View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

SOME NOTES ON FOREIGN ECONOMIC AID
M. Bronfenbrenner, professor of economics, Michigan State University
P

r e l im in a r y

These thoughts and suggestions refer to the administration of direct
Government expenditures for foreign economic aid, mainly but not
exclusively in the underdeveloped areas of Africa, Asia, and Latin
America. They refer both-to grants and to loans; indeed, one sugges­
tion will be the transfer of much of our expenditure to the former
from the latter category. They exclude such items as military aid,
disaster relief, commodity purchases for stockpiling, and Government
guaranties for American private capital abroad. They also assume
the line between such categories as military and economic aid, or
between disaster relief and reconstruction development, to be more
unequivocal than is likely in practice.
The figure concerned is as yet a relatively small one, compared to
the total Federal budget. I t is currently less, rather than more, than
$2 billion annually, and the question may arise why special attention
should be devoted to it here. To this sort of argument, if it in fact
arises, there are at least two answers:
1. Expenditures for foreign economic aid generate an uniquely large
political multiplier. By the term “political multiplier,” which may
be original, I mean that each dollar of foreign economic aid generates
demand for X dollars (X varying over time, but always substantially
greater than unity} of domestic expenditures of all kinds, chiefly eco­
nomic aid for low-income areas within the continental United States.
In particular, it has been found extraordinarily difficult to reduce these
latter expenditures, say, in a period of inflation where much fiscal
theory would recommend reduction, while maintaining economic as­
sistance to foreigners. So that, while talking directly about $2 billion
of foreign economic aid expenditures, we are talking indirectly about
perhaps $5 billion or $8 billion of total expenditures. (Please do not
ask me to justify these figures, which represent pure armchair specu­
lation.)
2. The element of altruism and human sympathy in our foreign
economic aid should not be overlooked, but it remains true that it has
been sold politically, mainly as an American weapon in the cold war.
And as the cold war of rival military expenditures shifts in emphasis
to the competitive coexistence of rival economic ideological salesman­
ship, we must expect the size of these expenditures to increase for an
indefinite period.
Considered in bloodless frigidity, with all elements of altruism and
human sympathy drained away, the problem of administration of our
foreign economic aid program can be put in economic terms as obtain­
ing maximum cold war or competitive coexistence advantage at a
given cost, or as the so-called dual problem of obtaining at minimum
97735—57------10



605

606

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

cost a given cold war or competitive coexistence advantage. And here,
to run ahead of the main body of this paper, my feeling is th a t our
performance (in Asia at least) leaves much to be desired, in th at the
U. S. S. R. and mainland China obtain much more competitive co­
existence advantage per dollar of foreign-aid expenditures than we.
F

o r e ig n

E

c o n o m ic

A

id —

A

m e r ic a

V

er su s

R

u s s ia

This section is a political digression. I t deals with the initial ad­
vantage and disadvantages with which we (and other western nations,
especially the United Kingdom and the Commonwealth countries)
face in the administration of foreign economic aid as compared with
the U. S. S. R. and its allies, especially mainland China. I f it should
appear, as I believe it does appear on balance, th a t America starts out
under an initial handicap, efficacy equal to the Russian or Chinese
will require expenditures greater than theirs.
We have, as I see it, two main advantages vis-a-vis the Russians,
in the foreign-aid aspect of the coexistence competition. The most
fundamental of these is our greater wealth. We have more to spend
for the purpose, and can afford easier terms. Less important, and
less unequivocally an advantage, are our democratic institutions. Our
expenditures for foreign aid can be presented as from the American
people as a whole, not merely from a few leaders spending the people’s
money without the people’s consent. I t is questionable, however,
whether full use has yet been made of either of these advantages.
We operate, on the other hand, under a number of competitive
disadvantages, correlated in most cases with these same advantages.
Our greater wealth and income can be exaggerated to imply that,
whatever we give, we can afford more, and, however easy our terms,
we can afford easier ones. Indeed, if one accepts the underconsumptionist and stagnationist critique of capitalism which is common in
intellectual circles, it is easy to argue th at our foreign-aid expenditures
do not hurt us in any way and are actually beneficial, if not necessary,
for us. (The theory implies, as is well known, th at our only alterna­
tives to such spending are depression, unemployment, or armaments.)
Furthermore, the less savory aspects of the history of western con­
tacts with the underdeveloped world constitute a handicap difficult
to overcome. If, as the Indians and Indonesians claim to believe, the
industrial revolution of the Western W orld was financed by the loot
of Bengal and the Spice Islands, any reasonable amount of American
aid expenditures in these areas constitutes nothing more than a token
payment in vicarious atonement for the sins of earlier generations of
British and Dutch. ( I t should also be remembered that, during the
approximate century of British free-trade policy, Americans who
“would not play false, and yet would wrongly win” participated along
with British subjects in the gains from B ritish “imperialism.”) In
countries where our aid expenditures are considered only moral repara­
tions, too little and too late into the bargain, there is little reason to
expect great effectiveness from them in swaying public opinion i-n a
pro-American direction.
Such half-truth history of the roots of western wealth has been
important in implanting among the intellectual classes of most non­
white countries a certain marked anticapitalist and pro-Socialist bias,
which is often transformed into an anti-American and pro-Soviet one.



