View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ECONOMY AND EFFICIENCY IN GOVERNMENT
EXPENDITURES

SO M E D E V IC E S F O R IN C R E A S IN G E F F IC IE N C Y IN
G O V E R N M E N T E X P E N D IT U R E
O . H. Brownlee, professor o f economics, University o f Minnesota
This paper treats what must be considered some comparatively
minor issues associated with government spending. It is concerned
with how to determine the levels o f some o f the services that govern­
ment ought to provide and how such services should be produced.
Its proposals are applicable to State and local as well as Federal
expenditures. I am almost certain that other participants in this
study w ill point out that solutions to many o f the central problems
o f public expenditure policy are essentially matters o f personal taste
on which unanimous agreement is not to be expected. A t the present
time, I am not prepared to debate this position. Instead, I shall deal
with some problems whose solutions should not be arbitrary ones, even
though the changes in expenditures that would follow from applying
them would look small in comparison with current levels o f spend­
ing.
.
.
.
.
The treatment provided does not point out in detail how the princi­
ples proposed might be applied. I shall sketch the applicability for
a few examples. These examples may appear to be extreme cases
and are chosen to demonstrate clearly the points I am trying to make.
These proposals when applied might prompt us to do some things in
ways much different from those currently employed.
Although I shall argue that demand and supply relations can guide
us more in determining government expenditure than currently is
the usage, this argument does not support either those who believe
that the best government is the one that does least nor those who believe
that the scope o f governmental activities should be expanded. In
many areas we don’t know whether government is spending too little
or too much— even though such questions could be answered unambig­
uously— because we have not obtained relevant inform ation nor em­
ployed decision-making procedures which would permit us to use the
relevant data.
G

overnm ent

S

p e n d in g

to

P

r o v id e

I

S

e r v ic e s

and

to

R

e d is t r ib u t e

ncom e

Government spends to provide services and to m odify the dis­
tribution o f income from that which would prevail if it were deter­
mined only by the pattern o f resource ownership and resource prices.
The extent to which income should be redistributed— the tax and ex­




223

224

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

penditure pattern together being important instruments of redis­
tribution—is essentially an ethical problem and will not be discussed
here.
Goods and services that should be provided by government

The goods and services whose provision to the population should be
of interest to government and the goods and services which govern­
ment should produce need not be the same things. The first group
includes things whose costs should be-covered to some extent from
tax revenues, although the organization of the production of these
things might be left completely to private enterprise. The things
whose provision to the population is a legitimate governmental con­
cern includes those that one might call “socially beneficial.” A d­
ditional consumption of such a good or service by one person increases
the welfare of other persons as well as that of the immediate consumer.
Elementary school education is a service generally believed to be of
this kind. Because Smith’s children do not capture all of the benefits
of becoming literate and perhaps learning how to think and thus
eventually becoming better citizens than would be the case if they
were without elementary education, Jones is willing to contribute
toward the education of the Smith children, i. e., to support govern­
mental expenditure for such education. I t is believed that if ele­
mentary school education were allocated among the population in the
same manner as steak or beer, too little of it would be produced.
Other instances of goods or services that are socially beneficial in­
clude services to check the spread of communicable diseases and
various services associated with sanitation—sewage and garbage dis­
posal, for example.
A second category of goods and services in whose provision gov­
ernment should be interested might be called public goods,1 those
which can be consumed by one person without any reduction in the
amounts available to other persons. For example, a radio or television
transmission can be received by an additional receiving set without
affecting the reception of other receivers; one’s view of a public monu­
ment is independent of the number of persons who have seen it pre­
viously.
Government’s interest in socially beneficial goods is to see that their
consumption is larger than would be the case if they were distributed
in the same manner as other goods. This objective can be attained
by subsidizing producers or by giving grants to consumers conditional
upon these grants being used to purchase such goods or services.
Either approach requires governmental spending. The interest of
government in public goods also is akin to seeing that more is pro­
duced than would be the case if they were privately produced'and
sold. I t costs something to produce and disseminate radio programs.
Yet the best way of collecting to cover these costs is not necessarily
to charge each listener according to the amount he listens but rather
to charge him a flat fee for the opportunity to receive radio reception.
Insofar as government may act as the intermediary in collecting and
dispersing funds, government expenditure is involved.
1 Refer to Paul A. Samuelson, The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure, The Review of
Econom ics and S tatistics, XXXVI, pp. 887^389.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

