View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ANTICYCLICAL EXPENDITURE VARIATION
W alter Froehlich, professor of economics, Robert A. Johnston College
of Business Administration, Marquette University
Relief payments and public works during bad times can be traced
back through a long history. A t least toward the end of the great
depression, a more systematic development of fiscal policy in order
to stabilize the performance of the economy has been tried. In good
times business expands, spending more than its revenues. Therefore,
business must borrow, partly from the banking system, or must in
other ways acquire additional funds. In bad times business contracts;
that is, spends less than its revenues. Fiscal policy attempts as nearly
as possible to stabilize the flow of expenditure in the economy and
thus presumably the level of economic performance as a whole. Thus,
government spending must become compensatory spending moving
in the opposite direction as business spending moves. Government
revenues should be greater than expenditure in prosperity, less than
expenditure in depression.
During the last decades, we have become more aware of a great
number of related problems. There is a delicate interdependence of
fiscal and monetary measures. Moreover, fiscal policy is not only
expenditure policy. The 1955 papers and hearings before the Sub­
committee on Tax Policy of the Joint Committee on the Economic
Report have considered tax policy. Debt management has become
more relevant because of the size of the debt and the necessary amount
of yearly refunding.
I t is widely held th at the major contribution of monetary policy
is to be expected during prosperity and that the main contribution
of fiscal policy is to be expected during depression. Yet, the prevailing
economic situation of the last 15 years makes it imperative that the
possible contribution of fiscal policy in times of prosperity and infla­
tion be more fully explored. The present situation has been called
an uneasy triangle. Full employment, price stability, and absence of
direct controls (over wages and/or prices) are not easy to achieve
simultaneously. Full employment and price stability may be had, per­
haps, at the price of direct controls—with far-reaching adverse eco­
nomic and sociopolitical consequences—but direct controls are, at
least in peacetime, ineffective and on the whole destructive of our
economic, social, and political system. Price stability and freedom
from controls may be achieved, perhaps, at a more modest level of
employment—again with far-reaching adverse economic and socio­
political consequences. H igh level employment without direct controls
may involve creeping inflation. The indirect and extended conse­
quences of prolonged creeping inflation have not yet been fully ex­
plored. To this present situation, we have to apply expenditure
policy. A high rate of growth likely does ease conflicts. In addition,



343

344

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

measures of market policy like making the market structure more
competitive, prices more sensitive, may be helpful.
Finally, we have become increasingly conscious of the fact that
economic analysis cannot simply relate the large aggregates and hope
to find useful, stable relationships between them. Such an analysis
would be at best only the first step. We shall have to strive at more
disaggregation, at consideration of smaller, more restricted aggre­
gates having more complicated and possibly less stable relationships
between them.
Stabilization shall refer throughout this paper to the short period
of essentially cyclical variation as contrasted to problems of growth
or of stagnation. Existence of cyclical patterns is assumed and no
inquiry is intended into the length, regularity, type, and recognition
of these fluctuations. Stabilization entails prim arily stabilization of
output and of employment, not prim arily of prices. The relation of
stability to growth has been discussed in preceding papers. Possibly,
too much insistence on stability (absence of cyclical variations) may
affect unfavorably the rate of growth. Questions of the immediate
future will also be excluded from this paper as they have been dis­
cussed in hearings before this committee in June 1957.
In order to avoid overlapping and repetition as far as possible I
shall consider exclusively the expenditure aspects of Federal fiscal
policy in regard to short-run (anticyclical) stabilization, th at is, m iti­
gation of cyclical fluctuations in output and employment. Three
areas will be touched upon:
1. Some relevant aspects and measurements of aggregate
output and employment as yardsticks of expenditure policy.
2. Some relevant aspects and measurements of expenditure and
expenditure change in regard to anticyclical policy.
3. Some relevant criteria and measures of repercussions of
expenditure change in regard to short-run stabilization.
J
N

a t io n a l

I

ncom e

and

E

m plo y m en t

S

as

M

easures

of

S

h o r t-R u n

t a b il iz a t io n

Concepts of aggregate output and equivalent concepts of aggregate
income serve different and possible conflicting purposes. We can, of
course, construct simply convenient pragmatic devices for a study of
economic relations. But when we look at national income (the money
equivalent of output) as a measurable achievement, we have in mind
the net yield of economic arrangements in the sense that more income
means that people are better off. Changes in the purchasing power of
monejr should be taken into consideration. Much thought has been
given in the literature to the index number problem. I t seems, though,
that the choice between different index numbers is not of major prac­
tical importance. Real income (as a rule per capita) is a widely
accepted measure of economic performance. I t would be outside the
scope of this investigation to discuss difficulties which arise from com­
paring incomes under different social systems, in fully developed and
underdeveloped countries or in countries of very different income
distribution. Yet in connection with public finance other pertinent
problems arise.
F irst let us consider a minor technical problem. We arrive at
national income by subtracting from gross national product capital



