View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

F E D E R A L E X P E N D IT U R E S FOR TRA N SPO RTA TIO N
Burton N. Behling, economist, Bureau of Railway Economics,
Association of American Railroads
Some of the specific questions set forth by the Subcommittee on
Fiscal Policy in its “outline of study” as submitted to the panel p ar­
ticipants have a very pertinent bearing upon Federal expenditures for
the provision of basic transportation facilities such as highways,
waterways, and airways. Indeed, the questions are so opposite to
conditions in transportation as to suggest the thought th at they could
well have been designed with particular reference to basic problems
in transportation and the Federal Government’s role in regard to
them.
Among such questions the following are particularly appropriate in
reference to transportation: As a practical matter, are there any
standards which can be applied to determine what kind of activities
should be undertaken by government, in what amounts and at what
rates ? For example, are there any practicable economic criteria for
comparing demands for public services with private demands ? Are
there any standards for determining the kind of government programs
and the way in which they are conducted so as to minimize govern­
ment interference in decisions by business and consumers about use
of resources? W hat standards can be applied for determining
whether specific programs proposed to be undertaken by the Federal
Government are economical? For example, how can any such stand­
ards of economy in government be applied in deciding whether a
specific program should be undertaken and the size of the program in
relation to other Government activities? In what sense can a gov­
ernment spending program be described as wasteful? W hat consid­
erations should enter into decisions about the level of government
(Federal, State, or local) at which public functions are undertaken?
These are major issues affecting transportation and, considering
the growth tendencies of Federal programs involving expenditures
on behalf of transportation, they are im portant from the standpoint
of the general Federal budget as well. Such expenditures also have
a significant relationship to the economic growth objectives of the
Employment Act, if for no other reason because th at act, soundly
construed, must be concerned not merely with growth, as such, but
with growth that is economic growth and not just more activity.
The fact that such questions as those presented so persistently come
up with reference to government expenditures on behalf of trans­
portation indicates an awareness of the need for better means than
we now have for testing such expenditures in economic terms. Basi­
cally the problem is the allocation and utilization of resources in trans­
portation for true economy, considering all of the costs th a t are in­
curred. Resource conservation and economy are no less essential
when transportation facilities are provided by government expendi1064



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

1065

tures than when they are provided through private channels. U n­
fortunately, however, gross deviations are more likely where Govern­
ment expenditures are involved, with the result that serious distortions
from standards of real economy in competitive transportation occur.
While the fundamental problem of economic allocation and utiliza­
tion of resources would exist even if all transportation facilities and
services were provided by the Government, the consequences of un­
economic allocation and utilization are especially disturbing where,
as is the actual case, some basic transportation facilities are provided
through public expenditures and some through private undertakings.
Under these conditions, public expenditures backed by the taxing
power create a serious threat to successful competition by those means
of transportation th at are privately financed and that, in addition,
must pay their share of general taxes. Although those who operate
on basic transportation facilities provided by government do pay
certain general taxes, they do not pay any taxes or make any payments
in lieu of taxes on the publicly financed facilities they use. F or com­
mon carriers, this tax disparity is compounded by another—the waremergency transportation excise taxes on freight and passengers which
still remain in effect more than a decade later. Private transporta­
tion bears no such taxes.
So the question is: W hat can the Government do to foster and
maintain an environment of economic neutrality with respect to trans­
portation, recognizing that the Government is, and in all probability
will continue to be, deeply involved in spending programs for the
development of basic transportation facilities of various kinds ? Or,
as the subcommittee’s outline very aptly poses the question: Are there
any practicable economic criteria for comparing demands for public
services with private demands and are there any standards for deter­
mining the kind of Government programs and the way in which they
are conducted so as to minimize Government interference in decisions
by business and consumers about use of resources ?
To forestall any possible misunderstanding perhaps it should be
acknowledged immediately that perfection in the allocation and
utilization of transportation resources can hardly be expected either
as to Government expenditures or in private sectors of the economy.
Miscalculations and misjudgments in commitments of capital and
spending will, of course, sometimes happen. This is really only an­
other way of saying that our economy is a profit-and-loss economy.
But certainly this does not mean, either, that all we can rely upon
is whim, group, or sectional pressures, and guesswork. Where we can
substantially improve upon the economic processes of decision milking
and reduce the errors in resource commitment there is every reason
to do it.
T

r a n s p o r t a t io n

U

ser

C harges

There can hardly be any question but what the principal defect now
existing in the policies and standards by which Government expendi­
tures on behalf of transportation facilities are determined can be very
substantially corrected. This defect is, in all too many situations, the
lack of a sensitive connection between spending for and paying for
transportation facilities provided by the expenditure of Govp.rn m p.nt
funds obtained from general tax revenues. In these circumstances
the costs involved have little or no influence upon those who seek

