of the economy’s
potential. But alternative policies can be designed that avoid reacting to the level of
the output gap altogether. To examine whether such alternatives could have
improved upon the instability that the activist policies examined earlier would have
induced over this period, I provide a brief comparison with two alternatives that are
based on the specification of the original Taylor rule (4):
Inflation targeting rule:
Ui = 2 + ir? + 0 . 5 « - 2 )

( 10)

Natural growth targeting rule:
R t = 2 + < + 0 . 5 « - 2 + Aay t).

01 )

The first of these simply drops the output gap from the rule, whereas the second
replaces the gap with its change over four quarters.14 To be sure, given the already
established promise of activist stabilization policies, one would expect that
these rules would not have performed as well over history, had information been

141 call this a natural growth targeting rule because, as a simple regrouping of the variables indicates,
7t° - it* 4- Aay — rf —n* where na = i f + Aaq is the growth of nominal income over four quarters and
7 i* = n* + Aaq* the natural growth rate of nominal income over the same period. This rule can be viewed
as an operational version of nominal income targeting. See the working paper version of this study for a
more detailed discussion. Orphanides (2003b), and Orphanides et al. (2000) present policy rule evaluations
that allow comparisons of versions of the Taylor and natural growth targeting rules under alternative
informational assumptions.




652

A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

perfect. Nonetheless, they might have performed satisfactorily in the presence
of concerns regarding informational problems, avoiding potentially large errors.
Rules with these characteristics might be termed prudent. In the case of the
natural growth targeting rule, in particular, since the change in the gap, Aay u may
serve as a simple filter of real activity that is less sensitive to measurement problems
than the level of the gap itself (as seen in Fig. 2), this rule may retain some of the
stabilization benefits suggested by the Taylor rule in the absence of information
problems.
To compare the performance of these two alternative rules, I performed
simulations parallel to the ones described in Sections 4 and 5 for the Taylor and
revised Taylor rules. As anticipated, the inflation and natural growth targeting
rules do not share the high degree of stabilization performance of the two
activist rules under perfect information. On the other hand, they also avoid the
Great Inflation experience associated with those rules when measurement errors
are taken into account. Fig. 7 provides a summary. (The working paper version of
this study (Orphanides, 2000) presents detailed results.) To compare performances,

LU
CO

2

DC
Q.
(0
0

"3
Q.

3
O

Inflation RMSE
Fig. 7. The performance of alternative policies: 1966:1 to 1993:4. T and R denote the original and revised
Taylor rules, respectively. I denotes inflation targeting and N natural growth targeting. The solid squares
and diamonds indicate infeasible outcomes from simulations assuming perfect information. The blank
squares and diamonds indicate the realistic outcomes from simulations reflecting the actual information
that would be available when policy decisions were made. The star indicates the actual performance of the
economy over the simulation period.




A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

653

for each simulation I compute the root mean square errors of the simulated final
output gap and of the simulated final inflation deviations from the assumed
two percent target from 1966:1 to 1993:4. To facilitate comparison of the
performance of the alternative rules, the concentric circles could be read as
iso-loss surfaces for a policymaker who places equal weight of output and inflation
stabilization.
Comparing the rules without noise (solid squares and diamonds) confirms that the
two activist rules perform better than the two prudent rules. In simulation, both the
Taylor and the revised Taylor rule yield both better inflation and better output
stability than either the natural growth rule or the inflation targeting rule. With
perfect hindsight, the revised Taylor rule dominates by producing best results for
both inflation and output stability. However, once we account for the noise in the
data, these outcomes are reversed. As shown by the blank squares and diamonds,
the revised Taylor rule actually yields the worst performance in this case and both
the Taylor rule and revised Taylor rule in fact do far worse than the actual
performance of the economy, shown by the star.