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

345

consumption allowances and indirect business taxes. This treatment
of the latter means that the measured achievement (national income) is
different according to whether it is financed by these indirect business
taxes or by a corporate income tax. In fact it is rather likely th at
both taxes are frequently shifted in a very similar way. I t is very
doubtful whether the different manner of taxation means a significant
difference in the price level. I f we justify deduction of indirect busi­
ness taxes because they supposedly are equivalent to the value of gov­
ernment services to business and hence must be deducted in order to
avoid double counting, the arbitrariness of such an evaluation is only
too apparent. Yet, as in the short run the structure of the tax system
probably does not change greatly, this question may be dismissed as
being of minor importance.
There is, though, a more fundamental difficulty, which cannot be
overcome. We consider the “product” of government a part of and an
addition to the gross national product. A final purchase is, according
to customary terminology, determinative for the national product and
income aggregates. A final purchase, that is a purchase not for resale
by the individual, is either one for consumption (and thus indicative
of anticipated satisfaction from consumption directly) or for final
investment (and thus indicative of anticipated satisfaction through
the roundabout process provided by investment). This relation to
“satisfaction” cannot be ascertained for government purchases of goods
and services. In the absence of evaluation by a market, that is of
market prices, a valuation at cost is a customary and wise business
practice leaving the correction one way or the other to the final realiza­
tion through future action in a market. Such final correction is miss­
ing if we evaluate the government product at cost. The judgment of
the economic subject that cost spent by him measures approximately
the expected advantage to the individual until corrected by later real­
ization is basically a useful assumption. Extension of such reasoning
in order to maintain that cost incurred by the Government approxi­
mates the value of the services to the citizenry never to be corrected by
the action of buyers and sellers in any market, generates grave doubt.
This is as true for democratic as it is for totalitarian government.
Elections serve many other complex functions; they cannot be con­
sidered ratifying specific government spending by every individual
taxpayer. Proposals have been made to evaluate the government
product. I t has also been proposed to distinguish government services
which may satisfy the individual citizen and which he would pre­
sumably buy if they were offered in a market and consider only those
an addition to the gross national product. Health services are an ex­
ample. The bulk of other services which are, perhaps, more neces­
sary, as for example maintaining the framework of society through
security measures, may not qualify under such a test.
The difficulty of evaluation and classification are quite clearly not
mere matters of statistical procedure. The statistical details of which
expenditure goes or does not go into making gross national product
as defined by the Department of Commerce can be learned from the
estimates of Federal receipts and expenditures published by the De­
partment.1 I t has been proposed that for the purpose of making
1 See Young, The Government Sector. A Reconciliation of A lternative Budget Concepts.
Conference on Research in Income and Wealth, Studies in Income and W ealth, vol. XX.
Princeton, 1957.




346

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

welfare judgments we should use two indexes, one for private services
and private consumption using a market price index as deflator, and
another for “final collective welfare goods” using a cost index as
deflator. The two subtotals cannot be added up in a meaningful way
for measures of welfare. They should better be regarded as providing
some evidence, which people may use to assist them to make welfare
judgments.2 The usefulness of customary national income aggregates
at least for welfare purposes must be doubted. Where the problem is
whether increased government expenditures are helpful in some way,
the use of government expenditures as measure of income creation at
cost, that is as measure of achievement, simply begs all questions. An
evaluation of government product is at best a difficult and frequently
an arbitrary value judgment. To include some and to exclude other
services according to whether they are similar to privately furnished
services is quite unsatisfactory. Certainly, government activity does
frequently increase human welfare, satisfy what one may call collec­
tive wants. In fact, many government services (like national defense)
are of overriding importance, but their importance cannot be simply
measured for our purposes in the manner appropriate to the measure­
ment of the private sector of national income. Public expenditure
may, in addition, indirectly lead to increased private consumption and
possibly private investment, though overwhelming negative effects on
private investment in real terms are also possible.. These indirect
effects come about over a prolonged period of time; they cannot easily
be measured or predicted as to size. I t is frequently uncertain whether
these total indirect effects are negative or positive, smaller or larger
than the government expenditure. This is especially true when the
expenditures are made during a time of relatively high level of em­
ployment or if they are financed from tax receipts. If, on the other
hand, national income is only meant to denote a goal of a certain
amount of employment opportunities at certain wage rates, then any
national-income figure does not mean more than the corresponding
employment figure. To state the employment figure directly is p ref­
erable, if only for greater clarity.
The Employment Act of 1946 is on solid ground to consider em­
ployment directly as a measure of economic stabilization. Measures
of unemployment are somewhat less reliable than measures of em­
ployment. The former require measurement of the labor force as
well as of employment with a possible statistical bias in opposite
directions.
Defining full employment as the situation where more vacancies
than unemployed exist in the aggregate or the like (unfilled vacancies
approach) leads to setting required employment at a figure where seri­
ous inflationary pressure and other distorting influences will be over­
whelming. The serious shortcomings of this type of definition do not
have to be discussed any more. Full employment can also be defined
as the degree of employment th at exists when the aggregate demand
for commodities is at the highest level that is compatible with the
condition that demand at existing prices (or at the prices of the last
previous peak) is balanced by current supply or the like (price ap­
proach). This type of definition is of small help for policy forma* I. D. M. Little, A Critique of Welfare Economics, Oxford, 1950.