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

607

Nor are these classes to be overlooked as mere “eggheads.” Their
social position is at once higher and stronger than it is in America,
despite the wretched poverty in which many of them live. Their
control over all agencies of communication, m particular, is almost
absolute. Short of totalitarian dictatorship, there is no substitute to
winning over at least a substantial minority of the intellectuals if one
wishes to influence public opinion. I f American foreign policy, both
political and economic, has thus far fallen short of expectations in
influencing the intellectuals of the underdeveloped countries, the
explanation lies rather more in this half-truth history, I should guess,
than in any imperfections of our policy itself, or our domestic racial
troubles, or the alleged anti-intellectualism of American civilization.
But be its causes what they may, the anticapitalist and anti-American
slant of the intellectuals of the nonwhite and underdeveloped coun­
tries constitutes an additional handicap to be overcome, a handicap
often overlooked in cold-war prognostications.
Our democratic political institutions can also involve us in diffi­
culties abroad. Voices are raised freely, in Congress and out, begrudg­
ing the aid we give, denouncing its beneficiaries, demanding harsher
terms, both political and economic. These voices are easy to quote
overseas to counteract the political effects of whatever is spent. And,
probably more important, it has been difficult for us as a political
democracy to contribute funds in aid of what the beneficiaries often
want, because the underdeveloped regions of our domestic economy
want the same things. A t least one distinguished Senator allegedly
abandoned his fight for reelection in the face of opponent’s campaign
comparing pictures of model schools in India (for which the Senator
had led in getting funds appropriated) with pictures of ramshackle
structures attended by some of the Senator’s own constituents.
We seem, in fact, to have run up against a dilemma in our aid ex­
penditures, as between spending on projects largely “invisible” in the
countries concerned, and projects more eminently “visible” there.
Spending on such “invisible” projects as seeds, insecticides, the serv­
ices of experts, the exchange of students and teachers, is relatively
easy to finance. On the other hand, its effect on foreign political
opinion seems to be negligible, whatever its cumulative economic effect
may be. Spending on such highly “visible” projects as steel mills,
dams, and technical institutes is more appreciated abroad, but appro­
priations are more difficult to appropriate because of the opposition
from representatives of domestic constituencies which want the same
things. Also, but less important thus far, these “visible” projects are
intended in some degree for eventual competition with our own ex­
ports, both agricultural and industrial. I t may be increasingly dif­
ficult to persuade the representatives to export constituencies to accede
to “subsidizing their own competitors.”
In facing this dilemma, we have tended in the main to spend on
the “invisible” projects for which Congress would most easily appro­
priate funds, and which may well be for the greatest long-run economic
good of the foreign beneficiaries, but which were not what the bene­
ficiaries themselves most desired. We have left the “visible” projects
too largely to our competitors across the Iron Curtain. To use a
crude analogy, we have given socks and sweaters for Christmas to a
little boy who wants an electric train, and let our in-laws give him the
train.