7. The mismeasurement of the output gap
Since the real-time mismeasurement of the output gap appears to be a key factor
of the policy failure associated with the Great Inflation, a more detailed examination
of its sources is warranted.
One possibility is that potential output and the resulting output gap were
constructed in a way that would render them inconsistent with price stability. If that
were the case, then surely policymakers should have never incorporated this data
into any analysis without making an appropriate adjustment. But this was not
necessarily the case. As Okun (1962) emphasized in implementing the methodology
he proposed for measuring the output gap, “[t]he full employment goal must be
understood as striving for maximum production without inflationary pressure”
(emphasis added).
As is evident in retrospect, however, the underlying assumptions built into the
estimates of potential output during the late 1960s and 1970s were seriously
misguided. Two key assumptions, in particular, proved overly optimistic. The first is
the level of unemployment compatible with full employment, what later became
known as the “natural rate” of unemployment or the “non-accelerating-inflation
rate” of unemployment (NAIRU). When the Council first produced their estimates
of potential output in 1961, it was assumed that four percent was a reasonable
estimate. Given the experience of the past thirty years, this now surely appears to
have been unreasonably low. Unemployment averaged 6.3 percent from 1966 to
1993. But four percent was an entirely reasonable assumption to make in 1961.
Indeed, four percent was considered a rather pessimistic assessment of the American
economy’s full employment potential at the time. Unemployment had averaged just
4.5 percent from 1947 to 1960—not a period of remarkable economic stability—and




654

A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

was under 4 percent in several of these years, without much discernible inflation from
the current perspective.15
The second crucial assumption necessary for assessing the economy’s full
employment potential concerns the rate of labor productivity improvement and its
translation to the natural growth rate of output. Okun’s calculations in 1961
suggested that the experience of the U.S. economy in the post-war period was
consistent with potential output growing at a rate of 3 \ percent per year. But the
absence of any inflation during the first half of the 1960s and an apparent increase in
the rate of growth of the labor force led to upward revisions of the estimates of
potential output growth. By the time Arthur Okun became chairman of the Council
in the final year of the Kennedy-Johnson administrations potential output was
assumed to grow at four percent. But again, these estimates were, if anything,
believed to be conservative.15
As overly optimistic as the assessment of the economy’s potential proved to have
been, the mismeasurement of potential output during the 1960s was almost trivial
relative to the subsequent errors. Emboldened by the growth performance of the
economy during the 1960s, Nixon’s Council adopted a 4.3 percent potential output
growth estimate from 1970 to 1973, exactly at the time when, as was recognized later
on, productivity was slowing down. But in a way, 1970 marked a change in the tide.
Over the next several years, the issue became one of questioning the optimism
reflected in the assessment of the economy’s potential and a gradual downgrading of
expectations. In a series of steps, estimates of both the natural rate of unemployment
and the natural growth of output became gradually more pessimistic and the
Council’s estimates of potential output were brought down. Fig. 8 shows the effects
of these changes on historical estimates of the output gap based on the data
published in the Economic Report of the President in 1973, 1976, 1977 and 1979,
compared to the current data. (For each year, the estimates shown were published in
January or February of that year, so the data upon which the analysis underlying the
potential output estimates would have been as of the end of the previous year.) The
most striking element in these revisions is that despite moving in the right direction
throughout the decade, the mismeasurement of the output gap worsened during the
first half of the decade. This, of course, is the expected pattern of errors in the face of
15The fact that the full employment level of unemployment was presumed to be half a percentage point
below the average unemployment over the several years prior to 1961 with fairly stable prices might
suggest at least some unwarranted optimism. But this would be the case only from a modern perspective
based on a linear accelerationist Phillips curve. However, at the time, it was believed that the Phillips curve
in the U.S. economy was non-linear with the implication that greater macroeconomic stability alone would
reduce the average rate of unemployment—other things being equal. And, of course, increased stability at
full employment was the ultimate objective. Baily (1978) and more recently Laxton et al. (1999) have
reexamined the implications of this argument with a non-linear accelerationist Phillips curve.
^Contemporaneous academic studies based on alternative methodologies, suggested an even brighter
outlook for the economy. Thurow and Taylor (1966) estimated a 4.7 percent potential output growth for
the second half of the 1960s, and although more conservative, Black and Russell (1969) still concluded that
there was “a clear acceleration in the rate of growth of potential GNP in the late 1960s to a rate slightly
above 4 percent.” (p. 75). As Clark (1979) observed about alternative estimates of potential output: “All
the results were similar to the CEA estimates or even somewhat higher” (p. 141).