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

347

tion because full employment as defined, may be reached at a very low
level of unemployment (Lerner’s high level full employment) or
quite possibly at a very high level of unemployment (Lerner’s
low level full employment). The latter situation may be caused by
rigidities, bottlenecks, monopoly situations in business and labor, and
so forth. Price rises sufficient to cause price level rises may, indeed,
start at a fairly low level of employment. Reliance on large aggre­
gates and their average behavior may be misleading. We may have
to consider the different behavior of industrial and agricultural
prices, of prices of manufactured goods and services, etc. I t bears
investigation whether monetary and fiscal policy can well stabi­
lize price levels if prices in large areas are administered and hence less
responsive to overall measures. In this case at least a very great,
more than proportional, impact on the responsive, sensitive prices in
the more competitive sector of the economy may be needed to reach
any desired overall level. I t seems that in the balancing of objectives
under the Employment Act of 1946, maintenance of a certain price
level must not be a necessarily overriding consideration.
The market structure in the markets for the outputs, and the work­
ings of the institutional setup of employment influence employment
and wages and have to be considered every time, especially if they do
not stay invariant over the change. Generally speaking, there will
be less unemployment in a growing economy than in a stationary
one. On the other hand, a growing economy requires changes and a
high level of investment. For that reason, frictional unemployment
due to industrial and regional change will be relatively high. This
type of unemployment in a growing economy such as ours has been
estimated as high as 4 percent of the labor force. This kind of unem­
ployment cannot properly and successfully be alleviated by overall
monetary—fiscal measures.
We have to be satisfied with the use of benchmarks, guideposts,
or similar rules of thumb. In fact, we do not need to establish a single
benchmark for full or maximum employment, W hat we need are
several benchmarks, every one denoting a number of unemployed for
a stated period of time. The term “unemployed” may have in every
case a different definition. Every benchmark should give us an oc­
casion to consider when certain anticyclical expenditure measures
ought to be started. We may use a figure or a percentage, but we have
to be careful which definition of unemployment we relate to th at figure
or percentage. Different definitions of unemployment can, perhaps,
be used equally well in connection with different benchmarks. Differ­
ent benchmarks might be in place for considering more time-con­
suming legislative action and for starting swifter administrative
action. The most important signpost is the figure of unemployed re­
quired for large-scale public works to be financed largely by budgetary
deficits. There must also be signposts developed for restrictive gov­
ernment action in an employment situation where inflationary pres­
sure becomes too great.
In general, if the public understands and approves governmental
action, such publicly supported action is likely to be more effective.
Nevertheless, it does not necessarily follow from these premises th at
contemplated tentative benchmarks should be made available to the
general public. The situation is somewhat though not fully simi­



