View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 11, Number 4—Fall 1997—Pages 189-197

Retrospectives

The Economics of Leon Hirsch
Keyserling
W. Robert Brazelton

This feature addresses the history of economic terms and ideas. The hope is
to deepen the workaday dialogue of economists, while perhaps also casting new
light on ongoing questions. If you have suggestions for future topics or authors,
please write to Joseph Persky, c/o Journal of Economic Perspectives, Department of
Economics (M/C 144), The University of Illinois at Chicago, Box 4348, Chicago,
Illinois 60680.

Introduction
Leon Hirsch Keyserling (1908-1987) obtained a B.A. in economics from Columbia University (1928) and a law degree from Harvard (1931). Although he
worked on a Ph.D. in economics at Columbia, absorbing the liberal economics
tradition for several years under Rexford Guy Tugwell (1932, 1935), Keyserling
never completed a Ph.D. As he often said in interviews, writing and lobbying for
various housing acts and the Wagner Act of the 1930s, together with the Employment Act of 1946, along with many other publications and official activities, got in
the way of completing his dissertation.
The list of Keyserling's activities is formidable. From 1933 to 1937, he was
legislative assistant to Senator Robert Wagner (D, New York), whom he aided in
drafting a $3.3 billion public works bill and the wage and collective bargaining
sections of the National Industrial Recovery Act in 1934; portions of the Amendment
to the National Housing Act (the Federal Housing Administration) in 1934-1935;

• W. Robert Brazelton is Professor ofEconomics, University of Missouri-Kansas City, Kansas
City, Missouri.




190

Journal of Economic Perspectives

portions of the Social Security Act and the National Labor Relations Act (Wagner
act) in 1935; and the U.S. Housing Act in 1937. He also found time to do research
on educational reforms at the Rockefeller Foundation in 1934, and to serve as a
writer for the Democratic Platform Committee under Senator Wagner for the reelection of Franklin Roosevelt, and other related Congressional testimonies, bills
and writings (Brazelton and Wehmeyer, 1989, p. 46). He then was acting administrator and general council to various housing agencies. He drafted the executive
order creating the National Planning Agency (forerunner of the Department of
Urban Development) in 1946, and helped to draft the General Housing Act of
1949. In 1978, he was draftsman for the Full Employment and Balanced Growth
Act, also known as the Humphrey-Hawkins Act.
One of the bills that Keyserling was active in pushing for, the Employment Act
of 1946, turned out to be central in bringing him to the attention of the economics
profession. That bill created the Council of Economic Advisers (CEA) in the White
House and established that the federal government had a role to play in the maintenance of high employment and price stability. Keyserling was appointed to the
original CEA by President Harry Truman in August 1946, and after the resignation
of the first chairman Edwin Nourse, who took the behind-the-scenes role of the
CEA so seriously that he refused to testify before Congress (Gates, 1968; Stein, 1996,
p. 8), Keyserling became the second chairman of the CEA in May 1950 (Stein,
p. 5). He served as chair until Truman left office in January 1953. He remained
active in public policy circles, especially as the author of 36 booklets for the Conference on Economic Progress (a privately funded "think tank" that published
studies related to Keyserling's views) and in his numerous testimonies before Congressional Committees—from 1953 until 1983.1 Keyserling died in 1987.
Keyserling's economic views remain interesting today. Keyserling gave the Truman administration its "economic philosophy" of the Fair Deal, as Alonzo Hamby
(1973, p. 295), a biographer of Truman, has pointed out. Clark Clifford (1993,
p. 85), who was in Truman's inner circle of advisors, referred to Keyserling (a fellow
member of the influential "Monday Night Group" which met in an apartment in
the Wardman Park Hotel), as the "intellectual of our circle, a respected but refreshingly controversial economist." Keyserling helped to create and shape the
CEA, one of the primary institutions through which the economics profession has
influenced economic policy. His period of highest political influence occurred at
a fascinating time for the economics profession, with the confluence of events like