A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

655

Fig. 8. The evolution of history during the 1970s: Output gap measurement. The dark solid line indicates
the historical series for the output gap with data available at the end of 1994. Each of the thin solid lines
shows the historical series for the output gap based on data available in the first quarter of the year shown.

an unexpected slowdown in potential output growth that is only gradually
recognized over time.17 By 1976, the Council recognized that a major revamping
of its estimates was required. The resulting revision was presented in the 1977
Economic Report of the President. The new estimates provided a drastic correction
to the mismeasurement problem. The size of the revision was substantial. It implied
that output for the previous year (1976) was four percentage points closer to
potential than the earlier estimates had suggested.18
17As early as 1972 the Council recognized that the confidence with which they could provide estimates
of the economy’s potential had deteriorated but this did not result in any significant progress. The energy
crisis in 1973 and 1974 compounded the problem and raised the degree of uncertainty regarding the
measurement of potential output. Not only additional complexities regarding the treatment of energy
became apparent, the underlying national income accounts data became less reliable as well. The problems
with the underlying GNP data led the Office of Management and Budget to establish The Advisory
Committee on GNP Data Improvement which provided a comprehensive evaluation of the underlying
data and led to a subsequent effort to improve their measurement (United States Department of
Commerce, 1977). Of course the Council was intimately aware of these difficulties, especially after a
member of the Advisory Committee, Alan Greenspan, became Chairman of Ford’s Council.
18Clark (1977), presented details of the underlying methodology for the Coundl’s new estimates
following a request made at the Congressional Hearings. As could be anticipated following such a major
downward revision in the estimates of the nation’s productive capacity, Council Chairman Greenspan
faced an unusually intense questioning by the members of the Joint Economic Committee. As large as it
was, this revision only corrected about half of the problem, as it appears from today’s perspective. But
again, this could not have been known in 1977. Although at the time it was widely recognized that the 1976




656

A. Orphanides I Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

The most fascinating element of the Council’s 1977 analysis, however, was the
identification of the sources of the mismeasurement of the output gap since the late
1960s. One source was not difficult to identify. The rate of unemployment consistent
with full employment had drifted upwards during the decade. Another important
source of mismeasurement, however, was a dramatic drop in labor productivity
growth. As noted in the 1977 Report, while productivity growth in the private sector
had averaged 3.3 percent per year from 1948 to 1966, between 1966 and 1973 the
productivity growth rate had fallen to only 2.1 percent and if anything, appeared to
have fallen even further after 1973. Since it was not yet possible to accurately
separate the cyclical influence of the 1974 recession from the additional suspected
long-run trend change in productivity after 1974, most of the Council’s analysis
concentrated on the pre-1974 slowdown.
In retrospect, much of the systematic mismeasurement of the output gap estimates
could be squarely attributed to a delay in recognizing that the underlying trend of
labor productivity had shifted unfavorably in the late 1960s. And that was in 1977.
By 1979, the additional data validated the suspicion of a further slowdown after
1973, leading to the last revision in the estimates shown in Fig. 8. Estimates of
productivity growth subsequently fell even further, so much in fact that most current
discussions concentrate on the slowdown after 1973 without mention of the
deterioration of the late 1960s and early 1970s.19 Unsurprisingly, this disappointing
performance led to the further revisions in potential output that now suggest that,
despite their best efforts, the Council’s revisions even during the late 1970s were far
too optimistic after all.
In summary, the systematic mismeasurement of the economy’s productive
capacity during the late 1960s and 1970s is hardly surprising. After all, accurate
measurement would have required information about what is appropriately known
as Solow’s residual, following R. Solow’s (1957) seminal growth accounting
decomposition. The accuracy of our measurement, then, should reflect the accuracy
of what M. Abramovitz (1956) aptly characterized as a “measure of our ignorance” .

8. The view from Constitution Avenue
Given the obvious difficulties associated with striving to achieve an ill defined full
employment objective and given the Federal Reserve’s undisputed responsibility for

(footnote continued)
estimates of potential output overstated the economy’s capacity, the extent of the overstatement was a
matter of controversy and the Council’s new estimates were well within the range of reasonable
alternatives. Thus, while Rasche and Tatom (1977) provided somewhat lower estimates of potential output
than the Council’s, Perry (1977) suggested somewhat more optimistic estimates. Unsurprisingly, none of
these estimates was anywhere as pessimistic as the present perspective would suggest would have been
appropriate.
19 Compare, for instance, Chart 3 in the 1977 Report which suggests a single break in productivity after
1967 with Chart 2-5 in the 1996 Report which suggests instead a single break after 1973.




