View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

W ELFARE PROGRAMS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH AND
STABILITY
Clarence D. Long, professor of economics, and Selma Mushkin, re­
search associate, School of Hygiene and Public H ealth and D epart­
ment of Political Economy, Johns Hopkins University
The present report is concerned with the relation of health, educa­
tion, and social-security programs to long-term economic growth and
economic stability. I t is also concerned with the size and problems of
financing welfare expenditures—present and prospective.
L ong -T erm E conomic G row th

The social-welfare programs contribute to growth in a number of
different ways. They help to improve the quality of living and en­
hance economic well-being. They help to provide the scientific and
managerial talent on which private investment depends for stimulus
and support. They influence the numbers available for gainful em­
ployment and the productivity of the work force. They generate need
for a supporting volume of public investment and give stability to
consumer markets. Each of these facets of the interrelation of socialwelfare programs and economic growth is discussed briefly below.
Economic well-being and growth

Rapid economic development has been accepted as a goal. But
men attach value not only to accumulation of goods but also to the
purpose of that accumulation. Good health, education, and family
security are essential parts of the quality of living and of the objec­
tives of an expanding economy in a political democracy. In centuries
past there has been economic growth and at the same time high mor­
tality rates. There has been economic growth and high illiteracy
rates. B ut once having reached a level of economic production which
meets the basic necessities without long hours of work, the question
of priorities between purchases of education and of health services,
and of additional goods becomes a real one. Munoz-Marm, the Gov­
ernor of Puerto Rico who has provided the leadership which has
raised Puerto Rico from a slum to a symbol of progress, recently
proposed an Operation Serenity through which society “would use its
economic power increasingly for the extension of freedom, of knowl­
edge, and of understanding imagination rather than a rapid m ulti­
plication of wants.” 1 Operation Serenity deserves careful thought
lest in the concern with economic growth, the purposes of economic
growth are overlooked.
1 Q uoted In H e n ry v an Zile H yde.
R eports, M ay 1957, p. 425.
1010




P ublic H e a lth a n d th e S ocial Sciences.

P u b lic H e a lth

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

1011

The time for basic decisions on these priorities may have been some
years ago. However, decisions on welfare spending—notably in edu­
cation—have been made not in the market but in the political arena
of legislative decision. Decisions on health programs have waited,
in large part, on the progress of medicine, that is, on achieving effec­
tive therapies for specific diseases. Our present ordering of priorities
may be illustrated in many ways. Prof. Alvin Hansen has put it this
w ay:
Quality and social priorities at long last must concern us or
perish in the midst of material plenty. Just now we are starv­
ing our schools while we race up and down 6-, 8-, and 10-lane
highways in ever newer and longer cars.2
We turn out chrome-finish refrigerators, dishwashing machines, dry­
ers, home air conditioners, self-rolling vacuum cleaners to improve
family living, yet preventable childhood illness and infant deaths
still occur, and appropriations for maternal and child health services
are restricted.
There seems to be little doubt that better criteria are needed to de­
termine priorities in the public and private spheres so that a more
balanced set of social priorities can be attained. New institutional
approaches may be required, calling for the inventive skills of the
political scientists, sociologists, and economists working jointly to
this end.
Growth of private investment

Levels of education, health, and social security not only are im­
plicit components of a standard of living but they are means to eco­
nomic growth and to prevention of public dependency. One impor­
tant way the social-welfare programs contribute to economic growth is
by financing the education and training of scientific and managerial
manpower.
Scientific advance and invention are increasingly recognized as im­
portant supports for new private investment—the investment re­
quired to produce increased material goods. Progress in science and
invention, in turn, depends upon our national pool of scientific talent.
Current concern about a shortage of engineering and scientific person­
nel, about the inadequacies of education in mathematics and the
sciences in the public-school system, and about the qualified young
people who are not attending college grows out of the dramatic
achievements in applied science in the past decade. Governmental
research and development programs for military purposes more than
doubled after the Korean conflict, and further increases are projected
with the emphasis on nuclear weapons, guided missiles, and high-speed
aircraft. In industry, research and development activity has grown
rapidly and, as a concomitant, there has been rapid obsolescence of
existing products and development of new products. The new prod­
ucts require retooling and new installations and because of the greater
technical complexity of products and production methods, new de­
mands are created for engineers and scientifically or technically
trained personnel.
2 A lvin H. H ansen. S ta te m e n t in F ed eral T ax P olicy fo r E conom ic G row th an d
S tab ility . Subcom m ittee on T ax Policy of th e J o in t C om m ittee on th e Econom ic R eport,
84 th Cong., 1 st sess., 1956.




1012

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

P artly in response to labor-market conditions and prospective earn­
ings scale, and to G I and other educational aids, and partly in re­
sponse to higher family income levels, there has been a considerable
increase in the proportion of persons of college age attending college.
College enrollments increased from about 1.4 million at the begin­
ning of the school year 1939 to almost 3 million the beginning of the
school year 1956. The number of 18-year-olds in the population in
1957, however, was less than the number of same age in 1940. During
this time period, the population increased by 39 million.3 The low
number of additional young entrants into the labor force reflects the
depression birthrate. I t is from this present relatively small man­
power pool that immediate needs for additional professional, scien­
tific, and technical leadership must come, as well as other trained
personnel.
To provide the scientific manpower required for economic growth
and to make maximum use of intellectual resources curriculums will
have to be enlarged, the supply of trained teachers will have to be
increased, and there will have to be additional opportunities for college
training and advanced degrees.
Labor force ancl 'productivity

A second important contribution of social welfare programs to eco­
nomic growth results from their impact on the size of the effective
work force and on productivity. For centuries, economic and politi­
cal theorists have emphasized the cost to society of premature death.
In 1835, Quetelet, a Belgian mathematician, wrote:
In his early years, man lives at the expense of society; he
contracts a debt which he must one day discharge; and if he
dies before he has succeeded in doing so, his life will have been
a burden rather than a benefit to his fellow citizens * * *.4
Measures directed to reduce losses in productive capacity through pre­
mature death and disability essentially require no elaboration as a
part of governmental policy for economic growth.
Between 1900 and 1917, the overall age-adjusted death rates de­
creased at 1.074 percent per annum, a higher rate of decrease than in
the subsequent period from 1921-37. The decline in the first p art of
the century is largely attributable to environmental public health ex­
penditures. Through these expenditures diseases such as typhoid,
diarrhea, and dysentery, commonly transmitted by water, milk, food,
and by insects, were controlled by public-health programs.
Between 1938 and 1950 the average rate of decline in mortality was
more than twice that of the first part of the century. Acceleration
in reduction of mortality starting about 1938 is attributable mainly
to the dramatic use of the new drugs in treatment of conditions in­
volving infections. As the National Office of Vital Statistics con­
cluded in its analysis of mortality reports:
The increasing availability and use of these new therapeutic
products have all but closed the history of many infectious
diseases as causes of death.5
3 T estim ony of R alph C. M. F ly n t, D irecto r of H ig h er E d u c a tio n P ro g ra m s B ranch,
Office of E d u catio n before S ubcom m ittee on S pecial E d u catio n , U. S. H ouse of R e p re se n ta ­
tives, C om m ittee on E d u c a tio n an d L abor, A u g u st 12, 1957, pp. 5, 6.
4 Q uoted in Ren6 Sand. T h e A dvance to Social M edicine. S ta p le s P re ss, 1952, p. 584.
5 N a tio n a l Office of V ital S ta tistic s . V ita l S ta tis tic s of th e U n ited S ta te s, 1950, vol. 1,
p. 169.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