97735—57------69


1066

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

Government expenditures for their own advantage in private or com­
mercial transportation operations. Those who urge the provision of
transportation facilities for their use and advantage cannot even be
said to represent a true “demand,” for the economic concept of demand
has meaning only in relation to a price or cost. Thus, for example,
when a steel company, or oil company, or coal company, or perhaps
all of these and others similarly situated seek a waterway improvement
from the Government at a cost to general taxpayers but not to them­
selves, they do not in a true sense constitute an economic demand. The
economic discipline of cost fades into the background and, then, deci­
sions are made prim arily through political activity rather than in
terms of economic calculation. We do not know what the demand for
subsidized transportation actually is, nor is there any satisfactory way
of finding out so long as those who petition for and use the facilities
are not required to pay the costs.
I t is for these reasons that the costs of transportation facilities
and services provided by Government expenditure need to be brought
out of hiding and registered effectively at the point of business and
consumer decision by requiring compensatory user payments from
those who use such facilities and services. A simple expression of this
principle may be stated as follows: Users of transportation facilities
and services provided by Government expenditure should have such
facilities and services only to the extent that they pay for them in
compensatory charges.
The answer to the question of whether transportation user charges
would help to bring about a more economic allocation of resources in
transportation seems very positively in the affirmative. In short, this
policy would afford substantial relief from political pressures for
uneconomic projects and spending programs because sponsors’ recom­
mendations to the Congress would be made on a more realistic
economic basis.
Reimbursement of the costs by compensatory user charges would
also establish a sounder competitive basis for the utilization of avail­
able alternative means of transportation according to relative economy,
all costs considered. W ithout such charges, shippers and consumers
cannot make unbiased economic choices in deciding which mode of
transportation to use in particular situations, for they will, of course,
take no account of hidden subsidy costs from which they are relieved
and which instead are borne by taxpayers. Their choices are misguided
or distorted choices and, as such, they foster not economy in trans­
portation but diseconomy resulting from misdirection and misutilization of transportation resources. Such diseconomy can only mean
that, in the aggregate, transportation costs are increased, not de­
creased. Yet the belief dies hard that subsidized transportation is
cheap transportation.
This discussion is particularly concerned with expenditures and
compensatory charges for transportation facilities and services.
Doubtless there are other im portant areas where prices for services
received rather than general taxes would be a superior economic tool
in financing and controlling government spending,1particularly where
1 This and other aspects of Government spending and its control are discussed by
C. Lowell H arriss, Government S p en d in g: Issues of Theory and P ractice, Public Finance,
international quarterly journal devoted to the study of fiscal policy and related problems,
No. 1, 1957.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