608

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY
S

ome

G

eneral

S

u g g e s t io n s

1. Aid should be put almost entirely in the form of grants rather
than of loans, for three main reasons. Direct grants are more highly
appreciated abroad, particularly as against loans from the U. S. S. R.,
which is short of capital and has sometimes pressed hard for repay­
ment. In the second place, it is doubtful that the American public
expects or counts on the repayment of many “loans” made under the
heading of foreign economic aid, so th at haggling over repayment
schedules, interest rates, and so forth, is not only an irritan t but a
needless one. (Finlands are few and far between.) In the third
place, funds already “lent” may be used by borrowing countries as
hostages for “ransom” if sanguine expectations of repayment are built
up. By this I mean that further loans or other aid may be extracted
against our better judgment as conditions for service on earlier loans.
(The Germans used this technique effectively in the early years of the
Nazi regime.)
2. Aid should be concentrated on what the beneficiaries actually
want, not on what we think they ought to want. W hat they want
may, of course, be general programs involving a large number of small
items individually almost invisible—like postwar reconstruction in
South Korea. They are more apt to be large visible items like dams,
bridges, railroads, and factories—or, as in Afghanistan, the paving of
the main streets of the capital. Insofar as possible, projects should be
supported which are wanted both by the governments and by the
people in the grantee countries. Projects wanted by the people but
not the government run too high a chance of being sabotaged m gov­
ernment circles by diversion of funds to other purposes. Projects
wanted by the government but not the people will usually be ineffec­
tive in influencing public opinion.
3. Once aid has been granted, supervision should be reduced to a
minimum, and supplied only at the request of the grantee country.
We have been criticized for taking back in payment to unwanted
American experts, consultants, supervisors, and construction com­
panies too large a proportion of the grants we make. There are other
ways of guarding against misuse of our funds.
P

roblem s of

A

l l o c a t io n

However generous American taxpayers may become, difficult choices
will have to be made between alternative programs and projects. We
cannot take on ourselves the financing of the entire economic develop­
ment of the entire underdeveloped world. Allocation problems will
always be with us, and must always be faced.

As a first step in the competition for each year’s allocations, United
States economic staffs stationed abroad, in embassies or in other
agencies like the International Cooperation Administration, should
list and, if possible, rank projects apparently wanted by both govern­
ments and people in the countries where they are stationed. They
should prepare, with what local assistance may be obtainable, estimates
of probable cost and (if possible) probable benefit, and submit to
Washington applications based on these estimates.
It is important that these applications be submitted to the American
Government by Americans and not by foreign governments them-




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

609

selves. We should not require or expect foreign governments to make
formal, mendicant, hat-in-hand applications, and subject themselves
to the indignities of possible refusal. Applications should be sub­
mitted by Americans to the American Government with the minimum
of publicity abroad and the minimum involvement of the prestige of
foreign countries or governments. I t is not unlikely under such a
system that certain foreign governments should deliberately court
publicity for their applications and involve their own prestige in these
applications as a form of pressure on the United States. Such pres­
sure, however, is easier to resist when no formal international nego­
tiations have begun and the whole m atter is strictly intragovernmental.
More applications will undoubtedly be submitted each year than can
conceivably be granted. The process of screening then might well be
in stages, as is the screening of research and allied applications in the
leading educational foundations. The first stage might be in the State
Department, International Cooperation Agency, or some joint board
representing all agencies concerned. The second stage might be in the
Bureau of the Budget, and the third stage in Congress. Each stage
of the screening process should be carried on each fiscal year, both
with an eye to the total amounts to be approved and to the specific
projects which seem most promising.
I t is difficult to present in advance anything which could pass for
principles to be followed in the screening of applications, and what
one says is more likely to be a “counsel of protection” than a “precept
for action.” A few such general notions may, however, be included:
1. In general, the total volume of new projects approved in the
United States should be reduced, other things equal, when the domestic
situation in the United States appears to be inflationary, and increased
when the domestic situation in the United States appears to be defla­
tionary. The direct contracyclical effects of this policy will hardly
be significant. The total volume of expenditures will be small;
changes in spending will lag behind changes in commitments and also .
fluctuate less sharply, since most commitments should probably cover
more than a single year. This principle is nevertheless of considerable
importance because of the political multiplier mentioned earlier.
2. Competition with other lending agencies, particularly multilat­
eral ones, should be avoided. Projects or programs should be rejected
when they are under serious current consideration by the International
Bank for Reconstruction and Development, by the Colombo plan, by
individual foreign governments, or by private agencies. An exception
to this principle should, of course, be made in the case of competition
with the U. S. S. R., mainland China, or countries generally hostile to
the United States Government.
3. Grants should in general be made contingent on the receiving
government’s paying for the bulk of the local labor and materials
involved, where such a requirement is meaningful. The purpose of
this requirement is to give the receiving government a share in the
project concerned, and to reduce the easy-come, easy-go attitude
toward funds received as free gifts or long-term loans.
4. Insofar as possible, grant policy should not follow the headlines.
By this we mean th at it should not be concentrated too closely in
regions which happen to be in the headlines when grants are being