1013

W hat have these gains meant for labor force participation and
production ? Reduced death rates have resulted in a decline in separa­
tions from the labor force at all ages up to age 65. Despite the marked
delay in entry into the labor force by young people, and the earlier
exit from the labor force by those in the older age groups, the male
worker today puts in many more years of work than did his counter­
part 50 years ago.
These achievements can be traced to a wide variety of fac­
tors, paramount among which is the series of technological
advances which resulted in the great productivity increases
we have witnessed in the past 50 years. But it is difficult to
see how these factors would have operated without the two
long-term trends we have described above; that is, without
the manpower potential of our population at least approxi­
mately keeping pace with the other factors of growth.6
The improvement in health status reflected in lower mortality has
been one of a complex of factors facilitating the employment of
women, especially of women with children.
Improved health status also leads to an increase in effective labor
force participation by reducing the manpower force required to meet
the contingency of absenteeism. Illness of the employee or his family
is an important cause of absence from work, and reduction in such
absences is reflected in improved efficiency and in reduced work-foreo
requirements. Elimination of such absences would be the equivalent
of the addition of at least 1.3 million workers to the labor force.7
Industrial advance and urbanization have been accompanied by a
twofold change in occupational patterns and skills which direct atten­
tion to the public education system.s On the one hand it has enhanced
the importance of skills and of specialists in the sciences, engineering
and related technical fields. On the other hand, new production tech­
niques both in industry and agriculture have for some groups of
workers meant a depreciation, a downgrading, and a dividing of skills,
and old skills have become redundant.
Both types of occupational change suggest greater emphasis on
educational and related services and as a consequence, higher public
expenditures. As indicated earlier, the increased need for professional
workers and technicians requires more advanced training for a larger
number of people. Increasing mechanization and the growing diffu­
sion of automatic or semiautomatic, multipurpose and high-precision
machines require retraining opportunities, counseling services, and
financial aids to facilitate new training and mobility within a com­
munity and necessary movement to new areas when “uprooting”
occurs.
The strategic political and economic role in our society of the
educational system leads to concern not only with advanced education
6 Seym our L. W olfbein. T he L ength of W orking L ife. D ivision of M anpow er and
E m ploym ent, D ep artm en t of Labor. Ju ly 1957, pp. 5, 8 (processed).
7 E stim a te d from d a ta presen ted in George W. B achm an & A ssociates. H e a lth Resources
in th e U nited S ta te s. T he B rookings In s titu tio n , 1952, p. 273.
8 T he p rice of illite rac y a n d ig norance is high, especially in a society in w hich th e basic
concept is t h a t of self-governm ent an d w hich depends upon a n educated citizenry to use
th a t system o f go vernm ent an d m ake th e selections a n d choices presum ed. Econom ic
m o tiv atio n an d en terp rise, m oreover, req u ire a system of u n iv ersal ed u catio n to offer g re a te r
eq u ality of o p p o rtu n ity an d flexibility of m ovem ent in th e labor force.




1014

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

and vocational training but with the education program basic to these.
Deficiencies in elementary and secondary school facilities and in funds
to attract necessary teaching staffs pose urgent problems for communi­
ties and the Nation.
Thus far the discusison has dealt largely with aggregate numbers
in the work force and rates of production. Education and health
services and supporting income maintenance programs such as the
program of aid to dependent children and the survivors insurance
can help to improve the productive capacity of the low-income groups
and at the same time contribute toward the elimination of poverty and
future public delinquency.
Educational attainment is one of the most important factors deter­
mining occupational and income status. The 1950 census data, for
example, indicate a progressive increase in the average income with
increased education. Average annual income in 1949 of men 45 to 54
years of age who had no elementary schooling was $1,588; it was $3,112
for those who completed elementary school and $4,519 for those who
completed high school. Average income of college graduates was
$3,388 above the average for high-school graduates.9 Thus, invest­
ment in education appears to pay substantial dividends in earning
power required for self-support.
The interrelationships between income and health status are diffi­
cult to disentangle. Some of the infectious diseases, like tuberculosis
and rheumatic fever, have been closely identified with poor housing
conditions and low income. Low income may be associated with neg­
lect of conditions requiring medical attention. Low income also may
be the result of illness of the primary wage earner or of interruption
of earnings due to sickness of other family members. Sufficient ex­
perience has been accumulated in the administration of the publicassistance programs to suggest th at illness is an im portant factor in
public dependency. Dependency of between one-fourth and one-third
of the 6 million persons receiving public assistance is attributable at
least in p art to illness. Expanded efforts to prevent illness, to provide
early access to medical care, to improve disease therapy and rehabili­
tation services would reduce the long-run burden of illness on public
resources. A t the same time, these efforts would increase the effective
work force.
Public investment

A third way in which the social welfare programs contribute to
economic growth is by generating public investment opportunities.
Approximately one-third of new public works construction has been
for health and educational facilities, including in the health category
sewer and water facilities. W artime curtailment of public construc­
tion, postwar population increases, and technological changes in the
physical facilities associated with altered public services created large
deficits in building needs. Hospital and health facility requirements
are in the magnitude of $12 billion; expenditures required for wastetreatment works, both public and industrial, are estimated at about
$10 billion; to meet the existing deficit in elementary and secondary
school facilities would call for about $6 billion in construction out­
8 P a u l C. Glick a n d H erm an P . M iller, E d u c a tio n a l Level a n d P o te n tia l Incom e, A m eri­
can Sociological Review, J u n e 1956.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

1015

lays. Education, health, and water facilities support public functions
in these areas but they also are important to private plant location, as
even a summary review of industrial location surveys emphasizes.
Federal support of facilities for education and health services has
a direct bearing on the capacity to provide services. First, support of
needed construction releases for current operation some funds which
otherwise would go into buildings. Second, public aid for construc­
tion provides a stimulus to private giving to charitable educational
and health agencies. Concern about National Government controls
and interference has often directed national program proposals into
support of brick-and-mortar programs rather than support of teach­
ing staffs or hospital operation. However, services and facilities
and their financing are patently interrelated.
Decision on timing of public works involve not only the acceleration
or postponement of public works in the light of private investment
activity but also the timing and priorities of various types of public
works and the relative urgency of a public facility as a part of a serv­
ice program. Should new highways be built now, and schools later ?
Should the costs of cleaning up polluted waters be left to a future
generation as this one bears the burden of a depression and wartime
backlog of construction needs in education ? Should construction of
educational facilities associated with research and scientific manpower
take precedence over basic education ?
Consumer markets and growth