1067

the users are identifiable, the uses are measurable, and the objectives
of policy can be attained by this means of financing. The user-pay
principle does not, of course, offer a universal solution or panacea for
problems of effectively directing and controlling Government spend­
ing in all areas of Government activity. I t would hardly be appro­
priate in public-school financing, for example, because our basic ob­
jectives of universal education could not in this way be achieved. Nor
would it be effective in respect to the maintenance of public law and
order, the national defense, or carrying out the objectives of certain
welfare programs. W ith respect to penal institutions and houses of
correction, the user-pay principle would, most certainly, break down.
Transportation, however, presents about as clear a case as would be
possible to conceive for application of the user compensation prin­
ciple. In present-day transportation in this country, with the several
alternative modes now available to meet our requirements, economic
criteria should have a greater role than they do under prevailing pol­
icies and methods of financing. This is not a matter of advantaging
one means of transportation as against another; quite to the contrary,
general application of the user compensation principle would go far
toward establishing an environment of economic neutrality. In trans­
portation, noting once again the terms of reference in the subcommit­
tee’s outline, these are “the standards for determining the kind of Gov­
ernment programs and the way in which they are conducted so as to
minimize Government interference in decisions by business and con­
sumers about use of resources.”
Although this conclusion respecting user charges has had increas­
ing acceptance, both inside and outside the Government during three
President administrations and in numerous committees of Congress
over the past 20 years or more, effectuation of the user-pay principle
has been slow and erratic. We continue to have what may well be
called chronic subsidies in transportation not because there is any
longer a basic need for them in order to have a sound and adequate
national transportation system but, rather, because please and pres­
sures for their continuation are so strongly exerted by those who reap
special economic advantage from them. For example, the infant in­
dustry argument is stretched almost beyond recognition and then is
subtly transformed into a further development contention in which
each new stage of development takes on the cloak of infancy. A closely
associated rationalization is that a superior means of transportation
should be nurtured by Government support in order to fulfill its prom­
ise, overlooking the fact that prolongation of subsidy makes the true
determination of relative economic superiority impossible. There is
also the kind of argument stemming from historical analogy in which
the major premise is that what was done a hundred or more years ago
or from time immemorial ought to be regarded as a model or standard
of policy now and for the future, in total disregard of differences in
conditions which make such historical comparisons invalid today.
Still another perennial favorite among the contentions for subsidy
is that the tax-supported mode of transportation makes a contribution
to the national defense, which may well be true as far as it goes but
overlooks the fact that each mode of transportation and every impor­
tant segment of the whole economy adds something to our total na­
tional strength and security.



1068

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

Finally, there is the contention that the particular mode of trans­
portation for which subsidy at taxpayers expense is being urged will
diffuse indirect benefits throughout the national economy and because
of this diffusion transportation users should not be required to bear
the costs. Diffusion of indirect benefits is, of course, not a unique
but very general phenomenon in an interdependent economic system.
All forms of transportation and, for that matter, all worthwhile types
of economic activity have this common characteristic; it is not peculiar
to any one of them. This fascinating theory of diffused and indirect
benefits as a basis for financing transportation and other economic
facilities and services has startling implications if we imagine its
application as a general policy throughout the economy. Consider,
for example, the consequences of applying it to steel, to coal, to alumi­
num, to telephones, to automobiles, and to a host of other goods and
services that might, by some standard or other, be regarded as gen­
erally beneficial. A t least we can be sure that this would play havoc
with the functioning of the price system.
W hether in transportation or elsewhere, indirect or diffused bene­
fits are no justification for spreading subsidies around wherever such
benefits can be indicated. Moreover, the best transportation facility
for a given purpose will, all cost and services considerations accounted
for, contribute the most in diffused or indirect benefits to the economy
generally. Should it then receive the most bountiful subsidy, whether
or not it is needed for successful performance ?
These indirect and diffused benefits are really the eventual product
of transportation. I f the costs are borne directly by the users, they
will either absorb them for the services they receive or pass them on
to others as a component p art of the price of economic services or
goods supplied to others. This, in the usual course of our price-cost
economy, is the proper (i. e., consistent with economic allocation of
resources in a competitive economy) way for transferred, indirect and
diffused benefits to be brought into relation with the stream of economic
costs. When this fundamental requirement of real economy is made
effective, we shall have the essential basis for an unbiased allocation
and utilization of resources in transportation.
A reasonable regard for brevity does not permit here any detailed
analysis of the various Government spending programs for basic
transportation facilities such as highways, waterways, airports, and
airways. However, some further observations regarding certain of
these transportation programs are especially pertinent to the questions
presented in the subcommittee’s outline.
T

he

E

x pa n d ed

F

e d e r a l - A id

H

ig h w a y

P

rogram

Although Federal grants-in-aid to the States for highway develop­
ment had been established policy on a limited scale for many years,
the much greater magnitude of the new program which eventuated
in the Federal-Aid Highway Act of 1956 called for a searching re­
examination of policy issues, and especially for a realistic determina­
tion of how the very large outlays proposed could be paid for. Up
to that time there had been no definite plan for financing Federal
highway aid and there was no specific connection between the Fed­
eral spending for highways and required payments by highway users
to support such spending, although contentions had now and then