1

The Conference on Economic Progress was a foundation based in Washington, D.C., and funded by
private contributors. Many of Keyserling's works for the conference were done with the assistance of his
wife, Mary Dublin Keyserling, an economist in her own right (Brazelton and Wehmeyer, 1989; Wehmeyer, 1996), who had served as Executive Director of the National Consumer's League, and later, as
an assistant to Eleanor Roosevelt and the Office of Civil Defense, and the Foreign Economics Administration of the Department of Commerce. After the Truman era, she served as a director of the Department of Labor's Women's Bureau during the Johnson years, and later, with the National Consumer's
League. Most of the works of Leon Keyserling and some of Mary Keyserling can be found at the Truman
Memorial Library, Independence, Missouri.




W. Robert Brazelton

191

the Depression and World War II coming together with the new Keynesian thinking.
Keyserling is a particularly vivid example of how one person combined an academic
background with a non-academician's emphasis upon pragmatism. Finally, it is fascinating to consider the contrast between Keyserling's views on economic growth,
countercyclical macroeconomic policy, and government economic policy in the
1946-53 period and the conventional wisdom of the 1980s and 1990s.

Keyserling's Economic Policies
As one would expect of someone coming to maturity during the Depression,
Keyserling's greatest concern was continued economic growth. As one would expect
of someone with academic training in economics at this time, he drew upon growth
theorists who were active during the 1940s such as Evsey Domar and Roy Harrod,
and he of course drew upon the then-recent insights of John Maynard Keynes.
Keyserling felt strongly that continual economic growth should be emphasized as
a chief policy goal, since he saw growth and social welfare and equity as tied together. Keyserling was a believer, despite the grim experience of the 1930s, that
the potential of the American economy was unlimited, and that with proper combination of countercyclical and long-term economic policy, economic growth could
produce and maintain abundance for all (Hamby, 1973, p. 301; Stein, 1996, p. 14).
The Triangle Economy

In thinking about growth policy, Keyserling at times looked upon the economy
as a triangle with three sides: consumption, investment, and government. As the
economy expanded, he believed that all three sides must grow in proportion and
that the goal of economic policy was to aid in this proportionate growth when
necessary. The idea of proportionate growth between C, I, and G is not a new or
radical concept in economics. As a matter of observation, it has often been noted
that the ratio of C, I and G changed little over the longer term, and that short-term
fluctuations in these variables were often associated with recession. In addition,
growth models of the time like those of Domar and Harrod pictured the economy
as expanding in this proportional way, with various interplays between the different
sectors.
The argument that the various sectors of the economy must grow in relation
to one another led in turn to thinking about the issues and tools of economic policy.
For example, trends in collective bargaining could affect wages, prices and profits.
Tax changes and the resultant deficit and the manner in which the debt is managed
would influence C, I and G and their growth rates in relation to one another (Brazelton and Wehmeyer, 1989, p. 209). In Keyserling's view, consumption demand
comes (primarily) from real wages (Keyserling, 1957, 1958a, 1964b, p. 91f; 1983,
p. 18); funds for investment come from current profits; and government spending
is determined by the political system. Thus, specific public policies to affect wages,




192

Journal of Economic Perspectives

profits and government spending could be helpful for keeping the sides of the
economy in proportion to one another.
To the modern eye, the triangle approach raises a number of immediate questions. For example, why doesn't the triangle have a side to represent the foreign
sector of the economy? Keyserling in the late 1940s and early 1950s could worry
less about U.S. exports than do economists today; not only was trade a smaller share
of the U.S. and world economies, but the United States was the world's unchallenged export power after having escaped the devastation of World War II. If Keyserling had had to worry about the trade balance, he might well have devoted more
time to the problem of stimulating exports as well.
At a more general level, how does one know the ideal proportions of such a
triangle economy? Might these proportions change over time? Without answering
these questions, how can one know whether there is a problem, or what policy will
best address the problem? Keyserling recognized that the shape of the triangle
would change over the business cycle and might change over the long-term, as well.
But as a pragmatic policymaker rather than a theorist, he was more interested in
using the triangle as a trigger for economic policy than in justifying it in theoretical
terms.
There is also some evidence that among the three interdependent sides of the
triangle, Keyserling saw consumption as the most important; not only as valuable
in itself, but as leading to the business profits which in turn generated investment.
An underlying implication here (to which we will return), is that investment is
determined by consumption levels, rather than by the amount of loanable funds.
To put it another way, it is consumption and its maintenance through sustained
growth in real wages that is most important to Keyserling, not profit rates by themselves (Keyserling, 1987; Brazelton and Wehmeyer, 1989, p. 213). This philosophy
also led Keyserling to put a policy stress on fiscal policy (taxes, expenditures, disposable income) rather than upon monetary policy, although he always believed
in the desirability of low interest rates.
Key Microeconomic Sectors