A fourth way the social welfare programs contribute to economic
growth is by enhancing the stability of consumer income and improv­
ing the equity of its distribution. Welfare expenditures are essen­
tially redistributive outlays which tend to reduce inequities in com­
mand over goods and services. While redistribution has not been
pursued as a positive policy, there is a redistributive effect which fol­
lows from the selection of the beneficiary groups, the limitation of
payments and services to needy groups, and from the characteristic
distribution of economic risks and of population by income groups.
The social-insurance payments go to those who have suffered a
reduction in income due to retirement, death, disability, or unemploy­
ment of the prim ary wage earner. Public-assistance payments are
conditioned on the meeting of a needs test. While not all health serv­
ices have an income qualification, public services are more attractive
to those who cannot afford any others, and most expenditures are made
for services subject to a need or medical indigency standard. Vet­
erans’ benefits are more attractive to those in the lower income groups,
and non-service-connected payments and medical benefits are restricted
to those who meet an income test.10
The net redistributive effect, however, depends not only on the
income status of beneficiaries but also upon the distributive impact
of taxes levied to finance the programs. Several studies have been
made of the redistributive effects of total budgetary income and
outgo.11 These several studies indicate that, on balance, the total
10 H o w ard G. S challer, V e te ra n s T ra n s fe r P ay m en ts an d S ta te P e r C ap ita Incom es,
1929, 1939, an d 1949, Review of E conom ics an d S ta tistic s, Novem ber 1953, pp. 325-332.
11 A lfred H . C onrad, T h e M u ltip lier E ffects of R e d istrib u tiv e P u b lic B udgets, Review of
E conom ics an d S ta tistic s , M ay 1955, pp. 1 6 0 -1 7 3 ; see also A. H. C onrad, R ed istrib u tio n
T h ro u g h G overnm ent B udgets in th e U n ited S ta te s, 1950, in Incom e R e d istrib u tio n and
Social P olicy (A lan T. Peacock, ed .), London, 1954, pp. 1 7 8 -2 6 1 ; see also Jo h n H . A dler
an d E ugene R. Schlesinger, T he F isca l System , th e D istrib u tio n of Incom e, a n d P ublic
W elfare, in F isca l P olicies an d th e A m erican Econom y (K enyon Poole, ed.)» 1951.




1016

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

fiscal operations of the National, State, and local governments redis­
tribute incomes vertically from the higher to the lower income groups
and reduce thereby the degree of income concentration. The largest
gains are shown for the income group receiving less than $2,000 of
consumer income. A study made more than 10 years ago points to
some net redistribution of income favorable to the low income groups
as a consequence of the social insurance program operations.12
The redistribution effected by the social-welfare programs alone
is very much circumscribed by the regressive base of the social-insur­
ance levies, and the major reliance on State and local revenues, p ar­
ticularly on property and sales taxes for the noncontributory programs.
For the most part, there is a horizontal redistribution of income be­
tween the wage earners who pay the taxes and the aged, the disabled,
the widows, and the children who receive the benefits. Over a period of
years a large part of benefits received and taxes paid by a family are
equated. Social-insurance contributions are returned on retirement or
death; education benefits received by the young family are returned in
property taxes when the children are grown. W ithin a single year the
major difference in the distribution of disposable income resulting
from welfare services and payments (as compared with the distribu­
tion of income received from production) is attributable to Federal
grants-in-aid and Federal benefits paid to special beneficiary groups,
such as veterans. Grants and special benefits to Federal beneficiaries,
however, account for less than 20 percent of total welfare outlays.
Social-welfare programs can help to maintain consumption. In
1929, welfare transfer payments and services accounted for 5.1 percent
of “adjusted” disposable personal income (table 2). In 1935, with
a drastically reduced income level, and expanded social services, these
welfare additions to consumer income accounted for 10.9 percent of
disposable income. Last year (1956), although income was at an all­
time peak, 11.2 percent of disposable personal income was made up
of welfare payments and services. A decade or so ahead this percent­
age may be expected to reach 12 or 13 percent of income after taxes—
a proportion sufficient in size to enhance the stability of the national
economy.
The shifting of income among income groups can have an additional
long-run effect on aggregate consumption and contribute to expan­
sionary forces in the economy. W ithout a quantitative evaluation,
which takes account of the specific content of social welfare finance,
the importance of this redistribution for aggregate consumption can­
not be assessed. There are other aspects of this question on which ap­
propriate investigation might throw much needed light. Does a full­
blown system of security protection alter decisions of families within
an income class to save or to spend? I f the major economic hazards
of family life were protected by the social insurances or by public
services would families alter their consumption and saving decisions,
and in what direction? How much can be achieved in raising,
through expanded health, education, and welfare services and pay­
ments, the productivity and living levels of low-income families?
These essential tools for social welfare policy decisions are at present
not available. The programs appear, however, within a limited range
to work toward a long-run increase in consumption.
u M ushkin, S cltovsky, an d Sm all, Social In su ra n c e F in a n c in g In R e la tio n to C onsum er
Incom e a n d E x p en d itu res. S ocial S ecu rity B o ard B u reau M em orandum No. 63, 1946.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

1017

Tax burdens

The potential contribution of health, education, and social-security
programs to economic growth has to be assessed against the tax load
required to finance these programs and the damper on national growth
which the tax burdens may represent. There is a vital choice to be
made between tax reduction and added government programs, between
leaving money in the pockets of individuals and corporations for dis­
bursement in such directions as they deem best, or for public direction
of these funds into governmental activities through the compulsion
of taxation. The balancing of forces of growth germinated by wel­
fare programs against the deterrents to growth set off by tax require­
ments is only one ratio which must be drawn from the profit and loss
statement.13
Not all welfare programs contribute directly to economic growth.
Education is not concerned exclusively with work-force skills, with
inventiveness and scientific advance; it is concerned too with trans­
mitting our cultural traditions, with elevating man, with broadening
horizons. A large share of the National, State, and local health dollar
goes to finance services for the chronically ill, many of whom will
make no further contribution to production. More than 2.5 million
of the public-assistance caseload is made up of old-age-assistance re­
cipients; and half of these assistance recipients are at least 75 years
of age.14 There are now about 14.5 million persons aged 65 and over
in the United States. The number of aged is expected at least to
double within a 40-year period.15 W ith the increases in the number
of aged, the number of persons eligible for retirement benefits under
the old-age and survivors' insurance program and other retirement
systems will rise. The percentage increase in beneficiaries will be
even more steep since benefits are largely deferred rights which ac­
cumulate over a long period of time. As of May 1957 over 10 million
persons were receiving old-age and survivors’ insurance benefits; some
8.5 million of these were aged 65 and over.
I t has been stated earlier that in a society struggling for subsistence,
prolonged educational training, voluntary retirement, and extensive
welfare services are not possible. But in a high level economy capable
of producing the wide variety of consumer goods which we have come
to accept as our standard of living, the choices are of a different order.
One type of choice is between (a) added economic output, (b) more
leisure hours for the worker, and (c ) added improvements in welfare
services and income. In the decades ahead, the choice may be between
how quickly we move to a 30-liour week or how fast toward meetinghuman needs more adequately.
When the 1935 Social Security Act was under discussion, emphasis
was placed on preventive rather than ameliorative measures. The
emphasis has continued to be on preventing public dependency and
dealing with causes of dependency. To reduce the weight on public
funds funds of preventable illness (physical and mental) and of
preventable illiteracy and poor education, to restore larger numbers
13 See discussion of th is issue in E veline M. B urns, Social S ecurity an d P ublic Policy.
M cG raw -H ill Book Co., 1956, ch. 14.
11 F ra n k J . H anm er, R ecipients of Old-Age A ssistance : P erso n al a n d Social C h a ra c te ris­
tics. Social S ecu rity B u lletin , A pril 1957, pp. 3-13.
15 T. N. E. G reville, Illu s tra tiv e U nited S ta te s P o p u latio n P ro jectio n s. Social S ecurity
A d m in istratio n , A c tu a ria l S tudy No. 46, M ay 1957, p. 23.
‘