610

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

allocated (the Far East in 1954r-55, the Middle East in 1956-57). It
should also be as political as possible as between countries, along the
lines of Secretary Marshall’s original “Marshall plan.” It is difficult
to imagine a grant being made to (or accepted) by Soviet Union or
mainland China in the near future, but grants which help to turn
countries from active hostility to being “neutrally against us or from
hostile to friendly neutrality may be the most productive investments
possible. (Poland and Yugoslavia are possible illustrations.) At the
same time, firm allies should not be overlooked in favor of countries
more strategically balanced. The great danger is of too great a con­
centration for political reasons in countries in the friendly neutral,
semially, or wavering ally categories.
5. Again insofar as possible, grant policy should be neutral economi­
cally as well. Socialism, welfare statism, inflationism, unfair discrimi­
nation against American exports, unfriendly attitude stoward Ameri­
can private capital (even to the point of confiscation) should not in
themselves bar favorable consideration. (This suggested policy of
“turning the other check” toward confiscating countries is in no way
inconsistent with compensating American investors partially or com­
pletely expropriated abroad.)
Conspicuous production, on the other hand, should seldom if ever
be supported. By conspicuous production is meant the grandiose and
spectacular project which the country itself is likely to abandon as
laughably wasteful and uneconomical after a few years. (Steel mills
located without reference to adequate iron and coal resources are
common cases in point. Likewise fancy tourist hotels and airports
in countries unsafe for foreign visitors.)
Corruption and diversion represent major problems in many coun­
tries, implying as they do that American grants would be wasted
outright, or at the very least applied for purposes other than were
intended. The temptation to supervise and police grants in coun­
tries of poor repute for corruption and diversion will be difficult to
withstand, and also the temptation to apply stricter standards to
foreign than to domestic politicians and civil servants in regard to
corruption and diversion. My suggestion is that all these tempta­
tions be avoided sedulously as good-will measures, but that really Dad
records of past corruption and diversion be made bases for refusal of
grants until housecleaning has taken place. (An analogy here is the
problem of censorship of publications. What I am advocating is like
the use of postcensorship rather than precensorship for newspapers or
magazines, assuming some form of censorship to be required.)
A lesser problem: some governments are willing to inform bene­
ficiaries of American aid where the aid comes from; other governments
do everything possible to keep the beneficiaries of American aid from
realizing their indebtedness to this country. Since foreign aid is a
weapon of competitive coexistence, it seems to follow that govern­
ments of the first type should be favored over governments of the
second type in the allocation of grants. Here again, supervision
should be avoided in favor of judgment based on the past record of the
government concerned.
6. Another aspect of economic neutralism is that aid be not con­
fined to governments or public agencies. Private projects may often
be expected to win out over public ones, especially in countries with