A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

657

maintaining price stability, a natural question is whether FOMC actions during the
late 1960s and 1970s could have been guided by an activist stabilization objective.
A superficial answer would be in the affirmative. As Fig. 5 suggests, Federal
Reserve policy could indeed be characterized as consistent with an activist strategy
indistinguishable from following a rule such as Taylor’s, based on the aggregate
activity and inflation measures available to the FOMC in real-time. On the other
hand, a closer look at the record also suggests that the FOMC recognized the
difficulties associated with the measurement problem and did not necessarily intend
to be excessively activist. Apparently, the dangers associated with the pursuit of
activist policies were simply not sufficiently appreciated. Of particular interest in this
regard are the views of Arthur Bums who became Chairman of the Federal Reserve
Board in February 1970. A respected academic who had served as Chairman in
Eisenhower’s Council, and arguably the nation’s leading expert on business cycles at
the time, Bums joined the Board with impeccable credentials and considerable
knowledge of at least some of these problems as he had frequently come across them
earlier during his career. In a largely forgotten study he published in 1936, Bums
(1936) had in fact already discussed the theoretical impossibility of accurately
measuring potential output. And in 1966, he explained in detail the difficulties
inherent in interpreting the Council’s estimates of the output gap, anticipating
correctly much of the confusion associated with the supply issues that only became
widely understood after the 1973 oil crisis.
However, the Council’s calculations of the gap between actual and potential
output, quite apart from being fragile, cannot be treated as measures of demand
shortages. If aggregate output falls short of its potential, the gap may have
nothing to do with any weakness of demand. It may instead reflect obstacles on
the side of supply or a failure of the constituent parts of demand and supply to
adjust sufficiently to one another. Since the structure of our economy keeps
changing, these changes as well as difficulties on the demand side must be
reckoned with in a scientific diagnosis. (Burns, 1966, p. 28)
Despite his awareness of these difficulties, however, Bums believed that he had a
solid grasp of business cycle and inflation dynamics.
In retrospect, the policy mistakes of the 1970s arguably started with Burns’ very
first FOMC meeting, on February 10, 1970. The consensus at the Federal Reserve
during the previous year and leading to Chairman M artin’s last meeting was that the
main problem facing the economy was inflation and, consequently, the Committee
had tightened policy significantly during 1969. Coming from the National Bureau of
Economic Research, Bums was tuned into the cyclical indicators of the performance
of the economy and arrived at the Board with a great concern. A recession loomed
large on the horizon. And Bums strongly believed that if a recession had already
started, that would be sufficient to reverse the inflationary tendencies of the
economy, based on the experience of earlier recessions. As a result, he suggested that
the FOMC ease policy. The FOMC was split but eventually agreed to start easing
policy at that meeting and, in a number of steps, eased policy further later that year.




658

A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

The NBER later confirmed that a recession had indeed started in December of
1969. A peculiar feature of the 1970 recession, however, quickly became increasingly
difficult to interpret. Contrary to expectations, inflation kept creeping up. This
despite worsening unemployment, falling capacity utilization measures and an
opening of the output gap. Indeed, the gap, which had already turned negative in the
third quarter of 1969, remained negative through 1970 and into 1971. Something,
had gone terribly wrong.
In retrospect, of course, all is perfectly clear. The utilization measures were
exceedingly misleading. Despite the connotations associated with the NBER calling
this episode a recession, the behavior of the economy in 1970 looked more like a
somewhat bumpy landing from a state of unsustainably high economic activity to a
more or less normal state of affairs. In no quarter did the unemployment rate exceed
six percent. Surely, this was a disturbing figure for those associating full employment
with a four percent rate, but it is unremarkable from today’s perspective. And
contrary to the prevailing view at the time, output hardly fell below potential based
on what we now know. Of course, all these measures appeared very different then.
1970 must have been an extremely disturbing year for the new Chairman.
Unfortunately, by easing policy in 1970, the Federal Reserve missed the
opportunity to reap the benefits of the 1969 tightening to eradicate the increasingly
more virulent inflation. Even worse, Chairman Bums misinterpreted the causes of
the 1970 economic outcomes. In retrospect, the faulty assessment of the economy’s
productive capacity seriously misled him. He explained his predicament during a
Congressional testimony in July of 1971:
A year or two ago it was generally expected that extensive slack in resource use,
such as we have been experiencing, would lead to significant moderation in the
inflationary spiral. This has not happened, either here or abroad. The rules of
economics are not working in quite the way they used to. Despite extensive
unemployment in our country, wage rate increases have not moderated. Despite
much idle industrial capacity, commodity prices continue to rise rapidly. (Burns,
1971, p. 656)
A natural response to a situation interpreted as a change in the rules of economics
is to seek new remedies. In August 1971, with Bums’ encouragement, President
Nixon imposed price controls on the economy. Aside from proving to be bad policy
that did not resolve the inflationary situation, the price controls proved rather
unfortunate in that they distorted the very information that could be used to reassess
what was wrong with the underlying economic assumptions. An unintended sideefifect of the controls was to impede efforts that could have led the Council to
improve their “official” estimates of the economy’s potential. Consequently, to the
extent policy continued to be influenced in any way by the faulty measurement of
potential output and the uncertainty about the natural rate of unemployment, the
error was becoming worse. In a sense, bad policy and bad measurement were
reenforcing each other.
Going into 1973, policy was decidedly too expansionary and remained so for too
long. Despite an attempt to reverse course with tighter policy, inflation was headed




