View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

C h r is tin a D . R o m e r a n d D a v id H . R o m e r

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY AND NBER

W h a t E n d s R e c e s s io n s ?

1. Introduction
The Employment Act of 1946 set as the goal of government economic
policy the maintenance of reasonably full employment and stable prices.
Yet, nearly 50 years later, economists seem strangely unsure about what
to tell policymakers to do to end recessions. One source of this uncer­
tainty is confusion about how macroeconomic policies have actually
been used to combat recessions. In the midst of the most recent
recession, one heard opinions of fiscal policy ranging from the view
that no recession has ever ended without fiscal expansion to the view
that fiscal stimulus has always come too late. Similarly, for monetary
policy there was disagreement about whether looser policy has been a
primary engine of recovery from recessions or whether it has been
relatively unimportant in these periods.
This paper seeks to fill in this gap in economists' knowledge by
analyzing what has ended the eight recessions that have occurred in
the United States since 1950. In particular, it analyzes whether mone­
tary and fiscal policies have helped or hindered previous recoveries. By
quantifying the role of policy, the paper seeks to identify how much of
recoveries is attributable to government action and how much to other
factors such as self-correction and fortuitous shocks. By determining
which policies were the most effective in ending past recessions, the
paper tries to discern the likely efficacy of policy today and in reces­
sions to come.

We thank Laurence Ball, Olivier Blanchard, John Cochrane, Ray Fair, Stanley Fischer,
Michael Lee, N. Gregory Mankiw, Julio Rotemberg, and David Wilcox for helpful com­
ments and suggestions; Keith Carlson and John Peterson for providing data; David
Reifschneider, Jill Thompson, and David Wyss for assistance with multipliers; and the
National Science Foundation for financial support.




14 •ROMER & ROMER

Our main finding is that monetary policy has been the source of most
postwar recoveries. While limited fiscal actions have occurred around
most troughs, these actions have almost always been too small to
contribute much to economic recovery. In contrast, monetary policy has
typically moved toward expansion shortly after the start of most reces­
sions and appears to have contributed, on average, almost two percent­
age points to real gross domestic product (GDP) growth in the four
quarters following the trough. Even if one accounts for the fact that
tight monetary policy before the peak continues to depress the econ­
omy for several years, the net effect of monetary policy in ending
recessions has been substantial.
We reach this conclusion through a series of steps. Section 2 analyzes
the record of policy actions since 1950. It shows that both nominal and
real interest rates fell by several percentage points before most troughs.
In contrast, the ratio of the high-employment surplus to trend GDP
typically fell slightly around troughs, but only rarely moved more than
a percentage point.
Section 3 analyzes the sources of these policy changes. It examines
the stated motivations of policymakers to see if the changes in interest
rates and in the high-employment surplus during recessions and around
troughs were taken largely to end the recessions or for other reasons.
We find that nearly all of the monetary changes and most of the fiscal
changes were genuinely antirecessionary. Interestingly, we find that
many of the largest discretionary fiscal actions taken in the postwar era,
such as the 1964 tax cut and the Nixon "N ew Economic Policy," were
not antirecessionary measures, but expansionary actions taken when
policymakers were dissatisfied with the pace of growth.
Section 4 examines the likely effects of the antirecessionary actions
we identify. Using estimates of the effects of policy both from our own
regressions and from Data Resources Incorporated^ forecasting model,
we estimate the contributions of monetary and fiscal policy to reces­
sions and recoveries. Although there is substantial variation in the
estimates of policies' impact, the results suggest that monetary policy
has been crucial in ending recessions, while fiscal policy has contributed
very little.1
Section 5 investigates two additional issues raised by our analysis.
The first issue is the overall stabilization record of policy. We argue that
there is little evidence that discretionary policy has had a large stabiliz­
ing influence, and that there are several important episodes in which
I. Perry and Schultze (1993) also investigate the sources of recoveries. They reach
conclusions generally similar to ours.




What Ends Recessions? * 15
expansionary policy has exacerbated fluctuations. The second issue is
the persistence of output movements. We find that the component of
fluctuations that is due to shifts in monetary and fiscal policy is highly
persistent and accounts for a large part of the persistence of overall
output movements.