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

611

corrupt, inefficient, or visionary governments. Particular companies
whose projects are assisted should however be unmistakably native in
ownership, top management, and financial control. Funds should be
channeled to these companies through public agencies, much as founda­
tion grants to scientists in this country are usually channeled through
universities and research institutes. To reduce the competitive ad­
vantage of the recipient companies, they should be required to repay
both principal and interest to their home governments, even though
further payment by the home governments to the United States Gov­
ernment nas been waived. (It would seem natural to require eventual
repayment to the United States in these cases, but such a requirement
would almost certainly bias the selection process in favor of private
projects. In addition, home governments require mollification where
private projects have been preferred over projects of their own;
eventual receipt of both principal and interest should mollify them.)
P

u b l ic it y a n d

P

u b l ic

O p in io

n

Questions naturally arise as to the political feasibility of such a
plan as has been outlined above. Two areas where adverse political
reactions may be expected are the less developed regions of the United
States, and foreign countries disappointed in the allocation of grants.
Trouble in neither of these areas is avoided under the existing system
of foreign aid administration, but these proposals would in all prob­
ability increase their severity. The attempt is presently made to
minimize adverse reaction by a policy of secrecy regarding the details
of the apportionment of aid expenditures, both by countries and by
types of program. I t is not impossible that declassification of this
information would help rather than hinder the success of the entire
forieign aid program—whether the present one or one reformulated in
the direction o f the present suggestions.
An almost certain advantage of declassification and increased pub­
licity would be to prevent occasional inevitable instances of corrup­
tion, diversion, or maladministration from being advertised as typical,
since the great volume of contrary evidence would become available.1
Another advantage would be to permit rural Congressmen and Sen­
ators (and their constituents) to compare amounts spent for specific
types of aid in specific foreign countries with the large amounts the
Federal Government will undoubtedly spend for similar aid to States
and localities at home. Here specific breakdowns (educational aids,
highway aids, electrification aids, flood control aids, etc.) will be as
useful as overall figures, since domestic concern seems to rest on specific
types of expenditure as well as on overall totals.
As between foreign countries, the present secrecy policy leaves most
or all countries feeling discriminated against vis-a-vis some or all of
their neighbors and rivals. (Small countries are concerned with to­
tals, larger ones with per capita figures.) Their feelings are prob­
ably exacerbated by the substitution of fantastic rumors for adequate
1 The “g reat volume of contrary evidence” must of course include the honest m istakes
and the m ice born of m ountains along w ith the spectacular successes. As my colleague
Prof. John M. Hunter has put it to me in criticizing an earlier draft of these notes, the
U. S. Government should regard foreign aid much as business concerns regard their research
programs. N either can be policed very carefully ; it is seldom th a t even h alf the individual
projects “p ay off” in either c a s e ; but sometimes even the negative results are contributions
to practical knowledge, and the aggregate benefits a t least equal the aggregate costs.




612

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

evidence regarding the distribution of American aid. A policy of
publicity should permit a frank admission to any particular country
that it was left out in any particular year, together with the ad­
monition th a t the equity of the program as a whole must be judged
over a longer period.
SU N FED

and

S

im il a r

P

r o je c ts

These proposals imply continued American control over the de­
tails of American aid appropriations. To th at extent they are un­
ilateral, and run counter to schemes for transferring control to m ulti­
lateral international organiaztions and concealing the identities of
individual .grantor countries. A t present the most ambitious of
these internationalist proposals would establish a Special United Na­
tions Fund for Economic Development (SU N FED ) administered
by the United Nations. I f the SU N FED proposal or any similar plan
is adopted, with large-scale American financial participation, the
foregoing paragraphs of course become irrelevant.
A main attraction of the multilateral and international proposals
is th at it transfers the unpleasant and often fruitless task of dunning
debtor countries from individual creditor countries to an interna­
tional organization such as the United Nations or one of its sub­
sidiary agencies. I f loans are replaced by grants, there need be no
dunning of debtors by creditors in any case, and this advantage dis­
appears.
In a competitive coexistence context, an im portant purpose of for­
eign aid is vitiated if grants or loans come indirectly through interna­
tional organizations rather than directly from the United States,
the United Kingdom, or the Soviet Union. I f the Soviet Union and
its allies are willing to put their foreign economic aid into a common
pot, to be allocated by United Nations agencies in which there is
no veto, it may of course be in the American interest to follow suit
and lessen the acerbity of the coexistence competition. But barring
a change of heart in the Kremlin, there is more to be lost than gained
by America’s merging its aid funds with those of other developed
countries, while the Soviet Union garners all the competitive advan­
tages of going it alone and having its aid clearly identified.