225

Goods and services that should be produced by government
Whether government should produce goods and services— socially
beneficial ones, public goods, or other goods— is simply a question o f
whether governmental organization o f production will result in a
iri ven amount being produced at a lower cost than would be achieved
by private producers. Thus, there is no inherent reason for a good
or service to be produced by government, even though this good is
freely distributed by government, i f private producers can produce
it at less cost; nor is there any reason why government should not
produce any good or service and sell it in the market, even though
this commodity has been produced privately, if it can do so at less
cost than private producers.
In this paper I shall avoid the hardest problems— those associated
with how much production there should be o f public goods and goods
with social benefits. Instead I shall deal with some o f the problems
o f trying to assure that the costs o f producing whatever outputs
are chosen is a minimum, some o f the devices that can be used fo r
determining the outputs o f goods that are neither public goods nor
socially beneficial but in the production o f which government has
definite advantages, and with some considerations in determining
whether a good is socially beneficial.
M

ore

C

W

o sts

id e s p r e a d
of

S

U

se

of

e r v ic e s i n

W

C o n t r a c t i n g a s a D e v ic e f o r L o w e r in g
h ic h G o v e r n m en t H as a n I n ter est

In the United States it is widely believed that with both types
o f producers having access to the same technology and the same mar­
ket inform ation, private producers will produce more efficiently than
government. There is relatively little pressure for government to
take over the production o f steel or autos or most other goods and
services that are clearly neither socially beneficial nor public goods.
A foundation fo r this belief might be that i f decision makers are
rewarded (or penalized) in accordance with the quality o f the deci­
sions which they make, the quality o f decision making will be better
than if rewards and quality o f decisions are not closely related.
Where profit is a good index o f the quality o f the decision, the results
o f private producers’ decisions in organizing production are gen­
erally accepted.
In many areas, government has chosen to specify the amount o f
a product"to be produced and to let private producers produce the
product for government. The military does not produce its own
planes, tanks, etc.; the postal service hires railways and airlines to
carry m ail; some school districts do not operate their own school
buses, etc. The line between where government should buy goods
and services and where it should produce them itself appears to have
been arbitrarily drawn. I f the contention that private producers
can produce more efficiently is correct, there are opportunities for
reducing costs o f government— although the savings may not be
large— through more widespread application o f the practice o f gov­
ernment specifying the task to be accomplished and letting private
producers bid fo r the job. F or example, fire protection, garbage col­
lection, mail collection and delivery, and even many law-enforcement
activities (such as checking parking violations and collecting taxes)
might be contracted to private agencies.



226

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

One cannot forecast accurately the outcome of more widespread ap­
plication of contracting. There should be reductions in costs of
doing some of the things now done by government. But total ex­
penditure might be increased. F or example, with better garbage
collection at the same cost as at present or the same kind of garbage
collection at lower cost, people might demand more of it than cur­
rently is being obtained. Rather than try to guess what the expend­
iture pattern would be, let me try to indicate how more widespread
use of contracting might be made by reference to an extreme case.
One function which government performs is th at of levying and
collecting taxes, the procedure whereby a person may determine
his tax liability having been stated basically by legislation. There
are, of course, what many people call “inequities” in the tax structure
that are the results of legislation. However, there are others that
are essentially administrative—in the assessment of property for tax
purposes and in the undercollection of income taxes, particularly
from self-employed persons. I t is claimed that these could be rem­
edied by devoting more resources to tax collection, yet there is no
agreement as to how much more should be devoted to this purpose.
One way of determining this would be to sell the right to collect
a certain tax in a particular area. I f taxpayers have adequate
recourse to opportunities to prove their true tax liabilities so that
they will not pay more than legally prescribed and if the right
to collect a tax sells for more than the net revenues (gross collec­
tions minus collection costs) obtained by government, greater effi­
ciency in tax collection would have been achieved. The tax “farm ­
ers” (as they were called in earlier times when such procedures were
followed) would be organizing their resources more efficiently than
has government in collecting a given amount of revenue and/or de­
voting more nearly the correct amount of resources to their function.
I t might be noted that such a move might prompt legislation such
that taxpayers could more unambiguously determine their tax lia­
bilities and that there should be virtually no bribery of tax collectors.
S