A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

659

to frustrating higher levels—even without an influence from the oil embargo which
came later, in November. In 1974, the Council succinctly summarized the success of
the various programs targeted at containing inflation and the outlook for the future
as follows: “Inflation seemed a Hydra-headed monster, growing two new heads each
time one was cut off.” (p. 21). But by then, the major policy errors had already been
committed.
Shortly after he left the Federal Reserve, Burns explained the role of
mismeasurement in precipitating the policy errors of the early 1970s. The first
element appeared in a rather circumspect paragraph in his aptly titled lecture “The
Anguish of Central Banking.”
In a rapidly changing world the opportunities for making mistakes are legion.
Even facts about current conditions are often subject to misinterpretation. ...
[After World War II], a broad consensus developed that an unemployment rate of
about 4 percent corresponded to a practical condition of full employment, and
that figure became enshrined in economic writing and policymaking. Conditions
in labor markets, however, did not stand still. ... The unemployment rate
corresponding to full employment is now widely believed to be about 5 1/2 or 6
per cent, and this year’s report of the Council of Economic Advisers appears to
concur in that judgment. But governmental policymakers, while generally aware
of what was happening in the labor markets, were slow to recognize the changing
meaning of unemployment statistics, whether viewed as a measure of economic
performance or as a measure of hardship. The Federal Reserve did not escape this
lag of recognition and, once again, I believe that other central banks at times have
made similar mistakes. (Burns, 1979, p. 17)
Plainly and justifiably, Bums was suggesting that the FOMC was in good
company when it incorrectly based policy on an incorrect natural rate assumption.
In a later speech, after first repeating the role of faulty measures of the natural rate,
he provided the final piece solving the puzzle:
A second major reason for the grave inflation that got under way in the late 1960’s
is the flattening out of the historical upward trend in output per man-hour of our
nation’s workshops. (Burns, 1981, p. 9)

9. Concluding remarks
Two lessons can be drawn from this historical journey. First, the dismal economic
outcomes of the Great Inflation could be attributed, at least in part, to an
unfortunate pursuit of activist policies in the face of bad measurement, specifically,
overoptimistic assessments of the output gap associated with the productivity
slowdown of the late 1960s and early 1970s. Second, and perhaps more important,
that in the face of informational problems, activist stabilization policies such as the
Taylor rule, may not accomplish the stabilization of inflation and output which are
often associated with them. Potentially, alternative strategies that do not rely on the