1018

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

of disabled to work capacity, and to make available community serv­
ices required for the continued employment of working mothers and
others with dependents in their care, additional public funds will have
to be provided at least temporarily. B ut only by such preventive
expenditures can the burden be effectively reduced in the future.
W

elfa re

P

rogram s

and

E

c o n o m ic

S

t a b il it y

The welfare programs occupy a significant place among govern­
mental measures to maintain a high level of employment. While
declines in business activity would have an impact on health and
medical services and on public education, these programs, given their
present financial framework, are not basic tools of stabilization policy.
The social-security programs, however, provide at least a partial
corrective to a decline in wages and salaries.16
Social insurances

Three aspects of the problem of management of the social-insurance
funds during various phases of the business cycle may be mentioned.
F irst, there are no nationwide special statutory provisions for ad­
justment of the fiscal operations of the social-insurance programs in
the different phases of the business cycle. The countercyclical flexi­
bility of the programs is achieved under the basic provisions of the
social-insurance programs. T hat is, there is no statutory provision
for flexible adjustment of contribution rates or benefits during a de­
cline, or during an inflationary period. However, benefit provisions
have been amended to reflect changes in earnings and, in the past,
scheduled rate increases have been reassessed in the light of economic
circumstances. I t may be anticipated that, in the future, considera­
tion will be given to postponing the scheduled contribution rate in­
creases for old-age and survivors insurance if such increases are likely
to intensify deflationary pressures. Consideration should also be
given to contribution rate increases to offset inflationary movements,
that is, rate increases limited to an equitable relationship of benefits
provided to premiums assessed.
Second, the investment provisions and management of the social
insurance reserves are designed to facilitate a coordinate operation
of the reserve holdings, public debt, and credit-control policies.
The primary objectives in designing the investment provisions of
the social-insurance trust funds were to assure safety of the funds,
necessary liquidity, and a yield commensurate with the needs of the
programs. I t was recognized from the outset that the social-insurance
funds under the Social Security, Act of 1935 would have important
impacts on the financial markets and on the management of the public
debt. The selection of marketable and special issues of United States
Government obligations as permissible investments for the socialinsurance reserves and the management of these investments by the
Secretary of the Treasury were designed to facilitate the adm inistra­
tion of these funds in the light of general economic policy.
10 T he fo llow ing section is a d a p te d from Selm a M ushkin an d P h ilip B ooth, F in a n c in g
o f U nem ploym ent, C ash Sickness an d W orkm en’s C om pensation In su ran ce. N a tio n a l T ax
Jo u rn a l, S eptem ber 1956, pp. 203-231, a n d fro m S elm a M ushkin, F isc a l S ta tu s of OldAge an d S u rv iv o rs In su ra n c e P ro g ra m s In th e U n ited S ta te s. N a tio n a l T a x Jo u rn a l, Ju n e
1955, pp. 149-170.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

1019

The various Government investment accounts, at least potentially,
provide the Treasury with authority and resources for maintaining
stability in the Government bond market and with an important in­
strument of economic and fiscal policy. As the Secretary of the
Treasury indicated in his 1949 rep o rt:
Beginning in the spring of 1947, the Treasury took action
to control an incipient boom in the Government bond m ar­
ket—by selling long-term bonds from some of the Govern­
ment investment accounts, by offering the investment series
of bonds to institution investors, and by increasing short-term
interest rates. All of these operations combined to take up­
ward pressures off the market. When conditions changed,
and a downward pressure on bond prices developed, the mar­
ket was stabilized through purchases of long-term bonds.17
W ith relatively minor exceptions, in terms of volume of market
transactions, the Government investment accounts used for market
stabilization purposes were not trust funds such as the social insurance
trust funds. Holdings of social insurance trust funds and other
similar trust funds in which moneys are held in trustee capacity by
the Treasury for the benefit of covered employees or States are not
considered suitable at present for market operations.
Third, under basic laws, the social-insurance programs tend to com­
pensate for changes in other sectors of the economy. The financial
operations of the combined social-insurance programs furthered the
general anti-inflationary economic program of the administration dur­
ing W orld W ar I I, the Korean conflict and in the years following.
In the fiscal year 1956, for example, a toal of $2.5 billion was added
to reserve investment holdings of Federal trust accounts. The oldage and survivors insurance trust fund accounted for $1.5 billion, or
58 percent of the total.18 The increments to these reserves, largely
financed from the excess of payroll taxes, aided in reducing the
inflationary pressures of high demand.
Temporarily, additions to the old-age and survivors insurance trust
fund have been curtailed. In recent months, the rate of benefit dis­
bursements has exceeded the rate of contribution income. Unless
action is taken to advance the scheduled stepup from 1960 to an earlier
date net payments to the public rather than net receipts from the
public to this fund may be anticipated. While long-range financial
stability of the old-age and survivors insurance system does not re­
quire an acceleration of the contribution time schedule, the need for
new measures to combat inflationary forces may suggest such action.
During a period of downswing, particularly in the early phases
of decline, the social-insurance programs work automatically as com­
pensatory economic devices. I t is estimated, for example, th at a
decline of 10 percent in employment would lead to a rise of approxi­
mately 5 to 10 percent or about 300 to 600 million dollars in old-age and
survivors insurance benefits, at present disbursement levels. A decline
in employment opportunities for the aged would increase the number
of eligible persons who are forced into retirement and who would
17 A m ore re c e n t s ta te m e n t of th e T reasu ry policy reg ard in g in v e stin g G overnm ent
a cco u n ts is co n tain ed in th e re p o rt of th e C om ptroller G eneral of th e U n ited S ta te s on
th e P o s ta l S avings System , tra n s m itte d to th e Congress on N ovem ber 4, 1954.
18 S ecretary of th e T reasu ry . A n n u al R e p o rt on th e S ta te of th e F in an ces fo r the
fiscal y e a r ended J u n e 30, 1956, p. 367.




1020

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

apply for old-age benefits. A t present, about 25 percent of persons
aged 65 and over who have insured status under the program have
chosen to remain in active employment and are not drawing benefits.19
The countercyclical adjustments of social-insurance programs are
further augmented by the responsiveness of contributions to changes
in employment and earnings. Contributions which are geared to pay­
rolls and earnings quickly reflect changes in these payrolls. A 10percent decline in earnings would tend to be reflected in a somewhat
smaller percentage decline in taxable earnings within the $4,200
maximum, and in tax collections.
Although the unemployment-insurance program was adopted dur­
ing the depression of the thirties, when the problems of widespread
unemployment and depressed economic activity were sharply before
the Nation, the program was designed as a partially corrective meas­
ure. A t the time the program was developed, proponents of unem­
ployment insurance were divided sharply into those who emphasized
the purpose of stabilization of employment through employer in­
centives and those who emphasized the purpose of m itigating the
hardships of the unemployed and of maintaining buying power by an
adequate benefit structure. Experience rating (with its variation
of rates from employer to employer) emerged from the emphasis on
employer incentive toward stabilization; these rate variations have
had a continuing effect on program development. Emphasis on em­
ployer incentives also has facilitated the integration of guaranteed
annual wage plans with the unemployment benefit structure. In ­
creasingly, however, attention has been directed to the adequacy of
benefits and the effects of these payments on consumption expendi­
tures.
Several factors have contributed to the recently increased general
concern with benefit adequacy. The Social Security Act of 1935 con­
templated unemployment benefits at 50 percent of current wages.
Benefits have failed to keep pace with changing levels of gross na­
tional output and earnings, despite liberalizations under State laws.
F or 4 consecutive years, the Council of Economic Advisers in its re­
ports to the President has urged States to increase benefits so that the
great majority of the beneficiaries will be eligible for payments “that
at least equal half their regular earnings.”
Despite growing disparity between average wage levels and unem­
ployment benefits, the unemployment-insurance program contributed
toward easing the toll of economic transition. During four periods
in the past decade and a half, the changes in the volume and amount
of unemployment benefits have clearly demonstrated the usefulness of
the program in stabilizing consumption. In the tooling up from
peacetime activity to war production during the early 1940’s, in the
transition in 1946 to civilian production, and again in the postwar
industrial readjustments of 1949 and 1954, the unemployment insur­
ance system evidenced its responsiveness to changes in employment
opportunities. During the 6 months from A pril through September
1954, benefit payments were $1.1 billion compared with $0.4 billion
in the corresponding months of 1953. The contribution of the pro­
gram toward easing the effects of production retooling and setbacks
19 B u re a u of Old-Age an d S u rv iv o rs In su ra n c e .
E m p lo y m en t a n d B enefit D a ta , A u g u st 1957, p. 12.