o c ia l l y

B

e n e f ic ia l

G

oods a n d

S

e r v ic e s

There is not complete agreement with respect to precisely which
goods and services are socially beneficial. However, some of this
disagreement is the result of failing to distinguish between benefits
that can be rewarded through the market and those th at cannot. F or
example, investment in plant and equipment th at will earn enough to
pay interest and amortization costs is socially beneficial in that it
results in a given amount of product being sold at a lower cost. How­
ever, the making of such an investment is rewarded through the
market. I f a person learns to understand things that improve his
decision-making ability as a citizen but do not increase his market­
able skills, this act is not rewarded through the market. Only the
latter kind of action warrants expenditure as a socially beneficial
action. I f there are unnatural impediments to investment th at pre­
vent the first kind of action from being carried out, such impedi­
ments can be removed by the establishment of governmental agen­
cies—for regulation or for making loans, for example—whose
expenditures are relatively insignificant.



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

227

Furthermore, as already has been indicated, goods or services that
are socially beneficial need not be produced by government. Unless
the government is interested in controlling the curriculum, the ap­
propriate stimulation to the production o f elementary education could
be provided by grants to families cdriditio'n&l upon such grants being
used fo r elementary schooling. Private producers could operate the
schools and collect for their services through fees.
A n appraisal o f current governmental aids to higher education p ro­
vides an opportunity to illustrate a confusion in popular notions o f so­
cially beneficial goods. Governmental aids to education are extended
not only to elementary schooling but to secondary school training and
so-called higher education— the educational services provided by col­
leges and universities. Yet, it cannot be argued that training a person
to be an accountant, an engineer, an embalmer or a mathematician or
to speak French brings significant social benefits. It is true that in­
creasing the number o f accountants, engineers, etc., reduces the prices
fo r the services which they produce. But im proving technology or
increasing the amount o f capital employed in producing varkjus goods
and services also reduces their prices. Investment in higher education
does not differ fundamentally from any other form o f investment in
the distribution o f its returns among the persons making the invest­
ment and others. I f a rationalization, consistent with our general
views as to how resource allocation should be made, were to be pro­
vided fo r public support to higher education, this rationalization
might be that existing market arrangements make it possible for us to
borrow to purchase a farm, a factory, or an oil well, but that borrow ­
ing to purchase a college education usually cannot be accomplished
through form al financial channels. Investment in higher education
thus would be too small, if we left its determination to the same forces
as are permitted to determine other investment decisions. One way to
encourage more investment in higher education is to reduce its price
through governmental grants to some colleges and universities.
However, if it is agreed that we should be interested primarily in
assuring that individuals may invest in themselves through training
on the same terms as they may invest in other assets, this objective
can be achieved by creating lending institutions for making loans to
purchase education— perhaps in creating an F H A fo r college educa­
tions. Such institutions could require, considerably less Government
expenditure than do current arrangements— in the long run they need
not require a n y ; and, they could result in a better allocation o f educa­
tional opportunity than do present institutions. A t the present time,
some persons who would not buy a college education i f they had the
financial resources and had to pay the fu ll costs attend some Statesupported institutions. Others who would buy a college education if
they could borrow the financial resources and had to pay the full costs
cannot attend college. A loan program, in lieu o f present form s o f
State support, would permit the second group o f individuals to attend
college, and— i f educational training were priced at cost— would re­
sult m the training o f fewer individuals in the first group. Govern­
mental operation o f institutions o f higher learning might continue
under the proposed arrangement. But, the reasons for such operation
are the same as those for State operation o f grocery stores, filling sta­
tions, etc.