348

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

lar to the situation common to monetary policy. As a rule a policy
is the more effective the less the general public knows in advance the
means available to and the specific measure of, let us say, the
Open Market Committee of the Federal Reserve System, and there­
fore is not able successfully to counterspeculate. The tentative na­
ture of our knowledge may also be a good reason not to state goals
publicly in advance.3
Presently, our knowledge of desired achievement, means, time, and
dosage is much too uncertain to consider the enactment of programs
to be started automatically at the reaching of a certain benchmark
(formula flexibility). Foreign experience in that matter seems in­
conclusive and on many grounds not applicable to the United States.
M

ea surem ent

P

or E

x p e n d it u r e s a n d

u rpo se o p

S

hort

R

un

E
S

x p e n d it u r e

C

h a n g e s for

t a b il iz a t io n

Measurement of public expenditure (or more specifically of Fed­
eral public expenditure) is dependent on the purpose to which we
want to apply the result. We are presently concerned with spending
for stabilization. F or stabilization purposes the actual cash flow
will be of primary importance. The administrative (conventional)
budget is of little help. A statement of receipts from and payments
to the public (consolidated-cash budget) will be of greater signifi­
cance. The Bureau of the Budget as well as the Treasury provides
us with statements of this kind. There are a number of steps in
the process of spending that can be distinguished; further refine­
ments may easily be made.
1. Statutory enactments and administrative action, which will lead
in due time to expenditure; e. g., a civil servant is hired or a soldier
joins the Armed Forces. They will in due course acquire rights or
at any rate will have to receive benefits of some kind. Authority to
make contracts may exist preceding appropriations as for example in
m ilitary procurement and in construction. Government enterprises
may have authority to spend money they have been authorized to bor­
row from the Treasury or from the public without further appro­
priations.
2. Appropriations proper (authority to obligate and to spend).
3. Actual administrative incurring of obligations or making of
commitments.
4. Actual production of goods for the Government, which as a rule
leads to private expenditures in producing them.
5. Actual delivery of goods and services to the Government where­
by claims against the Government arise.
6. Payments actually made under appropriations (outlays). These
come about under previously incurred obligations but also without
previous obligation.
Unobligated obligational authority carried over as well as unspent
obligated appropriations carried over complicate the budgetary pic­
ture ; so do—to a much smaller extent—supplementary and deficiency
appropriations.
There is a wide and growing range of Government activities, the
exact classification of which may be somewhat in doubt but which
3 Sainuelson in Colm, ed.. The Employment Act, P a st and Future, W ashington, 1956.




ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

349

should be included with the expenditures. In a technical sense, loan
guaranties (e. g., Federal Housing Administration, Veteran’s Admin­
istration) are not expenditures. As the Government as a rule does
not have to reimburse anybody due to the guaranty, this guaranty
will not even lead to a governmental expenditure. Such activity
might be considered stimulating, promoting, making possible private
expenditure. But for the purposes of stabilization these activities
should be treated like governmental expenditures. The same is true
for long term leases of, for example, specially built postal and office
facilities. Technically only the rental is an expenditure, but the
economic effect is the same as if the Government had spent the money
to build the facilities. Abatement of taxes due to carryback provi­
sions should be considered an expenditure, because the tax reduction
is due to facts which have largely occurred after the tax has been paid
which is now reduced by the carryback of losses. Tax refunds due to
tax litigation, though they also do improve the cash situation of the
recipient and are paid out of appropriated funds, may better be
treated as decreasing receipts from taxes.4
Every one of the steps enumerated above has economic consequences.
Some effects will occur during the earlier stages in anticipation of
expected government expenditure, some repercussions will come about
after the receipts from government are respent by the recipients. The
former effects are not easily treated in a formal manner, as it happens
frequently with attempts at formal treatment of expectations. P ri­
vately financed deficit expenditure on government account (to borrow
a term Professor H art has used in the June hearings) is important
in military procurement, especially in the earlier stages of industrial
planning and of preparation of actual production.
Control of spending is divided between the legislative and executive
power. Congressional control ends as a rule with appropriation.
This control is further complicated by unused and carryover obligational authority and spending authority. Administrative control con­
cerns itself with the steps following appropriation.
Generally speaking a step that makes very likely the occurrence of
those following it will be the most important step. Much depends on
when anticipatory action can and will be taken. An appropriation
that conforms to a willingness of the administration to spend it will
be an important step. Sometimes the letting of contracts will have
the strongest impact leading to anticipatory private spending. Some­
times only actual expenditure will count. The relative importance of
every step is different according to circumstances. Anticipatory p ri­
vate spending and anticipatory private use of resources, not only the
periods of income propagation following the expenditures, have to be
considered. Expenditurelike activities (guaranties, etc.) may be very
important. The use of large aggregates and the use of single time
points to judge the process will lead to serious oversimplification.
Variation of government expenditure can be measured in terms of
flexibility. Flexibility may mean an absolute (dollar) change or a
percentage change relating government expenditure and an external
variable (like gross national product or employment). As discussed
above expenditure in the wider sense may be measured at any of the
4 See on these problems C. Lowell Harris, The Journal of Finance, 1954.
97735— 5T------ 24