660

A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

level of the output gap may provide more robust benchmarks for policy analysis. To
be sure, the analysis here only offers an example of the difficulties in identifying
robust policy strategies. However, the results are also consistent with the lessons
from more detailed policy evaluation comparisons dealing with informational
problems, such as presented in Orphanides (2003a) and Orphanides et al. (2000). In
particular, these studies suggest that the appropriate degree of policy activism, as
measured by the efficient policy response to the real-time assessments of the output
gap, depends sensitively on its reliability, and also that avoiding the level of the
output gap appears to be a robust approach for guarding against serious
mismeasurement problems.
Although economics is often called the dismal science, many macroeconomists
appear to be, if anything, overly optimistic and cheerful about the prospects for
improving macroeconomic performance. Armed with models we know are imperfect,
having to design policies based on data that we know are at best incomplete and at
times exceedingly misleading, and lacking the means for controlled experiments,
many continue to search for the promise of improved macroeconomic stability. Such
efforts are always welcome. Expectations regarding the likely improvement in policy
design that might fruitfully result from such efforts, however, must be scaled down.
It is all too easy to be drawn back to the promise of excessively activist monetary
policy by the siren song of sustained prosperity without inflation. It is all too
tempting to dismiss the failed policies of the past as due to faulty analysis
and incompetence that we now know how to avoid. But upon closer examination,
strategies identified as new and improved guides for activist monetary policy
in recent years bear more similarities to the discredited policies of the past
than commonly recognized, and too close a resemblance to those policies for
comfort.
This is not to deny that activist policies may at times be entirely appropriate and
successful. That may be the case if and when a high degree of confidence regarding
our understanding of the workings of the economy is warranted. But such times
cannot be easily identified ex ante. A willingness to recognize our ignorance and
lower our stabilization objectives accordingly may then be the safest defense against
destabilizing fine-tuning.
At the deepest level, the failure of the macroeconomic policies of the 1970s and the
need for the dislocation of the early 1980s to restore monetary order were due to the
hybris that enough was known to perfect the economy’s performance. Arthur Burns
had already taught us this lesson in 1967 when he perceptively identified the true
origins of the Great Inflation:

And so we finally come to the agonizing question: why did the nation’s policy­
makers, who for years had succeeded so well in monitoring a business expansion
under difficult conditions, finally unleash the forces of inflation? Why did men
who showed the ability to profit from experience succumb to one of the oldest
weaknesses of government practice? One reason, I think, is that they were misled
by the very success that for a time attended their efforts. (Bums, 1967, p. 30)




A. Orphanides / Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

661

The continuing fallacy is to downplay the degree of our ignorance and at times
perhaps mistake the good fortune of the recent past for wisdom. Must we repeat
such errors before we learn to respect the limits of stabilization?

References
Abramovitz, M., 1956. Resource and output trends in the United States since 1870. American Economic
Review 46 (2), 5-23.
Baily, M.N., 1978. Stabilization policy and private economic behavior. Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity 1, 1-50.
Ball, L., 1997. Efficient rules for monetary policy. NBER Working Paper No. 5952, March.
Barsky, R., Kilian, L., 2002. Do we really know that oil caused the great stagflation? A monetary
alternative. In: Bemanke, B.S., Rogoff, K. (Eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2001. MIT Press,
Cambridge, MA.
Black, S., Russell, R., 1969. An alternative estimate of potential GNP. The Review of Economics and
Statistics 51 (1), 70-76.
Blinder, A., 1996. On the conceptual basis of monetary policy. Remarks at the Senior Executives
Conference of the Mortgage Bankers Association, New York, January 10.
Brunner, K., 1985. Monetary policy and monetary order. In: Monetary Policy and Monetary Regimes,
Center for Research in Government Policy and Business, Number CS-17, Graduate School of
Management, University of Rochester, Rochester, NY.
Bryant, R.C., Hooper, P., Mann, C. (Eds.), 1993. Evaluating Policy Regimes: New Research in Empirical
Macroeconomics. Brookings, Washington, DC.
Bums, A., 1936. The Brookings inquiry into income distribution and progress. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 50 (3), 476-523.
Burns, A., 1957. Prosperity Without Inflation. Fordham University, New York.
Burns, A., 1966. Aggregate or structural approaches to achieving employment act objectives. In:
Twentieth Anniversary of the Employment Act of 1946, Hearings Before the Joint Economic
Committee, Congress of the United States, United States Printing Office, Washington, DC.
Bums, A., 1967. First lecture. In: Bums, A., Samuelson, P. (Eds.), Full Employment, Guideposts and
Economic Stability. American Enterprise Institute, Washington, DC.
Bums, A., 1971. Statement before the Joint Economic Committee, July 23. (Reprinted in Federal Reserve
Bulletin, August 1971, pp. 655-662.)
Bums, A., 1979. The Anguish of Central Banking, The 1979 Per Jacobsson Lecture, Belgrade, Yugoslavia,
September 30.
Bums, A., 1981. Regaining a Stable Price Level. The Founder’s Day Address, Xavier University,
Cincinnati, Ohio, May 7. (AEI Reprint No. 124, August, 1981.)
Clarida, R., Gali, J., Gertler, M., 1999. The science of monetary policy: a new Keynesian perspective.
Journal of Economic Literature 37 (4), 1661-1707 December.
Clark, P.K., 1977. A new estimate of potential GNP. In: The 1977 Economic Report of the President,
Hearings before the Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States, U.S. Government
Printing Office, Washington, DC.
Clark, P.K., 1979. Potential GNP in the United States, 1948-80. Review of Income and Wealth 25 (2),
141-165.
Council of Economic Advisers, Various Years. Economic Report of the President, U.S. Government
Printing Office, Washington, DC.
De Long, B., 1997. America’s only peacetime inflation: the 1970’s. In: Romer, C., Romer, D. (Eds.),
Reducing Inflation: Motivation and Strategy. University of Chicago, Chicago.
Estrella, A., Mishkin, F., 1999. Rethinking the role of NAIRU in monetary policy: implications of model
formulation and uncertainty. In: Taylor, J.B. (Ed.), Monetary Policy Rules. University of Chicago,
Chicago.




