View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

T H E IN T E R E S T R A TE IN C O ST-B EN EFIT A NALYSIS
.

Arnold C. Harberger, associate professor of economics,
University of Chicago

I t would be hard to overstate the importance of the interest rate
used in the discounting of benefits and costs to judge the worthwhile­
ness of proposed long-term Federal investments. Suppose a project
were expected to yield benefits of $1 million a year beginning 5 years
from the initiation of construction and extending indefinitely into
the future. Using an interest rate of 2y2 percent, we would evaluate
this stream of expected benefits at $35.36 million as of the date of
initiation of the project. But if we were to use a 6-percent rate, our
evaluation would be no more than $12.45 milion. The choice of inter­
est rate becomes more critical, the longer the duration of the project
in question, and the longer the lag between the beginning of construc­
tion and the time when benefits begin to accrue. Clearly major mis­
takes can be made if the wrong interest rate is used in evaluation. I f
the cost of the above project were $20 million, it would be a fine in­
vestment if 2 1/2 percent were the right rate and a terrible mistake if
6 percent were the right rate. I propose to argue in this paper th at a
rate of 6 percent or better is the proper rate to use in evaluating
Federal projects. This compares with a rate of 2y2 percent most com­
monly used by the Government agencies which undertake cost-benefit
analyses.
The justification most commonly given for the use of the 2y2 per­
cent rate is that th at is the rate at which the Government can borrow.
This, of course, is no longer true; perhaps a Sy2 percent rate would
accord better with the present state of the money market. Be that as
it may, my argument for a rate of 6 percent or better does not depend
critically on the state of the money market. I t holds equally well
for the easy-money days immediately following the second W orld W ar
and for the hard-money period through which we are now passing.
The essence of my argument is that there exist and have existed
ever since the war widespread opportunities for investments yield­
ing 6 and 8 percent and higher. So long as such opportunities are
available, our society does itself a disservice by investing at yields of
merely 2y2 or 3y2 percent. The opportunies I speak of are those at
the margins of industrial and agricultural investment, and I suspect
it is also true that investment in residential construction m ight yield
close to 6 percent.
Let us consider a typical industrial investment. Let it be financed
half out of equity (or retained earnings) and half out of borrowings.
W hat must it yield in order that it be a successful investment in the
market sense ? Presumably, the total yield should be sufficient to pay
the interest on the borrowings and provide a rate of return on the
newly invested equity equal to the market rate of return on equity.
Takirio- figures which are reasonably representative of the period since



