View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

F E D E E A L E X P E N D IT U E E PO LICY F O E ECONOMIC
GROW TH AND S T A B IL IT Y IN T H E A EEA O F NATUEALEESO U EC E DEV ELO PM ENT W IT H S P E C IA L E E F E E EN CE TO T H E PO T EN TIA L IM PA CT O F ATOMICEN ERG Y DEVELOPM ENTS ON T H E EN EEG Y , FU EL,
AND PO W E E ECONOM IES OF T H E COUNTEY
K arl M. Mayer, Washington, D. C.
T

he

B

road

A

O b je c t iv e s o f t h e U n it e d S t a t e s
t o m ic - E n e r g y P r o g r a m

The broad objectives of the atomic-energy program in the United
States can perhaps best be stated by quoting from the declaration of
the Atomic Energy Act of 1954:
1. Atomic energy is capable of application for peaceable
as well as m ilitary purposes. I t is, therefore, declared to be
the policy of the United S tates:
(a) The development, use, and control of atomic energy
shall be directed so as to make the maximum contribution to
the general welfare, subject at all times to the paramount
objective of making the maximum contribution to the common
defense and security.
(b) The development, use, and control of atomic energy
shall be directed so as to promote world peace, improve the
general welfare, increase the standard of living, and
strengthen free competition in private enterprise.
The purpose of this paper is to examine, in the light of the afore­
mentioned policy statement, the present status of the atomic-energy
industry in the United States and the direction in which it is likely
to move—keeping in mind the impact of fast or slow rates of atomicenergy growth on the competitive energy, fuel, and power economies
of the country.
In the first part of this paper it will be assumed that the speed
and direction (as well as the incidence and degree of impact) of the
United States atomic-energy industry will essentially be in response
to economic forces. In the latter part of this paper certain changes
in the rules of the game will be considered and the probable effects
of the changes discussed.
W

ork

A

lready

D

one in t h e

F

ie l d

A great deal of basic work has already been done (and continues
to be done) in the field of inquiry under discussion. Because of the
limited amount of time available for the preparation of this paper it
was considered necessary to draw heavily on the basic material which
has already been gathered and analyzed.
97735—57----- 46




701

702

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY
A

n

A

n a l y s is

of

the

U

n it e d

S

tates

E

nergy

E

conom y

Before discussing the potential growth of atomic-energy use in
the United States economy, it will perhaps be desirable to take a brief
look at the market for energy sources before the entry of the new fuel.
Very detailed and comprehensive studies are available on energy
reduction and consumption in the United States (see, for example,
am ett, Lyon, and Colby). Data were taken from Barnett, Lyon,
and Colby, sources in the Federal Power Commission, the Census B u­
reau, and from worksheets prepared by the author in order to draw
up the rough sketch of energy flow in the United States in 1947.
D ata for 1954 are still being revised; however, the sketch given as
figure 1 in this paper will serve the purposes of the present dis­
cussion.
In the preparation of figure 1, from another study, various com­
ponents of energy consumption were systematically removed from
the estimated total production of energy in the United States in 1947
until only that component remained which was consumed by the
manufacturing industries for nonpower purposes (please see the bar
on the extreme rig h t).
The key or legend indicates those components of the energy market
which may feel a more direct impact in the years ahead. The order
in which the components are listed (power, industrial heat, transpor­
tation, and residential-commercial) are roughly ordered according to
the amount of study to which each component has been subjected as
a potential market for atomic energy. A t one time it was generally
held that the above-mentioned order also ranked the various com­
ponent markets according to the degree of attractiveness (from the
standpoint of atomic energy); however, there are many people in the
field who now feel th at this is not true.
In this paper the component markets will be discussed in the order
indicated by the legend of figure 1.

E







F igure 1

AN ESTIMATE OF THE FLOW OF
ENERGY RESOURCES IN THE U.S.
(S h o w n

in B T U

X

ENERGY BLO C S;
containing heat u sed in
m anufacturing

y/A

I O '5 fo r 1 9 4 7 )

to p ro d u c t e le ctric power
for transportation
for re sidential-com m ercial
p u rp o se s

1
1
1

•-1
:
>

r ...... 1
i
L_ _ _ :

Total Energy

Domestic

Domestic

N on-Energy

Manufacturing

Manufacturing

Produced in U.S.