350

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

steps outlined above, though actual spending is the most important
step; the relevance of the large aggregates to which expenditure is to be
related is also open to doubt. The change is usually measured without
reference to the time which has to elapse before the measured result
comes about, though lags are important.
Built-in (automatic) flexibility of expenditure should mean th at
under existing programs and statutes (without legislative change or
major exercise of administrative discretion, though appropriations
may be still needed) expenditure will change as the result of change
of the gross national product or of employment. Unemployment
benefits or relief payments may serve as an example. The expenditure
change in turn may influence the size of gross national product and
employment. In actual measurement change in gross national product
causing expenditure change and change in gross national product
modified by expenditure change will not be easily distinguishable,
though the economic processes are distinctly different. Built-in flex­
ibility of taxation has increased very much over the last generation
due to the increasing importance of personal and corporate income
taxes. This flexibility may be too great and thus cause instability, or
it m ight just be sufficient. Nevertheless, the opinion is widely held
today th at the effects of built-in flexibility of taxation are not strong
enough to mitigate economic fluctuations sufficiently. Built-in flex­
ibility of expenditures, like relief payments, would add to the stabiliz­
ing influences. The fluctuations of payments in agricultural programs
do not follow a clear anticyclical pattern. Unfortunately, flex­
ibility on the whole has declined considerably as against the thirties
largely due to the preponderance of m ilitary expenditure. Only the
slightest degree of flexibility can be assumed in th at area and that
only in the sense that if there were widespread unemployment and
social unrest in the Western W orld the aggressive propensities of the
Soviet Union would probably increase and then require more expendi­
ture for defense and foreign aid. We may measure built-in flexibility
in a very simple way such as A. G. H a rt’s form ula:
Dollar Increment of Deficit
Dollar Increment of Gross National Product
We may develop more specific formulas using specified models of the
economy. Due to the present size of governmental expenditures even
relatively small variations must exert considerable influence. Never­
theless, our reliance on built-in flexibility of Federal expenditure
should be slight.
Legislative and administrative flexibility is an autonomous change,
measured by the dollar or percentage change of expenditure. Such
change will presumably bring about a change in gross national product
or employment. One must compare the situation with the one which
would have developed in the absence of the expenditure change.
The degree of variability and the speed of variation do not go hand
in hand. Frequently speed of expenditure change will be greater than
speed of revenue change. The speed of possible increase of expendi­
ture is different from the speed of decrease of expenditure. The meas­
ure most frequently proposed to speed up expenditure increases is
the public works shelf. I f the (necessarily inexpensive and long



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

351

drawn) planning stage of public works would precede the time of need,
i'aster spending would be possible when need arises. This procedure
is not without danger as every planned project has an innate propen­
sity to be executed irrespective of the business cycle. The speed with
which projects once started can be stopped is something else again.
Canals are likely to be completed. Road improvement can be done
piecemeal and is easily terminated; this adaptability in terms of
anticyclical policy should not lightly be sacrificed for a long-range
program—except if it were suggested such a pi ogram were necessary
to counteract stagnation. Grants-in-aid and subsidies can seemingly
be easily terminated but this termination may not be feasible due to
actual or presumed socioeconomic consequences for the recipients, be
it private individuals or governments.
Legislative deliberation frequently takes more time than adminis­
trative deliberation. Nevertheless, legislative speed (from the begin­
ning of deliberation to the actual expenditure) may well be in any
specific case greater than administrative speed. Again, consideration
of every case on its merits without much reliance on supposed general
considerations will be necessary.
Surpluses and deficits might balance out over the business cycle.
We may or may not use a capital budget; at any rate, for true capital
items debts may be incurred and capital-consumption allowances may
be spread over the useful life of the capital item. F or cyclical sta­
bilization, depreciation taken may well be higher in years of pros­
perity and lower in years of depression. Surpluses and deficits cer­
tainly must not balance over the cycle in a progressing economy. The
rate of permissible debt rise in relation to the rate of growth of the
economy, though, is outside of the scope of this paper.
A debt rise may be also permissible within a fairly unchanging
economy, but stringent limitations are to be observed lest the public
demand for funds dry up the supply of funds necessary for private
investment. There is also the great danger that funds are provided
in an inflationary way through the banking system. Finally, the in­
creasing size of the recurrent debt-service burden may have an unfav­
orable effect, though this seems to be somewhat less iikely. Different
ways of debt management make for important differences. In gen­
eral, additional expenditures are expansionary, but expenditures made
on servicing the public debt may be contracting due to their asset
effects. More spending on interest of the public debt may make it
possible to have a public debt of longer duration; such securities will
be harder to liquify and more other liquid assets will have to be held by
the public or the banks. High interest rates also may make possible
a transfer of the securities from the banks to private holders, thus de­
creasing private funds available. Such a transfer can also be a first
step toward monetary restraints in the banking system; th at is, it
may make possible the application of more restrictive monetary policy.
All these considerations, however, go beyond expenditure policy
proper.
R