228

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

I t should be noted th at pricing higher education at cost would per­
m it us to determine whether too much or too little is being produced.
When a good or service is not socially beneficial and is priced below
cost, the fact th at more of this good or service is demanded than is
available is not sufficient to claim th at a true shortage exists. In the
long run, there would be “shortages” (excess demand) of all such
goods and services if they were priced in this manner. Information
about the quantities of socially beneficial goods and services that
would be purchased at various prices also is required to determine
how much should be produced. Because, at some arbitrary price,
there is excess demand for such a good or service does not necessarily
mean that too little is available. Excess demand for this good also
may mean only that the price is too low.
P

u t t in g

D

e c is io n s

S

W

it h

upply

R

espec t to

and

D

em and

H

ig h w a y

B

S

e r v ic e s o n a

a s is

Among the goods in which government should act as collector and
disperser—if not producer—are those in which costs of collecting
from each user in accordance with the amounts used are high relative
to production costs. W ater or electricity would be such a good, if
either good were cheap but meters were very expensive. A classic
example is highway services. W ith the exception of a few limited
access highways and bridges, the costs to private producers of col­
lecting from highway users directly in accordance with use are so
high relative to construction and maintenance costs that unless gov­
ernment provided highways and streets, there would be too few of
them.
For more than three decades, there has been much argument re­
lating to how much should be spent on highways and who should
pay the bill. The question of who should pay the bill hinges on
whether highway service is socially beneficial. Although improved
highways cut transport costs and hence the prices of things con­
sumed by persons not directly using the highways, there are many
other activities that result in reduced prices and for which no special
means of compensation are provided. Except for potential m ilitary
uses of the highways—for which the m ilitary services should pay—
the case for attributing social benefits to highway services is a weak
one.
In addition to attributing social benefits to highways, further re­
sistance to conceptually applying the usual market criteria to deter­
mining how much of such service should be produced has arisen from
viewing highway services as public goods. I f using a highway im­
posed no maintenance costs and if there existed no problems of high­
way congestion, such a view might be legitimate. However, it is not
economic to construct highways so th at there are not maintenance
costs (at least for some vehicles), and street and highway congestion
is one of our most widely discussed problems. I f difference in qual­
ity of service is considered—quality might be defined in terms of op­
portunity to travel at a certain speed, with a certain comfort and some
specified probability of accident—much of the service offered by the
street and highway system is not a public good.



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

229

I f it is agreed that highway services are neither socially beneficial
nor public goods it would be desirable to try to ration these services
among users and to determine the amounts th at should be produced
in the same general way as these problems are solved for other goods.
The practical problems are those of attaching appropriate prices to
highway services, collecting from highway users according to the
amounts of each of the services used and employing highway-use
data to determine the amounts of roads of various qualities to con­
struct.
Some of these problems have been explored in more detail else­
w here2 and I will state only some of the implications of these ex­
plorations here. Collecting from highway users in accordance with
the amount of service obtained can be accomplished by reliance upon
motor-fuels taxes for passengers’ care with supplementary weightdistance taxes for trucks and buses. Revenues could be allocated to
each section of the highway system in accordance with the traffic
pattern and comparisons of revenues and costs would be employed
to guide the construction and maintenance patterns. Encourage­
ment to toll roads would be provided by imputing revenues to them
in the same fashion as for other roads. Thus, decisions about how
much of various kinds of highway service to provide could be based
on whether such changes would pay. We would be able to know
more clearly than we can at the present time how adequate is our
highway system.
S

um m ary

The devices that have been suggested in this paper—more wide­
spread use of contracting in the production of services provided by
government, a loan program to prospective college students rather
than an expanded State role in the production of higher education,
and the provision of highway services in accordance with market cri­
teria—are all designed to make it possible for us to know more ac­
curately whether the right amounts of certain kinds of services are
being provided and if the least-cost methods for providing various
amounts are being employed. The changes in government expendi­
tures th at would result from using such devices might not be large, but
some improvement in resource use would result.
2 See O. H. Brownlee and W alter W. Heller, Highway F inancing and Development,
American Economic Review, May 1956, pp. 232-250.