Q u arterly

S um m ary of E arn in g s,

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

1021

also served to underscore the weaknesses in the benefit structure—■
weaknesses not only in benefit amounts but also in duration and in
coverage—which reduced the compensatory economic effects of the
program.
The potentially compensatory effects of the program have also been
offset somewhat by the fact that under experience rating operations,
tax rates have tended to rise in periods of increased benefit expendi­
ture and to decline in prosperous years. Increased attention to the
need for correcting this weakness in the tax structure has led a few
States to adopt tax schedules designed to provide a uniform annual
yield expressed as a percentage of wages. This device merely pre­
vents tax rate changes from accentuating business cycle movements
but it does not actually counter such movements. The 1956 action by
Congress setting up a loan fund for States whose employment insur­
ance reserves are in danger of exhaustion provides some additional
safeguards to States in their attempt to improve the cyclical move­
ment of contributions.
Studies of the economic effects of the unemployment insurance pro­
gram have served to define different ways of measuring compensation
for wage loss and to clarify their uses. A t least two yardsticks need
to be distinguished: 20 the proportion of income loss of individual
workers and their families which is compensated; and the net change
in national disposable income (taking account of the net change m
benefit outlays and earnings). Various studies of the offset to income
loss suggest that, in a period of downturn of fairly short duration
such as the 1948-50 downswing, unemployment benefits amount to
one-quarter or one-fifth of the net income loss. The difference be­
tween compensation for an individual worker’s income loss and com­
pensation for the economy as a whole is suggested perhaps most
sharply by the potential financial operation of the program after a
period of prolonged downswing. I f the period of decline depresses
wage rates, benefits paid to eligible unemployed workers may be ex­
pected to be a proportionately higher percent of their wages. How­
ever, an increasing number of unemployed workers would have lost
eligibility for benefits which is based on recent attachment to the
covered labor m arket; those qualifying for benefits would in increas­
ing numbers exhaust their rights to benefits,21 and the total benefit dis­
bursements in a 12-month period might in fact be reduced despite a
continuing rise in the volume of unemployment. The net effect as
compared with a previous period may be a negative—rather than a
positive—addition to income.22
Depression experience with workmen's compensation payments
points up the different meanings of compensation for wage loss.
Weekly maximum benefits for an Illinois worker with one child were
almost 85 percent of average weekly earnings in 1933 as compared
20 See M arv in K. Bloom. M easuring th e E ffect of U nem ploym ent B enefits on th e
Econom y. R esearch C ouncil f o r Econom ic S ecu rity publication No. 102 fo r a description
of v ario u s m ethods of m easurem ent.
21 In 37 S ta te s, d u ra tio n of benefits v aries w ith th e w o rk er’s earn in g s o r em ploym ent
experience (o r b o th ) in th e base period used fo r d eterm in in g h is benefit rig h ts . I f he
h ad considerable unem ploym ent in th e base period, h is weeks of benefits in th e n e x t year
w ould be co rresp o n dingly reduced, th u s in creasin g th e likelihood th a t if ag ain unem ployed,
he would e x h a u st h is benefit rig h ts before g e ttin g a n o th e r job.
23 T he u p w ard a d ju s tm e n t of em ployer ta x ra te s coupled w ith cyclical changes in tax
sh iftin g w ould a p p ear to reinforce th is effect.

97735—57------66



1022

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

with a range of about 50 to 55 percent during the 1920’s and even
lower percentages during the early 1940’s.23 Accidents for which
compensation was received were relatively few because of the low
level of employment and the retention of only the best workers. In
West Virginia, with an exclusive State fund program, total accidents
in 1932-33 among insured workers were at about two-thirds the
1928-29 number. Total benefit disbursements amounted to $3.8 mil­
lion in 1933 as compared with $4.8 million in 1929. I t is im portant to
note that low levels of earnings and employment necessitated premium
adjustments in many State workmen’s compensation programs during
the depression. In their recent volume of workmen’s compensation,
the Somers have pointed out th a t:
Prosperity has meant low (premium) rates, depression
high rates. * * * Throughout the forties rate reductions
were general and substantial, reflecting the vast increase in
payrolls, the relative inelasticity of benefit maximums against
rising wage levels, and the development of other socialsecurity programs which have, in part, taken the pressure off
workmen’s compensation.24
Despite upward rate adjustments during the depression, disburse­
ments for benefits exceeded premium payments in some States at least.
A n im portant step forward in understanding the economic opera­
tion of the program has been taken through the recent initiation of
studies of income and consumption patterns of beneficiaries under
the unemployment-insurance program in selected communities.25 A
start has been made in the case of the unemployment-insurance pro­
gram to evaluate the cyclical response patterns of the social insurances.
Similar studies are needed in the case of the other social-insurance
programs.
Public assistance

The public-assistance programs backstop the social-insurance bene­
fits by providing income maintenance for those in need, for those who
have exhausted their unemployment benefit rights, and for those whose
social-insurance benefits in addition to other income resources fall
below the standards of asisstance. W ithin narrow limits, the publicassistance caseload may be expected to vary with changes in unemploy­
ment level as long as the open-end grants are maintained. Federal
participation depends upon the size of the program in the States as
determined by the numbers of needy persons in the federally aided
categories; however, it also depends upon the amount of State and
local funds devoted to the assistance programs. While under present
Federal grant-in-aid provisions there may be some automatic increase
in the proportion of financing out of Federal funds, the increase in the
Federal share is contingent on a reduction in average payments under
the pressure of an increased number of claimants and of declining
State and local revenues.
Repeatedly the imbalance between development of general assistance
provisions and of the growth of federally aided categories has been
23 H erm an M iles Som ers a n d A nne R am say Som ers, W orkm en’s C om pensation, P re v en ­
tio n , In su ra n c e , an d R e h a b ilita tio n of O ccupational D isab ility , J o h n W iley & Sons, Inc.,
1954, p. 78.
“ Ibid., p. 114.
® P h ilip B ooth, R ecen t S tu d ies of B enefit A dequacy, p a p e r p re se n te d a t a n n u a l m eet­
in g o f A m erican S ta tis tic a l A ssociation, New Y ork C ity, D ecember 27, 1955.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