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

1069

been advanced th at the proceeds from some of the existing general
fund excise taxes could be regarded as serving that purpose.
In the early stages of considering proposals for an expanded Fed­
eral highway program virtually all attention was centered on high­
way needs, with very little on financing that would involve additional
levies with which to pay for the proposed expenditures. Not until
this approach was substantially reversed and the matter of sound
financing was definitely confronted did a feasible plan begin to emerge.
Only a few of the significant provisions of the 1956 act can be
touched upon here. There were certain notable achievements, how­
ever, that merit particular emphasis in the context of this subcom­
mittee’s search for improved standards of governmental expenditures.
The first of these accomplishments is the requirement of the act
that Federal expenditures for highway aid shall be covered entirely
by revenues from charges levied upon highway users, with a trust fund
of receipts from user charges set up to assure th at this requirement
is met. Since the conditions and principles involved are essentially
the same, consideration might well be given to applying this trust
fund control plan to the financing of government expenditures on
behalf of waterway and airway transportation facilities as well as to
highway facilities.
In the 1956 Highway Act Congress also provided that operators of
large and heavy vehicles on the highways shall pay special user
charges in addition to the kinds of charges imposed on passenger
automobiles and other ordinary vehicles. Although the scale of the
special charges adopted was modest, in principle at least the extraor­
dinary responsibility of large and heavy vehicles for highway costs
was recognized despite very strenuous opposition from the commercial
trucking industry.
Also, for the first time, Congress in the 1956 act found it necessary
to impose limits upon the dimensions and weights of vehicles permitted
to operate upon the Interstate System of Highways, in order to pro­
tect the highway investment and to prevent a continuing upward
spiral of increasing vehicle sizes and weights, and of the resultant
highway standards and costs that would be necessary to accommodate
such vehicles. As the House and Senate committees proceeded in their
deliberations on the highway problem, they foresaw the pitfall of an
open-end commitment to provide evermore costly highway facilities
for vehicles of ever-increasing weights and dimensions.
Congress also recognized that it had not reached final answers in
its first action on these problems. Accordingly, the Secretary of
Commerce was directed, through the Bureau of Public Roads, to con­
duct further investigations of these and related matters. Studies now
being conducted, particularly under the directives of section 210 of
the act, involve a consideration of the effects of vehicle sizes and
weights on highway costs. This section of the act further directs the
Secretary of Commerce and his aids to study and report on “indirect
benefits” from highways “in addition to benefits from actual use of
such highways.” I t will be interesting to see what findings this
analysis of “indirect benefits,” a subject referred to elsewhere in this
paper, may bring forth.



1070

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY
T

he

St. L

aw rence

S eaw ay

Provisions of law, in both the United States and Canada, authoriz­
ing joint development of the St. Lawrence seaway require th at its
costs be self-liquidating from tolls upon the users. Although prior
to authorization sponsors of the project gave unreserved assurances
that the navigation project would easily be self-supporting and involve
no Costs to taxpayers, some prospective users, now th at the waterway
is approaching completion, express misgivings as they press for low
tolls in disregard of the costs to be met.
While this turn of events is not altogether surprising where a gov­
ernment-financed project is involved, the implications are nonetheless
significant. If, as some of the sponsors and prospective users o f this
project now contend, it cannot be self-supporting, as contemplated, this
would necessarily mean that it is not an economically sound transpor­
tation facility. The seaway as a navigation facility can provide noth­
ing except transportation and no amount of emphasis upon “general
benefits” could change this fact or elevate an otherwise uneconomic
facility to the status of economic soundness. Those who now contend
that the seaway cannot pay its costs and "who make appeals to various
“general benefits” in an attempt to avoid adequate toll charges would
do well to consider the economic implications of their position jind
to note in this connection the following penetrating analysis with
reference to waterway projects generally, as contained in the report
of the task force on water resources and power of the (Hoover) Com­
mission on Organization of the Executive Branch of the Government:
* * * Facilities solely for navigation provide transpor­
tation, nothing else, and all of the intangible benefits mustnecessarily be derived from a waterway improvement as an
instrument of transportation. The essential fallacy of bring­
ing intangible benefits into the reckoning as additional factors
is that they beg the entire question of whether a proposed
waterway facility will actually be an economically sound
transportation alternative and they, therefore, lead to m ulti­
ple counting of the alleged economic benefits twice if not
more than twice.
The sound promotional development of industry, of agri­
culture, of higher living standards and of the economy gen­
erally depends upon the economic utilization of available
resources on the basis of alternatives available or capable of
development. A waterway that is deficient when measured in
terms of economy as a facility for transportation cannot be
given any real justification by adding on so-called intangible
benefits to give it greater validity, for the reason that the other
■forms of transportation which are existing or potential alter­
natives to it likewise provide such collateral and intangible
benefits and, obviously, the best economic facility as an instru­
ment of transportation will contribute to such intangibles to
the maximum extent * * *.2
2 Commission on Organization of the Executive Branch of the Government, Task Force
Report on W ater Resources and Power, June 1955, vol. 3, pp. 1317, 1332-1333, Evaluation
of Federal N avigation Projects, by Charles D. Curran, task force adm inistrator. See, also,
in the same volume, pp. 1299-1316, User Charges on the W aterways of the United States,
by John H. Frederick.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