To Keyserling, the balance between consumption, investment and government
was a necessary condition for growth, but not a sufficient condition. His view of the
determinants of growth also identified the possibility that certain microeconomic
sectors might be in short or excess supply in relation to the rest of the macroeconomy. For example, if steel were in short supply in terms of growth needs, then steel
profits must be allowed to increase so as to increase the supply of steel, and public
policy might help accomplish this goal via selective monetary andfiscalpolicy tools,
as discussed below in terms of housing.
Indeed, in the years after World War II, housing was also seen as a key sector;
not only for its own sake, but because of the complementary goods such as furnishings and the resulting employment (and wages) that would help to maintain a high
consumption, high growth economy (Keyserling, 1972). Also, of course, housing
was a labor intensive industry whose expansion would increase the demand for




Retrospectives: The Economics of Leon Hirsch Keyserling

193

labor, capital, and infrastructure such as highways. Thus, it was a perfect selective
vehicle to encourage growth, especially in a recession. In terms of fiscal policy,
government expenditures could be directed selectively towards housing. In terms
of monetary policy, selective low interest rates could stimulate consumers' demand
for housing and housing loans, along with action by the Federal Housing Administration and Veterans Administration loan systems.
Business cycles will occur, whether from endogenous or exogenous causes. For
our purposes, let us separate the business cycle into two parts: the contraction and
the inflation. It has been obvious to most economists since Keynes that a contraction
can be due to inadequate demand and that expansionary fiscal and monetary policies can be a useful policy response. Keyserling agreed, although he would have
emphasized that the mechanism through which this policy occurred best and most
equitably was a boost in consumption that then stimulated profits and investment.
However, Keyserling's views on inflation were more unorthodox. The typical
aim of anti-inflationary policy is to decrease demand because inflation is viewed by
many as too much money chasing too few goods. However, Keyserling (1980)
viewed such tightening—say, through higher interest rates—as counterproductive,
for several reasons. Higher interest rates raise the cost of capital, which will reduce
profits or be passed on to the consumer. Also, as the tight money policy decreases
output, many individual firms will end up producing at less than the efficient scale
of production, so that the average cost of production rises, which again will reduce
profits or be passed along to the consumer. Thus, anti-inflationary policy increases
per unit cost, putting an upward bias on prices, especially as the real world is not
one of competitive markets, but rather, one of administered pricing (Keyserling,
1973; 1975; 1979; 1980). Moreover, increasing unemployment to control inflation
is hardly a way to maintain equity and to maximize social welfare.
Instead, Keyserling (1964a, p. 86f) proposed using selective credit controls or
interest rates to combat inflation. These selective measures would aim at holding
back sectors of the economy that were expanding too rapidly, but also at stimulating
areas of the economy that were lagging. The second may appear counterintuitive,
but these policies are based upon Keyserling's belief that shortages, administered
prices, and the slow growth of output are the main causes of inflation, not excess
demand per se (Brazelton and Wehmeyer, 1989, p. 235; Keyserling, 1964a; 1973;
1975; 1979; 1980).
This anti-inflationary policy may sound radical. But such eminent economists
as James Tobin (1986) have also pointed out that high interest rates increase business costs, increase the costs of the public deficit (and debt), increase unemployment, decrease present output, and discourage long-term growth. For Tobin
(p. 6), a more realistic anti-inflationary policy would call for "annual economy-wide
guideposts for wages and prices, with compliance induced by tax based rewards and
penalties. . . . " I n the same spirit, Keyserling also called at times for voluntary
wage/price guidelines (Brazelton and Wehmeyer, 1989, pp. 215-219).
Truman's biographer Alonzo Hamby (1973, p. 301) described Keyserling's beliefs on anti-inflationary policy in this way:




194

Journal of Economic Perspectives

Economic policy should concentrate less on prices as such and more on the
relationship between wages, prices and profits; it should work for the optimum
balance between consumer purchasing power and corporate income in order
to maintain full employment and expansion. The New Dealers, he believed,
had turned too frequently towards controls to fight inflation. Selective controls might be necessary at times, but the way to deal with inflation was to
enlarge productive capacity to meet demand. Fundamentally,. . . Keyserling
was willing to trade a mild inflation for growth. Such an alternative was greatly
preferable to the achievement of price stability via a "downward correction"
or recession. Higher unemployment and lower production solved few problems and worsened many more. "The idea that we can protect production
and employment by reducing them 'a little bit' is about as safe as the ancient
remedy of blood-letting."
Monetary Policy

Keyserling believed in fiscal policy more than in monetary policy, but realized
the effectiveness of both depending upon the circumstances. In his view, monetary
policy should therefore be based upon growth considerations, which meant keeping
interest rates low to encourage consumer spending and investment.
In the period 1946-52, the Federal Reserve kept interest rates low by agreeing
to buy government bonds at the prevailing rate of interest, thus providing extra
liquidity to the markets whenever interest rates went above the desired level. This
policy led to sizeable increases in the money supply, but few economists were concerned. After all, the economy was also growing rapidly, and at least prior to the
Korean War, without much inflation. Moreover, many economists were fearful after
World War II that the U.S. economy would return to the Depression.2 However,
after the beginning of the Korean conflict, and subsequent emergence of inflation,
the Federal Reserve reached an "Accord" with the Treasury no longer to peg interest rates on government bonds, and thus to let interest rates rise as an antiinflationary measure. To Keyserling, this was an error for all the reasons described
earlier: it decreased investment, current output, and future growth potential; it
increased per unit costs; and it penalized all sectors when only some were inflationary. Keyserling once told me that the Accord was one of our greatest policy
mistakes. However, Keyserling was not in favor of expanding the money supply or
the budget deficit without limit as a tool for expanding the economy; for example,
he was critical of such increases in the money as in the Weimar Republic and such
increases in the deficits as in the 1980s in the United States (Keyserling, 1964b,
1978; 1980; Brazelton and Wehmeyer, 1989, p. 315).
Agricultural Income Supports

Throughout this century, farm output has generally soared, while farm incomes have often struggled. Agricultural policies since the 1920s have addressed
2

For example, see Colander and Landreth (1996) for Paul Samuelson's expression of such beliefs at this time.




W. Robert Brazelton

195

the problem of farm income by legislating ways of keeping farm prices at a higherthan-market "parity" price level. This price parity policy has been maintained up
to the present, although in the mid-1990s, there has been some action in Congress
to alter the program.3 As Keyserling (1958c, p. 3; see also Brazelton and Wehmeyer,
1989, p. 142) pointed out, the higher prices led to overproduction, which in turn
led to greater downward pressure on farm incomes.
Keyserling accepted the view that farmers were competitive sellers facing oligopolists on the buyers' side of the market, and thus at a competitive disadvantage.
However, the appropriate solution was not to decrease competition between farmers with assured prices, but instead to subsidize the incomes of farmers. A similar
plan was suggested by President Truman's Secretary of Agriculture Charles Brannon (Keyserling, 1955b, 1957, p. 1, 1965; Brazelton and Wehmeyer, 1989, p. 142).
In Brannon's formulation, the farm family would receive income from their production of goods at market prices. Any difference between the income so generated
and the level of a decent income related to the farm would be made up through
an income subsidy. The market price would be free to fall, so the consumer would
pay the lower market price, not the higher (as now) parity price. Keyserling (1958c,
p. 5; see also Brazelton and Wehmeyer, p. 143) wrote of a program with "income
goals for farm families, designed to reward appropriate production adjustments
with a level of farm income and living standards moving gradually toward parity
with that of other Americans." Of course, the question of how to assure income
support without reducing incentives for efficiency gains remains a difficult one.
Indeed, this was an important reason for the defeat of the Brannon plan; even some
liberal and powerful Democrats such as Mike Monroney (D, Oklahoma) believed
it to be socialistic, and others, such as Senator Albert Gore, Sr. (D, Tennessee), had
introduced a price support system as an alternative (Creel and Burke, 1997, pp. 29,
87). The Gore alternative won.