662

A. Orphanides I Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

Friedman, M., 1947. Lemer on the Economics of Control. The Journal of Political Economy 55 (5),
405-416.
Heller, W., Gordon, K., Tobin, J., 1961. The American economy in 1961: problems and policies. In:
January 1961 Economic Report of the President and the Economic Situation and Outlook, Hearings
before the Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States, U.S. Government Printing
Office, Washington, DC.
Hetzel, R., 1998. Arthur Burns and Inflation. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 84
(1), 21-44 Winter.
King, R., Watson, M., 1994. The post-war U.S. Phillips curve: a revisionist econometric history. CamegieRochester Conference Series on Public Policy 41, 157-219.
Laxton, D., Rose, D., Tambakis, D., 1999. The U.S. Phillips curve: the case for asymmetry. Journal of
Economic Dynamics and Control 23 (9-10), 1459-1485.
Levin, A., Wieland, V., Williams, J., 1999. Robustness of simple policy rules under model uncertainty.
In: Taylor, J.B. (Ed.), Monetary Policy Rules. University of Chicago, Chicago.
Maisel, S.J., 1973. Managing the Dollar. W.W. Norton, New York.
Mauskopf, E., 1995. The Monetary Transmission Mechanism in the United States: Simulations Using the
Federal Reserve Board’s MPS Model. Financial Structure and the Monetary Policy Transmission
Mechanism, Basle, Switzerland: Bank for International Settlements.
Mayer, T., 1999. Monetary policy and the Great Inflation in the United States: The Federal Reserve and
the Failure of Macroeconomic Policy, 1965-1979, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
McCallum, B.T., 1999. Issues in the design of monetary policy rules. In: Taylor, J., Woodford, M. (Eds.),
Handbook of Macroeconomics. North-Holland, Amsterdam.
McCallum, B.T., Nelson, E., 1999. Performance of operational policy rules in an estimated semi-classical
structural model. In: Taylor, J.B. (Ed.), Monetary Policy Rules. University of Chicago, Chicago.
Meltzer, A.H., 1987. Limits of short-run stabilization policy. Economic Inquiry 25, 1-14.
Meyer, L., 1998. The Strategy of Monetary Policy. The Alan R. Holmes Lecture, Middlebury College,
Middlebury, Vermont, March 16.
Okun, A., 1962. Potential output: its measurement and significance. In: American Statistical Association
1962 Proceedings of the Business and Economic Section. American Statistical Association,
Washington, DC.
Okun, A., 1970. The Political Economy of Prosperity. Brookings, Washington, DC.
Onatski, A., Stock, J., 1999. Robust Monetary Policy Under Model Uncertainty in a Small Model of the
U.S. Economy. Manuscript, February.
Orphanides, A., 2000. The quest for prosperity without inflation. European Central Bank Working Paper
No. 15, March.
Orphanides, A., 2001. Monetary policy rules based on real-time data. American Economic Review 91 (4),
964-985.
Orphanides, A., 2003a. Monetary policy rules with noisy information. Journal of Monetary Economics 50
(3), this issue.
Orphanides, A., 2003b. Monetary policy rules, macroeconomic stability and inflation: a view from the
trenches. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, forthcoming.
Orphanides, A., Solow, R.M., 1990. Money, inflation, and growth. In: Friedman, B.M., Hahn, F.H.
(Eds.), Handbook of Monetary Economics. North-Holland, Amsterdam.
Orphanides, A., van Norden, S., 2002. The unreliability of output gap estimates in real time. Review of
Economics and Statistics 84 (4), 569-583.
Orphanides, A., Wilcox, D., 1996. The opportunistic approach to disinflation. Finance and Economics
Discussion Series, 96-24, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, May.
Orphanides, A., Porter, R., Reifschneider, D., Tetlow, R., Finan, F., 2000. Errors in the measurement of
the output gap and the design of monetary policy. Journal of Economics and Business 52 (1/2),
117-141.
Perry, G., 1977. Potential output and productivity. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, 11-47.
Rasche, R., Tatom, J., 1977. Energy resources and potential GNP. Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis
Review 59 (6), 10-23.