1023

pointed out. The majority report to the Commission on Intergov­
ernmental Relations of the Study Committee Report on Federal Aid
to Welfare urged abandonment of the categorical approach and sub­
stitution of a single Federal grant for public assistance to the needy.
A single Federal grant program for all State and local
welfare will encourage States to give attention to the needs of
all needy persons. The present arrangement of Federal aid
for several rather narrowly defined programs means that help
to needy persons or families ineligible for assistance under
these programs may be, and frequently is, much less than
that provided to those qualifying for federally aided public
assistance.26
I t is the general assistance program which is the most sensitive to
economic changes. During the post-World W ar I I industrial re­
adjustment which occurred in the first part of 1949, for example, the
general assistance caseload rose 20 percent.
As long as the present State-Federal, local-State fiscal arrange­
ments for grant-in-aid purposes continue in force, a solution to the
problem of maintaining welfare expenditures for the four aid cate­
gories and of meeting increased general assistance caseloads in the
face of shrinking State and local revenues will wait on emergency
action.
Health and education programs

The service programs as contrasted with the transfer programs are
not designed to stabilize economic activity. Moreover, the Federal
outlays under these programs are not very significant in terms of
economic adjustments. A part from veteran education allowances
and medical services, the total Federal expenditures for these purposes
are less than a cent and a half per dollar of budget outlay.27 While
there may be some increase in demand for types of public health serv­
ices with a decline in family income or increased unemployment, e. g.,
tuberculosis, cancer, and other disease casefinding, public health nurs­
ing, immunizations, and other clinic services provided under the pub­
lic health programs, the total Federal support of such activities is in
the neighborhood of about $12 million. W ith the exception of a few
States, medical assistance to those in need is provided by public hos­
pital agencies or welfare departments. Similarly education pro­
grams supported by the National Government would not be enlarged
appreciably by decline in employment. Increases in demand for voca­
tional training and a decline in dropouts from school by youngsters
entering the labor force might be anticipated, but the Federal support
programs are such that these changes would not influence Federal
expenditures without new appropriation and legislative authoriza­
tions.
Operation of the federally aided welfare programs is dependent
upon the basic grant-in-aid provisions. Increased attention needs to
26 A S tudy C om m ittee R e p o rt on F e d eral Aid to W elfare su b m itted to th e Com mission
on In te rg o v e rn m e n ta l R elations, J u n e 1955, p. 14.
27 C om puted fro m e x p en d itu re estim ates fo r th e fiscal y e a r 1957 in th e budget m essage
o f th e P re sid e n t f o r th e fiscal y ear 1958, pp. M4 a n d M58.




1024

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

be focused on the ways to improve existing grant provisions so that
they may be more useful as an instrument of fiscal policy. As a
minimum it would appear desirable to amend these provisions so that
program levels could be maintained in the face of declining State and
local revenues. Proposals have been advanced to vary the propor­
tion of Federal financial participation in grant programs with
changes in economic activity.28 A major objective of these counter­
cyclical grant proposals is to maintain the level of services and pay­
ments under grant programs by safeguarding these program levels
against the impact of reduced State and local revenues. More ex­
tensive and detailed study is needed of countercyclical grant pro­
posals to assess their practicability as a fiscal policy device. The
three provisions of grant programs which influence their fiscal opera­
tions need to be appraised, namely, appropriation provisions, allot­
ment provisions, and matching requirements (statutory or adminis­
trative) .
W elfare P rograms : P rojected C ost

and

F i n a n c in g

In the preceding discussion of the contribution of social welfare
programs to economic growth and stability brief reference has been
made to the future development of the social welfare programs. The
section which follows discusses the emerging problems of social wel­
fare finance for the decade or so ahead.
Outlays under existing programs

Increased social-welfare costs are projected under existing legisla­
tive authority. The two prim ary pressures on social-welfare expendi­
tures are the growth in child population of school age and in the aged
population who will qualify for benefits under retirement systems.
In 1955 there were 27.7 million children enrolled in elementary
school and 7.4 million in high school. By 1965 it is expected that
there will be 35.7 million enrolled in elementary grades and 11.9 mil­
lion in high school.29 Continued increases in the b irth rate as well as
the still to come impact of the postwar baby boom on the high schools
and colleges of the country are the basic factors which presage grow­
ing expenditures for public education even as shortages of facilities
and teachers may become more acute. As indicated earlier the basic
old-age and survivors insurance program is far from a mature pro­
gram. A t present, benefit outlays amount to about 4 percent of tax­
able payrolls, the level premium cost of the system, however, is esti­
mated at 7.4 percent of payroll. Long-range actuarial estimates of
the Social Security Administration indicate a long-run trend of
mounting old-age and survivors payments; benefit outlays are esti­
mated to reach $12 billion by 1965, $17 billion by 1980, $22 billion by
2000, and to increase beyond that time.30 Pension costs under other
public retirement programs will also increase with the rise in the num­
ber of qualified retired employees. There are other factors which in­
dicate higher welfare outlays in the years ahead, within present statu­
28 Ja m e s A. M axwell, F e d eral G ra n ts an d th e B usiness Cycle, N a tio n a l B u reau of
E conom ic R esearch, 1952.
29 U. S. D ep artm en t of L abor, O ur M anpow er F u tu re , — 1955-65.
30 R o b ert J . Myers, A c tu a ria l C ost E stim a te s fo r th e Old-Age S u rv iv o rs a n d D isa b ility
In su ra n c e S ystem as Modified by A m endm ents to th e S ocial S ecu rity A ct in 1956. ( P re ­
p ared fo r th e use of th e C om m ittee on W ays an d M eans, Ju ly 23, 1956, pp. 8 a n d 14.)




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

1025

tory authority—pressures for example of competitive earnings levels
on salary levels of public employees, of scientific change, and of chang­
ing standards of living.
.Social-welfare expenditures in 1956 totaled about $34 billion. The
services represented by these outlays accounted for about 11 percent
of consumer income that year. To finance the social-welfare services
a revenue burden amounting to 9 percent of gross national product
was imposed.
Tables 1 and 2 present illustrative projections of the social-welfare
budget in 1965 based on existing legislative authorizations, known
population changes, and a continuation of past economic trends. Edu­
cation outlays are estimated for 1965 at almost $5 billion more than
1956 level; social-insurance benefits, primarily due to retirement bene­
fits to a larger number of aged are estimated at about $8 billion above
the 1956 paym ents; other welfare expenditures are estimated at about
$2 billion above the 19o6 expenditure levels.
Does a social welfare budget of almost $50 billion mean a larger
revenue load on the national economy? W ith an increase in popula­

tion, employment, and earnings of the projected amounts, socialwelfare-program revenue requirements (including additions to socialinsurance reserves) are estimated at $53 billion. For the most part
the growth in social-welfare-revenue requirements would be propor­
tional to the gains in national output. The United States Depart­
ment of Labor estimated the manpower demand and gross output for
1965, based on a projection of past trends to 1955, and on a 25 percent
increase in gross output per capita.” The Bureau of Labor Statis­
tics estimates, adjusted only for price increases since 1955, indicate a
gross product of $585 billion in 19(55 as compared with a gross product
of $434 billion in the second quarter of 1957. Thus, the growth in
social-welfare outlays under existing legislative authority would not
be at the expense of a higher aggregate tax load on gross production
of the economy.
Will the increased social welfare budget require new taxes? Will
it require an expanded Federal budget? The classification of pro­

gram expenditures shown in table 2 provides an approximate ap­
proach to answers to these questions. Over half of the projected
increases are in social-insurance benefits financed through trust-fund
operations, and by special earmarked social-insurance contributions
now provided under existing statutory authority.
Federal programs for special beneficiary groups and those pro­
grams in which the Federal Government provides over half the funds
are estimated to represent a smaller rather than an increased taxload
on the national output. Total expenditures in these two classifications
are estimated at $7.6 billion for 1965 as compared with $7.1 billion
for 1956, a far smaller rise than the projected rise in gross national
product. Thus as far as the Federal administrative budget is con­
cerned the projection is for reduced Federal tax-rate requirements.
Almost 45 percent of the projected $15 billion increase in the socialwelfare budget represents higher outlays for programs financed pri­
marily out of State and local taxes. While these predominantly
State and local programs are estimated to increase $6.6 billion and
reach $23.2 billion by 1965, the proportion of gross product devoted to
31 O ur M anpow er F u tu re , 1955-65. op. cit.