ond Foreign

Consumption

producing

Consumption

1947

Consumption

Fuel
Consumption

Use

704
T

h e

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY
M

arket

P

o t e n t ia l o f

N

uclear

E

nergy in

the

U

n it e d

S tates

Power

The data given in figure 2 (taken from another study) illustrate the
economic setting within which nuclear power finds itself now and will
find itself in the years immediately ahead in the United States. In
other words, if nuclear power can be generated only at costs in excess of
10 or 12 mills per kilowatt-hour, such power is of little economic
interest in the United States.
I f nuclear-power costs can be reduced over time, roughly as illus­
trated by the line given in figure 3, then one can derive a projected
development of nuclear power shaped prim arily by economic forces,
as shown in figure 4. Note that only a very slow growth can be
expected before 1970. Most of the growth will take place at the
expense of steam-electric plants which would otherwise have been
built. In addition, the bulk of the fuel which will be displaced? as
nuclear power enters the market, will be bituminous coal in the United
States.
The data given in figures 5 and 6 indicate the existing and projected
differences between the power-market situation in the United States
and other areas. Whereas there is a large and immediate market for
12- to 15-mill nuclear power in Europe, the market in the United States
is relatively small.




F ig u r e 2
2 6 0

THE COMPETITION MIX
l l l l OLD HYDRO

220
NEW HYDRO

200

ECONOMIC

OLD STEAM

180

}g|gg| NEW STEAM

160

IIHIIII INTERNAL COMBUSTION

GROWTH

140
120
100

AN®

80

STABILITY

NUCLEAR POTENTIAL-BILLION

kwh

240

60
40
20
0

2

3

4

5

T h e M a r k e t P o t e n t ia l fo b N u c l e a r P o w e r




M

6
7
8
9
MILLS PER kwh
at

10

V a r io u s C o s t s

II

12

13

14

15

A -52253-7
of

G e n e r a t io n , 1965

BLOT OF X TC U U .?. C » S t AS K FCKOTtOBi OS TIMS,

a:

LU

m

g
Q

3

I
O
«
0
V

3
1

8
w

«o

e>

A-52140-5-9

g




F ig u r e 3

F ig u r e 4
N u c le o r
G e n e r a tio n a s a %
of Totol U. S. O u tp u t

KWH x 10' s Generated Per Year
35 0 ----

21%

300

18%

250 —

15%

200

12%

AN©

150 —

STABILITY

100

GROWTH

Hydroelectric
■ i Internal Combustion
I I Small Steam
Large Steam

ECONOMIC

PROJECTED ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF /
U.S. NUCLEAR POWER INDUSTRY BY
/
COMPETITIVE PRIME MOVER
/

—

50 —

0




//////////y/z

1965

1970

1975

1980

O

F igube 5
Potentiols Shown in
KWH x I0 9 Per Year
300 i-------------------

THE MARKET POTENTIAL OF
NUCLEAR POWER BY CONTINENT
SHOWN BY GENERATING COST

250

1970
200

E23 Oceania
I I Asia
118 Africo
Europe
! I South America
North America

150

100

50




3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

II

12

13

14

15

16

Cost of Power in Mills Per KWH

17

18

19

20 21

22

23

24

ECONOMIC
GROWTH
AND
STABILITY




F iqtjbe 6

710

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

Industrial heat

The bulk of the boilers sold to the manufacturing industries in the
United States are used to generate heat rather than electric power.
Of course, some boilers are used to make steam which in turn gener­
ates power and later gives up additional energy to supply heat to
industrial processes.
The characteristics of industrial-heat boilers may be somewhat dis­
couraging to nuclear-reactor designers since they must be cheap, small,
and generate small amounts of steam at low pressure. However, if
nuclear reactors can generate steam of the same quality and quantity
at a lower price, they will be able to invade a large and expanding
market. Estimates of how large the industrial-heat market is at each
price level must await further study.
Transportation

A technical-economic study of the potential of nuclear energy in the
field of marine propulsion is currently being undertaken by Stan­
ford Research Institute and the American Standard atomic-energy
division. This work is being sponsored by the Maritime Commis­
sion and the Atomic Energy Commission. Studies in other branches
of transportation have been undertaken by several other groups.
Among people working in this field are Dr. Lyle Borst, of New York
University, who has done work in the possible application of nuclear
energy to rail transportation.
Residential-commercial applications

A relatively small amount of work has been done in this field.
However, Schurr and Marschak did give the subject some attention in
their study, Economic Aspects of Atomic Energy.
C o n c l u s io n s R

e g a r d in g t h e

M

arket

P

o t e n t ia l o f

N

uclear

E

nergy

The conclusions, regardless of application, will, of course, always be
the same. In a greatly simplified form, one can always say th at it is
merely a matter of cost. A t this point a great deal of the simplicity
disappears.
The energy-cost structure varies from area to area, so th at nuclear
energy for a particular application is likely to be competitive in cer­
tain areas sooner than in others. The energy-cost structure in the
United States is such that, although the total market (at all price lev­
els) is large, the size of the market at higher price levels is very small.
F or this reason, the atomic-energy industry in the United States is
likely to grow less rapidly than in other areas if the development of
the industry is determined by economic forces alone. Stated some­
what differently, the likely penetration of nuclear energy into markets
now held by other sources of energy, fossil fuels, and conventional
generating equipment will tend to be smaller in the United States than
in other areas of the world.
In Geneva paper P/475, the author concluded th at nuclear-energy
costs will have to be reduced—nuclear energy cannot expect the costs
of conventional sources of energy to rise substantially in the United
States in the years ahead. In the paragraphs which follow, some
general consideration will be given to the prospects for reducing
nuclear-energy costs.