A. Orphanides I Journal o f Monetary Economics 50 (2003) 633-663

663

Reifschneider, D., Tetlow, R., Wiliams, J., 1999. Aggregate Disturbances, Monetary Policy, and the
Macroeconomy: The FRB/US Perspective. Federal Reserve Bulletin 85 (1), 1-19.
Rotemberg, J., Woodford, M., 1999. Interest-rate rules in an estimated sticky price model. In: Taylor, J.B.
(Ed.), Monetary Policy Rules. University of Chicago, Chicago.
Rudebusch, G., Svensson, L., 1999. Policy rules for inflation targeting. In: Taylor, J.B. (Ed.), Monetary
Policy Rules. University of Chicago, Chicago.
Sack, B., 1998. Does the Fed Act gradually? A VAR analysis. Finance and Economics Discussion Series,
98-17, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, March.
Sargent, T., 1999. The Conquest of American Inflation. Princeton University Press, Princeton.
Sims, C., 1998. The role of interest rate policy in the generation and propagation of business cycles: what
has changed since the ’30s? In: Fuhrer, J., Schuh, S. (Eds.), Beyond Shocks: What Causes Business
Cycles? Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Boston.
Smets, F., 2002. Output Gap Uncertainty: Does it Matter for the Taylor Rule? Empirical Economics 22 (1)
113-129.
Solomon, R., 1962. The full employment budget surplus as an analytical concept. In: American Statistical
Association 1962 Proceedings of the Business and Economic Section, American Statistical Association,
Washington, DC.
Solow, R., 1957. Technical change and the aggregate production function. Review of Economics and
Statistics 39 (3), 312-320.
Svensson, L.E.O., 1997. Inflation forecast targeting: implementing and monitoring inflation targets.
European Economic Review 41 (6), 1111-1146.
Taylor, J.B., 1993. Discretion versus policy rules in practice. Camegie-Rochester Conference Series on
Public Policy, Vol. 39, December, pp. 195-214.
Taylor, J.B., 1999a. The robustness and efficiency of monetary policy rules as guidelines for interest rate
setting by the European central bank. Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (3), 655-679.
Taylor, J.B., 1999b. An historical analysis of monetary policy rules. In: Taylor, J.B. (Ed.), Monetary
Policy Rules. University of Chicago, Chicago.
Taylor, J.B. (Ed.), 1999c. Monetary Policy Rules. University of Chicago, Chicago.
Thurow, L., Taylor, L., 1966. The interaction between the actual and the potential rates of growth. The
Review of Economics and Statistics 47 (4), 351-360.
United States Department of Commerce, 1977. Gross National Product Data Improvement Report,
Report of the Advisory Committee on Gross National Product Data Improvement, U.S. Government
Printing Office, Washington, DC.
Williams, J.C., 1999. Simple rules for monetary policy. Finance and Economics Discussion Series, 99-12,
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, February.
Woodford, M., 1999. Optimal Monetary Policy Inertia. Manuscript, January.
Yellen, J., 1996. Monetary policy: goals and strategy. Business Economics 31 (3), 40-44.