1026

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

their finance would remain at the 1956 level—4 percent of gross
national product.
Increased State and local revenues under existing tax legislation
proportionate to gains in economic activity and output are not indi­
cated, however, by past trends. Several recent studies, for example,
have emphasized the inflexibility of property taxes which still account
for about 45 percent of State and local tax collections.32 Property-tax
collections over the past decades have failed to keep up with expanded
national output. The host of complex issues involved in expanding
property-tax collections, including impact on housing values and
effect on new housing construction, the relation of property assess­
ments to market values and equalization of property assessments, sug­
gest problems ahead in financing education, public hospital and medi­
cal care, general assistance, and the other related programs. While
considerable, progress is being made in methods and procedures of
property taxation and in removing constitutional and legal barriers
to effective property-tax utilization, it may be anticipated th at a sub­
stantial gap will exist between State and local revenues and amounts
required to finance welfare-program outlays. I t is this gap which
points to continued public debate of State-local and national-State
fiscal relations in the years ahead.
Types o f new proposals and approximate costs

The social-welfare programs are developing programs. Tech­
nological and scientific advances, the growth of metropolitan areas,
altered patterns of family life, and the rising standard of living con­
tribute to changing welfare standards and create new social problems.
In the operation of social-welfare programs gaps in protection are
brought to light and new approaches to social problems are identified.
In view of these forces which underlie proposals for extension of exist­
ing welfare activities, it is not sufficient to measure the fiscal impact
of existing program s; an attempt must be made to anticipate develop­
ments in the immediate years ahead.
Many different proposals have been advanced to enlarge and im­
prove social-welfare services. The proposals advanced are directed in
the first instance, at least, to one of several of the following:
Research (scientific and social)
Physical facilities necessary to the service function
Manpower required to provide services
Methods of organization of services
Methods of financing the provision of services, or cash payments
I t is possible within the scope of this paper to take account only of
several major proposals from among the many advanced. Among the
more important of the proposals are extension of the social insurances
to provide more adequate protection against the hazards of unemploy­
ment, industrial accidents, sickness, and severe disability, and against
unexpected and large hospital-care costs, enlargement of educational
and health facilities, and improved organization of these services, im­
provement in the quality of education in the public schools, and in
opportunities for higher education, and assistance to voluntary health
plans to facilitate the broadening of coverage and benefits to the aged
32 M abel Newcomer, S ta te an d L ocal F in a n c in g in R elation to E conom ic F lu c tu a tio n s,
N a tio n a l T ax Jo u rn a l, J u n e 1954, pp. 97-109. Also M elvin an d A nne W hite, Im p a c t of
E conom ic F lu c tu a tio n s on M unicipal F inance, N a tio n a l T a x Jo u rn a l, M arch 1954, pp. 17-39.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

1027

and other medically indigent groups in the population. An illustra­
tive listing of program proposals follows:
Social-insurance programs
Extension of cash sickness-disability benefit protection
Improved workmen’s compensation protection
Increased unemployment-insurance benefits
Extension of severe disability benefits to persons in younger
age groups
Hospitalization insurance for old-age and survivors’ insur­
ance beneficiaries
Programs for special Federal beneficiary groups
(No change)
Programs financed prim arily by Federal funds
Extended vocational and other rehabilitation services
Programs financed prim arily by State and local funds
Education proposals
Scholarship or other support for college and graduate
students
Construction aid for new or expanded higher education
facilities
Construction aid for elementary and secondary schools
Operation aid for elementary and secondary schools
Extended educational services for handicapped children
Health maintenance proposals
Improved organization of medical services; for example,
care of mentally ill, rural health services
Construction or operation support to increase health man­
power; for example, homemakers, laboratory tech­
nicians
Aid to voluntary health insurance plans to increase cover­
age and scope of benefits; for example, for low-income
groups for aged, etc.33
W ithout a specific description of program content it is patently
not possible to estimate with any precision’ funds required to finance
the proposed programs. However, the approximate order of magni­
tude of additional annual revenue requirements, National, State, and
local, is illustrated based on a continuation of economic and demo­
graphic trends.
Adoption of these proposals is estimated to increase the social wel­
fare budget about $7.5 billion, from the $49.5 billion projected for
1965 to about $57 billion. W ith the new benefits added, the revenue
requirements of the social welfare program would be increased by
1965 to 10.4 percent of gross product, as compared with 9 percent
for 1956.
I f the problem of hospitalized illness expense of aged persons is
met in the next decade through extension of the social insurances,
about 55 percent of the $7.5 billion increase in social welfare outlays
would be financed out of social insurance contributions. The remain­
ing 45 percent would represent additional revenue required by pro­
grams prim arily financed by States and localities. I f the hospital
cost problem of the aged is met in some other way, for example, by
83 P ro p o sals fo r aid to v o lu n ta ry h e a lth p lan s an d fo r provision of h o sp ita liz a tio n in s u r­
an ce fo r old-age a n d su rv iv o rs’ in su ran ce beneficiaries m ay be considered a s a lte rn a tiv e p ro ­


posals, inv o lv in g ab o u t th e sam e a m o u n t of public expenditures.


1028

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

aid to voluntary health plans under a Federal-State grant program,
the division of costs between the social insurances and State and local
programs would be reversed. About 40 percent of the additional
outlay would represent social insurance charges and 60 percent a
charge prim arily on State-local funds.
Expansion of the social insurances would require a stepping up
of contributions, from an average rate of about 9 percent in 1965 to
about 11 percent, and an increase in the taxable wage maximums.
Willingness of employed groups and their employers to assume the
new contribution obligations will be a direct factor in the political
discussions and decisions of benefit extensions. I t may be noted that
not all of the increase in contributions would represent a new charge
on covered employees and their employers. A t present employers are
contributing $5.7 billion annually to private pension and welfare
funds, including contributions for cash sickness, disability benefits,
and health insurance for their employees.
In a recent survey of 3,100 firms employing 6.8 million employees
the National Industrial Conference Board found th at 85 percent of
hourly workers and 75 percent of salaried workers were covered under
group accident and sickness insurance and all but 2 or 3 percent were
covered for basic hospitalization insurance. The companies surveyed
were financing the entire cost of group accident and sickness insurance
for almost 4 out of each 10 workers while for over 5 of each 10 the
plans were financed jointly by employers and employees. In the case
of hospitalization insurance, employers financed the entire cost for
more than one-third of the employees and participated in the financing
of protection for nearly an additional one-half of the employees.
A p art of the present employer contributions to private welfare
plans would be offset against additional social insurance contributions
by the altered arrangements for dealing with protection against sick­
ness, and with hospitalization coverage of retired employes. (A t the
same time, improved labor mobility would result by removal of at
least a p art of the fringe benefit barrier to shifts in employment.)
As indicated earlier $6.6 billion in additional funds would be re­
quired by 1965 for programs prim arily financed by State and local
funds, without additions to existing activities. Although the tax
load on gross national product would not be enlarged, financing of
these programs will require marked changes in methods of raising
funds and a reordering of National-State-local responsibilities. Addi­
tional health and education programs along the lines of those pro­
posed before legislative committees and by various study groups would
add $3.3 billion to $4.5 billion to the budget of these programs. The
additional State and local program obligations can be expected to
intensify the search for new revenue sources and to make more per­
sistent demands for State aids to localities, and for Federal aids.
Revenue relief or public programs