*39

240

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

the war, let us assume the interest charge on borrowings to be 4 per­
cent, ana the earnings yield of equities to be 10 percent. This earmngs
yield is? of course, after taxes; the before-tax yield of equity capital
has typically been in the order of 20 percent. Thus our typical suc­
cessful investment yields 4 percent on half the invested funds and 20
percent on the other half, making the rate of return on the whole equal
to 12 percent. It may be objected that the 10 percent figure for earn­
ings yield, -while representative of the whole postwar period, has been
rendered obsolete by the great rise in stock prices that has occurred.
For recent years a figure of 7 percent might be better for the after­
tax yield of equities. This means 14 percent before tax, and together
with a 4 percent borrowing rate applied to half the total capital im­
plies an overall yield on capital of 9 percent, rather than the 12percent figure obtained earlier.
Another approach to estimating the rate of return on capital in
the United States is to compare total income received on account of
capital with the total value of the capital itself. Neither of these
components is easy to estimate, but much work has been done in re­
cent years to improve our knowledge of both.1 In spite of the lack
of absolute precision in the presently available estimates, one may
feel quite confident that the stock of capital in the United States
is somewhere between 3 and 4 times the national income, and that
the income accruing to capital amounts to somewhere between onethird and one-fourth of the national income. Our estimate of the
rate of return on capital in the overall economy lies, then, in the
range between 6^4 percent (income of one-fourth divided by capital
of 4) and 11.1 percent (income of one-third divided by capital of
3), and probably closer to the middle than to the extremes of the
range.
In the case of agriculture we have a reasonably good measure of
the return on capital in the ratio of the gross rent paid to the value
of rented farms. For 12 Corn Belt States this rent/value ratio
ranged from an average of 5l£ percent in Ohio to an average of
8 percent in Wisconsin, with most States averaging between 6 and
7 percent. The figures are for 1954-57, and apply to farms rented
wholly for cash.2
It is clear that there do exist many alternative investments yield­
ing 6 percent and more per year. One might ask, however, whether
these differ substantially from typical government projects in their
degree of riskiness, so as to warrant a substantially different rate of
return. I cannot help but feel that Federal projects are highly
similar in their degree of riskiness to many private projects. Both
power and irrigation facilities are provided by the private market
side by side with Federal installations, as are, from time to time, river
and harbor improvements, flood-control facilities, etc. These rank,
to the best of my judgment, neither as especially safe nor especially
risky investments. It therefore seems reasonable to expect that Fed­
eral investments in these activities should pay off at least at 6 per­
cent, which, as we have seen, appears to be somewhat below the aver­
1 Cf. ^Raymond Goldsmith, A Study of Saving in the United States. (Prineetopi: 1956.)
Moses ^bram ovitz, Resource and Output Trends in the United S tates Since 1870* A'merican
Econom ic Review, May 1956, pp. 5-23, and the sources cited therein.
2 U. S. Departm ent of Agriculture, The Farm Cost Situation, May 1957, p. 19, table 8-




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

241

age return on investments in the private sector of the economy. The
purpose of Federal investment is, I believe, to improve our level of
living and that of our children; the measure of this improvement is
provided in dollar terms through the estimation of benefits. There
seems little or no justification for the Government’s withdrawing re­
sources from the private sector unless these will yield as much im­
provement in levels of living as ordinary private investments.
My recommending the use of a substantially higher interest rate
in cost-benefit analysis does not imply any prejudgment that serious
mistakes were made because a lower rate was used. If estimated
benefits were 5 times costs using a 2 percent rate, they would likely
turn out to exceed costs, though by a smaller margin, when a 6 or 8
percent rate was used. It is the projects which are marginal in the
first place that look bad when a higher rate is used. It is accordingly
of interest to inquire whether projects actually undertaken could pass
the test of a higher interest rate. A group of investigators at the
University of Chicago have looked into this question, using the same
benefit and cost estimates as were presented by the agency in ques­
tion, but simply applying different interest rates for time discount­

's -

.

.

Out of 24 Bureau of Keclamation projects which were in fact un­
dertaken, only 8 would have been judged acceptable at a 5-percent
rate, only 2 at a 7x "Percent rate, and only 1 at a 10-percent rate, if
/2
only primary benefits are taken into consideration. Counting sec­
ondary as well as primary benefits, 16 projects would pass the test at
the 5-percent rate, 9 at the 7^-percent rate, and 4 at the 10-percent
rate. Similar results emerged from a study of 29 Corps of Engineers
projects. However, in the case of 27 Department of Agriculture
watershed programs, practically all of the projects would stand up
under a 5-percent rate, and two-thirds would be acceptable at a 10percent rate, though one must add that the estimates of benefits, which
are the raw material of benefit-cost analysis, appear to be subject to
substantial possible error in these cases.’
Thus it appears that the use of a higher rate would have precluded
some, but by no means all of the projects actually undertaken. I
strongly recommend and urge that future Federal investments receive
scrutiny in terms of a rate or interest comparable to the return to capi­
tal in the private sector. This will lead to a better use of our re­
sources, and in the bargain may provide some possibilities for budget
limitation.
8 U niversity of Chicago Office of Agricultural Econom ics Research.
Ju ly 18, 1956, pp. 4 -5 .




Paper No. 5612,