Conclusion
From the perspective of the late 1990s, Keyserling's economics is a mix of the
intriguing and the controversial. It may sound odd to modern ears that he talks
about growth without much emphasis on technology and education. Targeting key
sectors of the economy is out of fashion today; even if selective credit controls might
have worked in the 1940s, one wonders how they would work in the modern financial world which permits nearly instantaneous arbitrage. Although a capitalist and
a believer in America's economic potential, Keyserling had an underlying suspicion
of market forces common to Depression-era policy makers. Thus, Keyserling
3

It may be worth noting that the United Kingdom followed an income support program in agriculture
until they were forced to abandon it and adopt a price parity program when they joined the European
Union. Food prices in the United Kingdom subsequently rose.




196

Journal of Economic Perspectives

(1966b; 1977; 1978; Hamby, 1973, p. 300) would develop a National Priority Budget
for full employment, which included fiscal and monetary policy and also guidelines
as to wages and prices and incentives or disincentives for various sectors. He saw
such planning as essential for maintaining the needed proportionate long-term
growth rates. Today, even among economists who believe that markets are often
far from being perfectly competitive because of imperfect information and other
issues, there is little support for the idea that a systematic federal economic plan
would improve the growth prospects of the economy.
However, even more market-oriented economists of today would generally applaud Keyserling's arguments for a policy focus on farm income rather than farm
prices, and admit that there is some truth in the view that the federal government
has a role to play in stimulating the economy in times of recession. Perhaps the
greatest controversy over Keyserling's views today is in the area of using monetary
policy for fighting inflation. Surely there is some truth in the view that even countercyclical policy should be designed to maximize output and welfare in the long
term. Even if selective credit and interest rate incentives may not be a workable
solution, might not modern economists usefully consider whether there are policy
tools that might hinder inflation while causing less injury to the entire economy
than an across-the-board rise in interest rates? Also, might there be a role for antirecessionary fiscal policy to subsidize, say, mass transit through either expenditures
or tax incentives as a replacement for the policies of previous decades that supported a full employment economy by aiding housing and highways? These are the
sorts of questions that Keyserling would be asking today.

References
Brazelton, W. Robert, A Critical Analysis of the
Growth Theories of Alvin H. Hansen and William J.
Fellner. Dissertation, University of Oklahoma.
Norman: 1961.
Brazelton, W. Robert, "A Survey of Some Textbook Misinterpretations of Keynes," Journal of
Post Keynesian Economics, Winter, 1980/81, 3,
256-270.
Brazelton, W. Robert, "Alvin Harvey Hansen:
Economic Growth and a More Perfect Society,"
American Journal of Economics and Sociology, October 1989, 48, 427-441.
Brazelton, W. Robert, and Willadee Wehmeyer,
Leon H. Keyserling and Mary Dublin Keyserling, Growth
and Equity: Over Forty Years of Economic Policies
and Analysis From Roosevelt, Truman to Bush.