I t is im portant to bear in mind that the proposals for public action
in social welfare program areas at times take the form of tax relief
measures. The Revenue Code of 1954, for example, increased deduc­
tions for personal medical expenditures as a method of offsetting the
hardships to families occasioned by unpredictable severe illness. This
authorized deduction is designed to provide a measure of tax relief
to families suffering expensive illness. The 1954 code introduced a



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

1029

new category of deductions up to $600 for expenses incurred in the
care of an incapacitated dependent, or children under 12 years of age,
by employed mothers, widows, or widowers. The new code, further­
more, provided some relief to taxpayers against the cost of higher
education by eliminating the $600 gross income test for determining
the dependency status of children under 19 years of age, of those over
19 still attending school, and by excluding scholarship aid in deter­
mining whether a taxpayer provides over half the support of a child
or stepchild. Other changes were made relating to welfare programs.
The code authorized the claiming of an exemption for support of
parents where several children contributed to this support but no one
taxpayer contributed over half the support. The authorization was
broadened for widows and widowers with dependent children to split
incomes for 2 years after the death of their spouse, and single per­
sons who support one or more parents in a separate home became
eligible for half the benefits of income splitting. A tax credit of 20
percent was provided for the first $1,200 of retirement income. P ro­
visions on the deductibility of cash sickness benefits and sick leave pay
were clarified.
Earlier—in 1948—taxpayers over 65 years of age, and blind persons
were allowed an additional personal exemption of $600; in 1950 aged
persons were permitted to deduct all medical expenses from gross
income.
In discussion of tax law modification to provide special deductions,
exemptions, and credits for special family situations, for the economic
and personal hazards of life the question of equity among taxpayers
has been the major issue. W ithin this context, there are many other
special family economic risks and circumstances which can create dif­
ferences in capacity of taxpayers. These situations are occasioning
demands for further extension of tax relief provisions. Im portant
among proposals now current are those calling for tax credits for
voluntary health insurance premiums, and for tuition paid to colleges
and universities; for additional personal exemptions for all disabled
persons; for a broadening of business expenses to include transpor­
tation and other extra work expenses of handicapped persons, ad­
vanced training expenditures of teachers, physicians, and other pro­
fessional groups, and expenses associated with changes of employment
such as employment agency fees, moving expenses, etc. The possi­
bilities of such special provisions are legion for there are innumerable
family relationships and ways of meeting family economic and em­
ployment problems.
There is an additional equity problem sometimes lost from sight in
these proposals for tax relief. Such special provisions for exemp­
tions, deductions and credits involve a loss in revenue—a loss which
is an indirect subsidy of the aged, of chlidren who provide parental
support, of young people attending colleges and universities and of
disabled persons. I t appears necessary to inquire, therefore, whether
the groups who would receive the benefits of tax reduction are the
most appropriate beneficiaries of a public program, whether public
expenditure programs in the amount of the projected revenue loss
would provide welfare aid more equally to all groups in the popu­
lation, or whether a direct expenditure program would more equitably



1030

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABIUTY

provide aid to the 45 million or so in the population whose economic
status is so low th at they are not Federal income taxpayers or depend­
ents of these taxpayers.
T a b l e 1.— Social welfare revenue requirements:1 Amount and percent of gross

national product, selected years
Amount (in millions)
Program
1929

Programs financed primarily by

1929

1935

1956

1965 2

4.4

9.3

9.0

9.1

435

13,357

22,300

.5

.6

3.2

3.8

529

435

6,521
6,836

14,300
8,000

.5

.6

1.6
1.6

2.4
1.4
.8

494

489

4,415

4,650

.5

.7

1.1

484
10

470
19

4,311
104

4,500
150

.5
(3)

.6
(3)

1.0
(3)

2

1,828

2,718

3,000

(3)

2.5

.7

.5

2

115
1,713

2,367
351

2,500
500

(3)

.2
2.4

.6
.1

.4
.1
4.0

Public assistance, special cate-

Programs financed primarily by

1965 2

$6, 754 $37,137 $53,200

and dis-

Veterans’ and other Federal bene-

1956

529

$4,596

Old-age, survivors,

1935

Percent of gross national product

3,571

4,002

16,647

23, 250

3.4

5.5

4.0

2,800
500
71
200

2,300
661
841
200

12,300
3,428
196
723

17,200
5,000
250
800

2.7
.5
.1
.2

3.2
.9
1.2
.3

3.0
.8
(3)
.2

.8
(3)

2.9
.9
(3)

.1

1 Represents contributions assessed for social insurance programs and revenues required to cover cost
of other programs.
2 Illustrative estimates.
3 Less than 0.05 percent.
N o t e .— P e r c e n t s m a y n o t a d d t o t o t a l s b e c a u s e o f r o u n d in g .

Source: Amounts shown for social insurance contributions, 1929,1935, and 1956, from Survey of Current
Business, July issues; other amounts for 1935 and 1956 from Social Security Bulletin, September and
October issues; 1929 figures from report of the Committee on the Costs of Medical Care and from official
agencies.




1031

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

T a b l e 2. — Social welfare benefits:' Amount and percent of personal disposable

income (including value of public services)
Amount (in millions)

Percent of personal
disposable income2

Program
1929

1935

1956

1965 3

1929

1935

1956 1965 3

$4, 435

$6, 706

$34,287

$49,500

5.1

10.9

11.2

11.9

368

387

10, 507

18,600

.4

.6

3.4

4.5

368

387

5,652
4,855

12,000
6,600

.4

.6

1.9
1.6

2.9
1.6

Old-age, survivors, and disability

Veterans’ and other Federal beneficiary

Programs financed primarily by Federal

Programs financed primarily by State

494

489

4,415

4,650

.6

.8

1.4

1.1

484
10

470
19

4,311
104

4,500
150

.6
(4)

.8
(4)

1.4
(4)

1.1
(4)

2

1,828

2,718

3,000

(4)

3.0

.9

.7

2

115
1,713

2,367
351

2,500
500

M

.2
2.8

.8
.1

.6
.1

3,571

4,002

16,647

23,250

4.1

6.5

5.5

5.6

2,800
500
71
200

2,300
661
841
200

12,300
3,428
196
723

17,200
5,000
250
800

3.2
.6
.1
.2

3.7
1.1
1.4
.3

4.0
1.1
.1
.2

4.1
1.2
.1
.2

1 Amounts shown for social insurance and public assistance represent transfer payments and exclude
administrative costs, except for grants to States; surplus food distributions to needy persons and public
institutions are also excluded.
2 Personal disposable income estimates are adjusted so that they include not only transfer payments, but
also value of services received under health and welfare programs. Value of other public services has not
been added.
* Illustrative estimates.
4 Less than 0.05 percent.
N o t e .—Percents may not add to totals because of rounding.
Source: Amounts shown for social security payments, 1929,1935, and 1956, from Survey of Current Busi­
ness, July issues; other amounts for 1935 and 1956 from Social Security Bulletin, September and October
issues; 1929 figures from report of the Committee on the Costs of Medical Care and from official agencies.