e p e r c u s s io n s

of

E

x p e n d it u r e

C

hange on

S t a b il iz a t io n

Repercussions can be measured by effected changes in the large ag­
gregates or in some more specific manner. Repercussions may result



352

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

from anticipated public spending. On the whole, though, the prim ary
determination of effects of Government expenditures on gross na­
tional product, national income, or on employment is prim arily
through the concept of multiplier effects following spending. The in­
crease in gross national product or national income is measured which
is not only due to the initial autonomous increase in investment of
Government spending but is also due to the consequent increases in
consumption. The multiplier might be a specific public-works or public-expenditure multiplier, or it might be a more generalized invest­
ment multiplier. Such multipliers are quite useful in model building,
but it sometimes becomes difficult to distinguish between monetary
effects (incipient inflation) and effects in real terms (increased level of
output). An employment multiplier, that is, the final increase in em­
ployment due to public works, though less fitted for model building,
does measure directly the desired main result in real terms. Moreover,
an increase in income and hence in consumption will lead to voluntary
increase in inventories and to increases in investment in facilities pro­
ducing the consumption goods when the existing facilities are already
fairly well used (acceleration). Sometimes increased investment will
lead to induced additional investment followed by new multiplier ex­
pansion. The total effect has sometimes been called leverage, meas­
ured by a supermultiplier (A. Hansen).
In any situation where there exists, at going prices and wages, con­
siderable unemployment and considerable unused resources, any addi­
tional compensatory public spending which does not create a com­
pensating reaction through decreased private spending will lead to
some additional private spending when the public expenditures are
respent by the recipients. This respending will lead with leaks and
lags to some additional use of resources and additional employment—
th at is, additional output at going prices. This additional income
will lead again with leads and lags to some additional output and
employment and so forth. Any increase in real terms is only possible
as long as there is sufficient unused labor and resources available.
Studies made before the Second W orld W ar about the numerical
size of the multiplier effect are largely obsolete due to the changed
structure of the economy. These are also presently inapplicable due
to the higher level of use of labor and resources. Little recent em­
pirical work has been published due to the fact that employment and
output have been rather uniformly high over the last 15 years. Any
multiplier effect in real terms is presently presumably very low, and
unfavorable effect on private spending likely to be high. "Multiplier
models have, as a rule, been insistent that the initial step is an increase
in autonomous investment or Government spending and the following
steps are increases in consumption. In reality, the neatness of the
distinction between investment and consumption is somewhat blurred.
Recent models consider certain additional repercussions in investment
and in consumption. F or policy purposes, measurement of repercus­
sions in the past is of help only to the extent th at stable relations can
be safely assumed over a considerable period of time or a safe estimate
of the importance of the changes were possible.
A t any rate, fluctuations in investment during the business cycle aremuch greater than fluctuations in consumption; investment goods play
a strategic role in the business cycle. For that reason, as well as fo r