ECONOMIC GROWTH AN© STABILITY
P

ro spects fo r

N

uclear

E

nergy

C o st R

711

e d u c t io n

Nuclear-energy use in the United States can be expected to grow
faster than a rate such as suggested by figure 4 if costs are reduced at
a rate faster than given in figure 3. The effective costs of nuclear
energy can be reduced by (1) research and technical progress, or by
(2) administrative action. Examples of both methods are suggested
in the paragraphs which follow.
From the standpoint of the powerplant operator, the cost of nu­
clear power is composed of elements which are similar to those which
constitute the cost of generating power by conventional means. In
order to illustrate the similarities (as well as the differences), an
analysis of the cost of power from a large (100-150 megawatt) nuclear
powerplant built in the 1960-70 period is given in table 1. The fig­
ures given in table 1 are given for illustrative purposes only; how­
ever, the magnitudes of the figures are not unreasonable.
T a b l e 1.— A n analysis o f the cost of nuclear power produced by a 100-150-mega­

watt plant in the 1960-70 period
Cost component

Estimated cost
in mills per
kilowatt-hour

P la n t1_____________________________________________________________ __6. 0
Operation and m aintenance__________________________________________ __1. 0
Fuel:
U ranium consum ption_____________________________________________1. 0
Fuel fabrication___________________________________________________1. 5
Fuel reprocessing__________________________________________________2. 0
Fuel-inventory charge___________________________________________
.5
Gross cost of production_____________________________________________ __12. 0
Plutonium credit____________________________________________________ __2. 0
Incentive credit_____________________________________________________ __(2)
Byproduct credit____________________________________________________ __(2)
N et cost of production_______________ _______________________________ __10.0
1 At about $200 per kilowatt of plant capacity, 13.5 percent overall investment charge, and 50 percent
lifetime plant factor.
2 Not known.

A plant cost of around $200 per kilowatt of capacity does not seem
unreasonable in view of the estimates made by such reactor builders
as General Electric, Babcock & Wilcox, and North American Aviation
Corporation. A good estimate of operation charges must await the
actual operation of a commercial nuclear powerplant for some period
of time. I t is possible, of course, to design a nuclear-power station in
such a manner as to reduce plant costs at the expense of higher fuel
and operating costs, or the other way round. Even the fuel cost com­
ponents can be varied by the design of the plant. Uranium consump­
tion can be reduced at the expense of high-cost fabrication and fuel
reprocessing; it may be possible to eliminate fuel-reprocessing costs
(and also plutonium credits) and reduce uranium consumption per
kilowatt-hour through the use of very expensive fuel fabrication tech­
niques, and by discarding long irradiated fuel elements. The opti­
mum cycle and the final level of costs reached by each component will
be determined through a whole series of cost-balancing and cost-trad­
ing activities between cost components, as reflected by a design and
development program.




712

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY
C

o m p e t it iv e

P

o s it io n o f

N

uclear

P

o w er

F or purposes of discussion, let it be assumed th at nuclear power
could be produced at a given place for 10 mills per kilowatt-hour. As­
sume, also, that a comparable amount of power could be produced by
conventional means at the same time ana place for 7 mills per kilo­
watt-hour. Faced with such alternatives, the powerplant executive
would, in all probability, elect to build the conventional plant.1
But let it be assumed that the Government would like to encourage
the construction of the nuclear plant as a means toward fulfilling a
Government objective. The nuclear plant can be built by the Gov­
ernment with public funds, or the Government can provide an in­
centive credit to encourage the construction of the nuclear plant, and
thereby make nuclear power competitive in the eyes of the powerplant
operator. The incentive credit can be given directly by a capital
subsidy or an outright operating grant, or indirectly by one of a num­
ber of means, including the following:
1. W aiving of fuel charges.
2. Interest-free or low-interest-bearing loans.
3. Low charges for use of Government goods and services.
4. Reduction in price of fuel.
5. Increase in the credit for plutonium.
6. Purchase of nuclear powerplant operating reports.
S ig n if ic a n c e