Independence, Missouri, Truman Memorial Library, 1989.
Brazelton, W. Robert, "Hansen on Keynes,
Hayek, and Commons,"Journal ofEconomic Issues,
September 1993, 27:3, 940-48.
Clifford, Clark, Counsel to the President. New
York: Random House, 1991.
Colander, David C , and Harry Landreth, The
Coming of Keynesianism to America. Brookfield, VT:
Edward Elgar, 1996.
Creel, Von Russell and Bob Burke, Mike Moroney: Oklahoma Liberal. Edmond, Oklahoma:
University of Central Oklahoma Press, 1997.
Gates, Robert J., The Role of the First Council of
Economic Advisors. Master's Thesis, University of
Missouri-Kansas City, 1968.

Retrospectives: The Economics of Leon Hirsch Keyserling

Hamby, Alonzo L., Beyond the New Deal: Harry
S. Truman and American Liberalism. New York: Columbia University Press, 1973.
Keyserling, Leon H., National Prosperity Program
for 1955. Washington, D.C.: Conference on Economic Progress, 1955a.
Keyserling, Leon H., Full Prosperity for Agriculture. Washington, D.C.: Conference on Economic Progress, 1955b.
Keyserling, Leon H., Consumption Key to Full
Prosperity. Washington, D.C.: Conference on Economic Progress, 1957.
Keyserling, Leon H., Wages and the Public Interest. Washington, D.C.: Conference on Economic
Progress, 1958a.
Keyserling, Leon H., The Recession Cause and
Cure. Washington, D.C.: Conference on Economic Progress, 1958b.
Keyserling, Leon H., Toward a New Farm Program. Washington, D.C.: Conference on Economic Progress, 1958c.
Keyserling, Leon H., The Toll of Rising Interest
Rates. Washington, D.C.: Conference on Economic Progress, 1964a.
Keyserling, Leon H., Progress or Poverty. Washington, D.C.: Conference on Economic Progress,
1964b.
Keyserling, Leon H., Agriculture and the Public
Interest. Washington, D.C.: Conference on Economic Progress, 1965.
Keyserling, Leon H., A Freedom Budget for All
Americans. Washington, D.C.: Conference on
Economic Progress, 1966.
Keyserling, Leon H., The Coming Crisis in Housing. Washington, D.C.: Conference on Economic
Progress, 1972.
Keyserling, Leon H., The Scarcity School of Economics. Washington, D.C.: Conference on Economic Progress, 1973.
Keyserling, Leon H., Full Employment without Inflation. Washington, D.C.: Conference on Economic Progress, 1975.




197

Keyserling, Leon H., The Humphrey-Hawkins
Bill Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of
1977. Washington, D.C.: Conference on Economic Progress, 1977.
Keyserling, Leon H., Goals for Full Employment
and How to Achieve Them Under the"FullEmployment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978". Washington, D.C.: Conference on Economic Progress,
1978.
Keyserling, Leon H., "Liberal" and "Conservative" National Economic Policies and Their Consequences. Washington, D.C.: Conference on Economic Progress, 1979.
Keyserling, Leon H., Money, Credit and Interest
Rates: Their Gross Mismanagement by the Federal Reserve System. Washington, D.C.: Conference on
Economic Progress, 1980.
Keyserling, Leon H., How to Cut Unemployment
to Four Percent and End Inflation and Deficits by
1987. Washington, D.C.: Conference on Economic Progress, 1983.
Keyserling, Leon H. "Will it be Progress or
Poverty?" Challenge, May/June, 1987, 30:2, 3036.
Stein, Herbert, "A Successful Accident: Recollections and Speculations about CEA," Journal of Economic Perspectives, Summer 1996, 10,
3-21.
Tobin, James, "High Time to Restore the Employment Act of 1946," Challenge, May/June
1986, 29:2, 4-12.
Tugwell, Rexford, "The Principles of Planning and the Institution of Laissez Faire," American Economic Review, March Supplement, 1932,
22, 75-90.
Tugwell, Rexford, The Trend in Economics. New
York: Crofts, 1924 (republished, 1935).
Wehmeyer, Willadee, Mary Dublin Keyserling:
Economist and Social Activist. Kansas City: A dissertation for the University of Missouri-Kansas City,
1995.