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

353

others, emphasis on spending on investment goods (including con­
struction) seems quite justified.
In a depression, fiscal policy relating directly to expenditures is
more forceful than monetary policy which only can make borrowing
easier if borrowers want to borrow. Expenditure increases are in
depression more powerful than tax reductions, because tax savings
may be used for debt repayment, increased cash holdings, and so on.
H igher taxes show probably more powerful restraining effects in
prosperity than expenditure reductions, though this is somewhat con­
troversial. Sometimes the feasibility of any tax or expenditure vari­
ation will depend on the established level of taxation and of expendi­
ture and their socioeconomic consequences. I t may be questioned
whether Colin Clark’s 25-percent maximum level of taxation has em­
pirical validity. Certainly, there are, somewhere, limits to tax in­
creases in a democratically organized society.
A Government surplus will have a restrictive influence if the re­
sultant surplus is sterilized, e. g., in the rainy-day fund, preferably
not deposited with the commercial banks. The surplus may be used
for debt reduction and still retain its restrictive effect if care is taken
that the increase in the spending power of the recipient of the money
is in some way destroyed. The classical case is the repayment of pub­
lic debt to the banks with simultaneous reduction of their moneycreating power. I f this reduction of the money-creating power of
the banks cannot properly be safeguarded, the debt reduction out of
surplus will have hardly any restrictive effect.
I f expenditures are balanced by revenues the countereffects of the
raising of revenues have to be considered. National income is defined
as equivalent to the sum of private consumption, net private invest­
ment, and labor and resources used by government, neglecting for
this discussion the small net foreign investment. Then, most of the
time, government, by taxation, absorbs some existing funds which
are “income” in the everyday sense of the word, and respends these
funds in their entirety. The Government prevents some fraction of
the amount taxed from being “saved.” I f we define “realized” sav­
ings as equal to investment, and if we assume they fall short of
“intended” savings, that is, savings in the everyday sense, in the situ­
ation described above, the decrease in consumption and investment
must then be less than the increase in the Government sector of na­
tional income (always measured by expenditure, th at is, cost). This
would be so because the decrease in investment (which investment is
less than intended savings) is less the increase in government spend­
ing, as some of the taxes fall on savings that would not be invested.
Thus, taxing and spending seem to raise, almost by the powers of
definition, national income. Under conditions of full employment,
people may work in part for the Government instead of for them­
selves; but, if there is a sufficient amount of idle manpower and re­
sources, the amount of employment and productive services required
by the Government may come forth in addition to what is wanted by
the private sector of the economy. The money value of all goods and
services produced for private as well as for public needs will have
increased. In fact, from the employment point of view, the result for
the society as a whole will be exactly the same as if the Government
had ordered idle manpower and resources without any direct compen­



354

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

sation. The additional quantities of goods produced and services
rendered may be paid for at unchanging prices. But, it cannot be
inferred in which way well-being will be affected. The effect will
depend on whether the Government services add to the well-being of
individuals otherwise dependent on their net average private incomes.
Moreover, it should also be noted that total net private income divided
by the number of people who work in both sectors and hence receive
income, that is, average net income of people employed, will fall.
Only the net private average income—that is, the total net income
divided by population or labor force—will stay unchanged. W hether
well-being is maintained for the average working person will depend
on the additional well-being created by government services. Only if
additional people are employed for private needs and their output is
sufficiently high to provide the additional goods necessary for them­
selves, as well as for the people employed producing for public needs,
only then will the average amount of privately used goods and serv­
ices for people working m production for private needs remain un­
changed or rise. There m ight be, in addition, adverse influences of
high taxes on investment or on effort.
Certainly no general assumption is possible th a t such management
of government finance is probable or in any way preferable to any
other policy. Thinking th at balanced budget expansion of the public
sector raises the national income by the amount of the expansion can
hardly be upheld. The indirect increase in national income, the latter
term defined in the customary sense, will be small. In fact, the effects
may be negative due to unfavorable indirect repercussions.5
Fiscal policy will have some influence on income distribution and
hence on the relation between consumption and investment and thus
on multiplier values. The change in mcome distribution will be ac­
centuated if we include in the measure of consumption free or under­
priced public services available to and relatively more used by Iowmcome groups. Any pertinent measurement of effects of fiscal policy
will require measurement of the distribution of the tax burden as well
as of the distribution of governmental payments and services. I f the
expenditures made and services rendered out of a deficit could be
separated from those paid out of taxes it would be possible to specu­
late whether these additional expenditures tend toward further in­
come equalization. B ut it is not likely th at the equalizing effect of
deficit financing over the business cycle will be very pronounced.
Some government expenditure will strengthen, some will weaken
private investment; sometimes investment will be weakened by even
more than the amount of public expenditure. Effects will not only
depend on how the funds have been acquired (taxes, borrowing from
private borrowers, borrowing from banks) out very much on the
specific manner in which they have been put to use. I t is also impor­
tant how the use of funds influences the general climate of opinion,
especially of investors’ opinion. Building of pyramids is not deter­
rent to any kind of private investment yet it will have an unfavorable
effect on investors’ attitudes in our society.
Total fiscal effects will not only depend on revenue and expenditure
of the Federal Government. On the other hand, the financial systems
‘ See Baumol and Preston. American Economic Review, 1955, 1956.



ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

355

of States and municipalities are not well organized for contracyclical
policy. Stringent constitutional or, in case of localities, even statutory
debt limitations, and required earmarking of funds make flexibility
very difficult to obtain. Individual State and local budgets by them­
selves are too small to have any recognizable influence on overall
fiscal policy. These governments can hardly have any incentive to
follow a Federal pattern, except for grants-in-aid that require match­
ing or for similar such devices. I t can be shown that Federal deficit
spending in the thirties, small by itself, was largely counteracted by
disinvestment and debt repayment by States and localities and there­
fore could not have had under these circumstances any significant
stabilizing influence.
C o n c l u s io n s

A few tentative conclusions may be draw n:
1. F or the purposes at hand large aggregates like total expenditure,
but especially such as gross national product and national income, hide
significant problems. Their use is frequently dangerous. We need
more specific knowledge about relations between more restricted aggre­
gates. We lack sufficient quantitative measurements of repercussions
and know little about the degree of stability of established rela­
tionships.
2. Deficit spending is as a stabilizing device more powerful than
revenue-covered spending. Deficit spending seems very useful (and
available alternatives to it most restricted) at low levels of output
and employment. A t what levels of output and employment the use­
fulness of this device diminishes and finally ceases is difficult to state.
Empirical measurements of final repercussions, but even only of multi­
plier and related effects, are very rough and uncertain and tend to
become soon obsolete. Final effects in real terms change not only
with changing levels of output; there are important indirect reper­
cussions from which we cannot abstract. Predictability of final effects
in quantitative terms is very limited. The behavior of the general
price level or cost-of-living price level is not always necessarily of
overriding importance. The influence of certain types of expenditure,
of prolonged deficit spending, and of debt increases on the prices
and on the climate o f public opinion necessary for strong private
investment has always to Tbe kept in mind.
3. Emphasis should be on public expenditure favorable rather than
on such unfavorable to private investment. For that reason it seems
that such expenditures should preferably not be competitive to private
investment. On the other hand, such expenditure must have a con­
siderable degree of usefulness not only for the welfare effects to be
derived from these expenditures but also because of their impact on
public opinion as prevailing in our society. This poses a fam iliar
dilemma in planning and executing public works.
i.
A relatively high degree of potential variability and potential
speed in starting as well as ending spending programs is important.
Built-in flexibility of expenditure can only be relied upon to a very
moderate extent. A high degree of social usefulness persisting over
the different phases of the business cycle makes spending more desir­
able by itself. Yet such usefulness poses a very serious problem when
termination becomes important. There are, therefore, additional dis­
tinct limitations on the desirable kind and intensity of social usefulness



356

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND STABILITY

of expenditure when speedy contracyclical variability is considered
necessary.
5. Coordination of Federal and State-local policies is desirable but
is distinctly limited by the established Federal system.
6. Fiscal policy is supposedly only concerned with levels of output
and employment. Different economic activities are influenced in
different ways by different ways of spending. I t is generally con­
sidered within the scope of overall fiscal policy to emphasize that
spending favorable to the general level of investment (in real terms)
is desirable. The behavior of the investment goods industries (in the
wide sense of the word, to include, for example, construction) has a
crucial impact on the economy.
7. Anticyclical policy does not necessarily require that the public
debt fluctuate around a predetermined size. Sterilization of the sur­
plus may be preferable to debt repayment despite the loss of interest
savings. There are distinct and strong limitations to permissible debt
rises. The danger of inflation is only one of several limiting factors.
The limitations, to be accepted, must leave some room for the feasi­
bility of at least some sudden debt rises due to war or warlike
situations.
8. Anticyclical fiscal policy should be content with less than com­
plete success in achieving a set employment and price level. We know
too little to permit fairly precise timing and dosage. Attempts at
stringent stabilization will have undesirable side effects. Expendi­
ture policy can be used, though, successfully to mitigate considerable
fluctuations. The effects of expenditure increase in depression have
been much more thoroughly explored than the effects of expenditure
decreases in an inflationary prosperity. The determination of the
extent of permissible fluctuations in output and employment and in
prices should be a prim ary policy decision. Our restricted knowledge
about final repercussions is an additional reason why some degree of
fluctuation should be unavoidable. The development of even only
tentative benchmarks for legislative and executive action would be
of greatest help, though they would not necessarily have to be made
public.
A discussion of anticyclical compensatory spending together with
a discussion of policies promoting a desirable and feasible rate of
growth point toward a framework within which the study of specific
expenditure programs should take place. A thorough investigation
of specific programs and their specific repercussions at different levels
of output and employment is necessary. Repercussions on prices and
price levels have to be studied most carefully. A t times these reper­
cussions might be of overriding importance. The value of generalized
models which relate in money terms the large aggregates to each other
is restricted. Such models should be considered only as a very first
step toward specific investigations of expenditure programs.