of

I

n c e n t iv e

C r e d it s

Direct subsidies can be designed to encourage nuclear powerplant
construction without affecting powerplant design. However, the
effects of indirect subsidies are much harder to control. I f a govern­
ment wishes to encourage a reactor operating by reducing chemical
processing charges, it discourages entry into the processing field by
the chemical industry. I f the price of fuel is reduced, then designers
will be encouraged to waste fuel and save expensive plant. I t the
price of plutonium is raised, then plant designs and operating cycles
will be shifted accordingly.
From the standpoint of the equipment suppliers and powerplant
operators, it will be extremely difficult to make plans for the future if
indirect incentive credits are used and frequently changed.
Unexpected changes in prices due to policy shifts could cause a great
deal of hardship to the individual manufacturer. However, no busi­
ness enterprise is wholly immune from such hazards; most businesses
are affected to some degree by changes in taxes, tariffs, tolls, and regu­
lations resulting from Government policy decisions.
R

e l a t io n s h ip o f

P

r ic e t o

C o st

Some have suggested th at Government prices for goods and services
should be made equal to their costs—but to which costs? Let it be
1 The author recently conducted a survey among leading powerplant executives of powerproducing organizations In the southern United States. I t w as found th a t the power
executives were of the opinion t h a t : (1) Nuclear and conventional power generation costs
should be figured on the same basis (1 3 -1 5 percent overall investm ent charge; 5 0-60
percent lifetim e plant factor, e tc.). (2 ) Nuclear plants should be Installed only when
and i f the cost of nuclear power is equal to or less than the cost of conventional power
on a comparable basis.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

713

assumed that irradiated fuel from many nuclear powerplants will
be reprocessed in a Central Government chemical reprocessing plant.
The basis for pricing could be any one of the following costs:
1. Average cost at present plant throughput.
2. Average cost at optimum plant throughput.
3. Average cost at maximum plant throughput.
4. Marginal cost at present plant throughput.
5. Marginal cost at maximum plant throughput.
Each price would have different advantages and disadvantages, and
a different set of impacts. I t is important, therefore, that each manu­
facturer become familiar with the pricing policies and bases of the
Government before becoming heavily committed in any particular
direction (or with any particular reactor type) in the nuclear-power
field.
C o n c l u s io n s

On the basis of facts developed by studies mentioned in this paper
and by other studies in the field it is most difficult to prove an economic
need for nuclear energy in the United States.
I f one seeks to prove a need for nuclear energy now in order to
conserve valuable, limited fossil fuels, he must in turn prove that the
fossil fuel saved now will be more valuable in the future than the
uranium, stainless steel, and zirconium used now—and thereby effec­
tively not available in the future. Stated somewhat differently, one
must prove that the higher fuel cost or expenditure now will be more
than offset by even higher fuel revenues in the future.
I t might be easier to show that nuclear-power development should
be encouraged because the additional cost associated with nuclearpower generation will be more than offset by the additional non­
power-economic benefits brought to the country or to a particular re­
gion. F or example, the presence of a nuclear-power industry in a
particular State (or in the country as a whole) might attract sufficient
ancillary economic activity to justify the payment of a subsidy by the
shareholders of the company, by the ratepayers of the system, or by
the taxpayers of the State.
I t might, on the other hand, be easier to prove a future economic
need for nuclear energy in terms of the economic benefits which will
accrue to the American economy should the United States become a
nuclear workshop supplying reactors to all parts of the world as nu­
clear power becomes competitive with power generated from local,
conventional resources. In this case it might be held that the dollars
invested today in the nuclear-energy field will be returned many times
over in the future. Persons holding this position would, in the final
analysis, also have to hold that public or private dollars invested in
this direction will show a greater social or private return than an
equivalent sum invested in any other available direction.
I f one determines that there is a noneconomic need (such as inter­
national prestige) to encourage or expand the use of nuclear energy,
then there is a cost involved and either or both of two action courses
are suggested: Government construction and/or subsidies for private
construction. I t is beyond the scope of this paper to discuss the rela­
tive merits of either of these courses of action; however, it is clear
that some concrete aid (other than the removal of restrictive rules,



714

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

regulations, and laws) is called for if the industry is to be encouraged.
Subsidies for encouragement can come from such groups as share­
holders, ratepayers, or taxpayers.
I f the subsidy rather than the public construction course is taken,
then there are many economic arguments which tend to favor the use
of a direct subsidy or capital grant even though such action may be
politically difficult to take. In the end, it will produce the same effect
at a lower overall cost.
The amount of direct subsidy or capital grant needed to encourage
a given, desired amount of activity in the nuclear-energy field is
directly proportional to the competitive gap between nuclear and nonnuclear-iuel costs. This suggests that consideration m ight be given
to the granting of subsidies to United States firms engaged in nuclearenergy activities in high-fuel-cost areas overseas.