1071

In an economic appraisal of the seaway project there are still other
circumstances to be considered. Under existing policies, users of the
seaway are to have the use, without charge, of improvements by the
United States in the connecting channels and harbors of the Great
Lakes. Also, electric power is to bear all of the common costs of this
joint power-navigation undertaking, with no share of such costs
assigned to the transportation function. I f transportation through
the St. Lawrence seaway cannot even bear its own direct or separable
costs, then the seaway shapes up as an extremely dubious economic
venture in transportation and as a waste of economic resources.
F

ederal

A

id s t o

A

ir

T

r a n s p o r t a t io n

The economics of air transportation has from its beginning been
closely interwoven with advances in military aviation, as the spec­
tacular development and operation of modern aircraft has been
spurred by tremendous expenditures of public funds required for the
national defense and security. This intrinsic relationship, stemming
from the fact that the basic tool of air commerce is also a primary
military instrument, will continue indefinitely. I t has, of course,
already contributed very greatly to the rapid growth of civil air trans­
portation.
Especially in view of this very substantial intrinsic advantage and
impetus, there is all the more reason to question the justification for
continuing, in addition, to bestow upon civil air transport subsidies
and aids that were initiated as temporary expedients when air com­
merce was a fledgling activity and industry many years ago. As yet,
however, little progress has been made toward the elimination of such
special aids to civil air transportation so as to place it on a sound eco­
nomic basis of self-support.
While most of the domestic airlines now receive “service rates” of
mail pay that are considered to be free of subsidy, some are still on a
subsidy basis and all of them continue to be eligible for subsidy under
the “need” provision of the Civil Aeronautics Act of 1938, which
stands unchanged.
Federal expenditures for airway facilities and services, and for
airport aid, have increased in recent years along with the growth of
air traffic, and further substantial increases have been programed for
the years ahead.3 Still, although the matter has been under considera­
tion for some time, no policy has been adopted which would require
the commercial airlines and private flyers to pay in compensatory user
charges a reasonable part of the costs 4 of these federally financed facil­
ities. In its present form and at the present rate the existing Federal
excise tax on motor fuel, which applies to aviation gasoline as well as
to other grades of gasoline but not to kerosene as used in jet engines,
would not serve as an adequate user charge for aircraft and has never
been designated as such by Congress.
This m atter of airway and airport user charges seems likely to come
before Congress in the near future. When Mr. Lewis S. Rothschild,
3 C iv il A e ro n a u tic s A d m in is tra tio n , F e d e r a l A irw a y P la n , F is c a l Y e a rs 1957—62, D ecem ber
19D6.
1 T h e F e d e r a l a ir w a y s a lso se rv e m ilit a r y a ir c r a f t, so t h a t som e a p p o rtio n m e n t o f th e
c o s ts is in d ic a te d .




1072

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

Undersecretary for Transportation, Department of Commerce, ap­
peared before a subcommittee of the House Committee on A ppropria­
tions on March 13-14,1957, he stated:
* * * We have been taking a hard look at the possibility
of instituting user charges in the field of air facilities, and we
believe that our studies are sufficiently far advanced so th at we
can see a feasible way of adding user charges.
W ithin the present session of the Congress we expect to be
up here to give you our ideas as to how a substantial p art of
this money can be recovered through the medium of user
charges.5
5 House Committee on Appropriations, hearings before the subcom m ittee on Departm ent
of Commerce appropriations for fiscal 1958, 85th Cong., 1st sess., pp. 222-223.