2. Policy Actions in Recessions and Recoveries
2.1 INDICATORS OF POLICY
To analyze whether policy could account for recoveries, it is necessary
to examine the behavior of policy during recessions and recoveries. We
examine two indicators of monetary policy. The first is simply the
quarterly change in the nominal federal funds rate.2 Throughout much
of the postwar period, the federal funds rate has been the primary
proximate instrument of monetary policy. And even during periods
when it was not, such as the 1950s and 1979-1982, the Federal Reserve
placed considerable emphasis on " money market conditions"— that is,
changes in nominal interest rates— in setting policy. Cook and Hahn
(1989) and Bernanke and Blinder (1992) document that the Federal
Reserve can control the federal funds rate in the short run, and
Bernanke and Blinder present a variety of evidence that innovations in
the funds rate are largely due to changes in monetary policy.
Our second indicator of monetary policy is the estimated change in
the real funds rate. Theory predicts that it is the real rather than the
nominal rate that is relevant for economic activity. The fact that expan­
sionary monetary policy lowers nominal interest rates strongly suggests
that the Federal Reserve influences real rates. But because expected
inflation may change systematically over the course of recessions and
recoveries, it is important to examine explicitly the behavior of real
rates.
Our procedure for estimating the real funds rate follows Mishkin
(1981). We first compute the ex post real rate as the difference between
the nominal rate and the change in the logarithm of the GDP deflator.3
We then regress the ex post real rate on a constant, a time trend, the
current and the first four lagged values of the nominal rate, and the first
2. Unless otherwise noted, all data are from Citibase (Dec 1993 update). The federal
funds rate data for 1950-1954 are described in Romer and Romer (1993).
3. Because the federal funds rate is a very short-term rate, the relevant inflation rate for
computing the real rate for a quarter is inflation within that quarter. Therefore, we
compute the ex post real rate for quarter t as it - 4[ln((P,+1 + Pt)/ 2 ) - ln((P, +
P / - i ) / 2)], where i is the nominal funds rate and P is the GDP deflator.




16 •ROMER & ROMER

Figure 1 NOMINAL AND EX ANTE REAL FEDERAL FUNDS RATES

four lags of inflation and real GDP growth.4 The sample period is
1951:1 to 1993:2. The estimated values of the ex ante real rate are the
fitted values of this regression. Figure 1 shows our estimates of the
ex ante real federal funds rate along with the nominal rate.
Our measure of discretionary fiscal policy is the change in the ratio of
the high-employment surplus to trend or potential GDP.5 This measure
is shown in Figure 2. The rationale for using the high-employment
surplus is the standard one that it adjusts for the impact of economic
activity on receipts and expenditures. Because of this adjustment, the
high-employment surplus can differentiate fiscal actions taken deliber­
ately in response to recessions from those that occur automatically. The
high-employment surplus, however, is not a perfect measure of discre­
tionary fiscal changes because some actions may have more or less
effect on the economy than their impact on the high-employment
surplus would suggest. Therefore, in the analysis of fiscal policy in the
next two sections, we discuss temporary tax changes, investment tax
credits, and other factors that might cause the change in the highemployment surplus to be a misleading measure of the expansionary
stance of fiscal policy.
4. To prevent the period t value of the GDP deflator from entering the first lag of

inflation, the lagged values of inflation are computed simply as 4[ln(Pf_ !) - ln(P,_2)l/
4[ln(P,_2) — ln(Pf_3)], and so on, rather than in the more complex way used to
calculate current inflation described in footnote 3. Using the more complex definition
has essentially no effect on the estimated real interest rate series.
5. For the period since 1955, the data are from the Congressional Budget Office. The data
for 1950-1954 are described in Carlson (1987).




What Ends Recessions? * 17
Figure 2 HIGH-EMPLOYMENT SURPLUS TO TREND GDP

Although it is useful to separate out the automatic changes in the
surplus that are caused by economic activity from the discretionary
changes, the automatic changes are nevertheless interesting. It is cer­
tainly possible, for example, that automatic stabilizers are important to
recoveries. For this reason we also examine the change in the ratio of
the automatic surplus to trend GDP; we measure the automatic compo­
nent of the surplus simply as the difference between the actual surplus
and the high-employment surplus.6
2.2 RESULTS
2.2.2 Monetary Policy Table 1 reports the behavior of the federal funds
rate during recessions— specifically, from the times of peaks in real
GDP to the quarter after troughs.7 The top half of Table 1 shows the
change in the nominal rate; the bottom half shows the change in the
real rate.
Table 1 shows that interest rates fall sharply in recessions. The falls in
the nominal funds rate are particularly consistent: 28 of the 33 entries in
the top portion of Table 1 are negative. The only significant exception
to the pattern of falling nominal rates occurred in 1974, when the
Federal Reserve moved to sharply tighter policy even though real
6. For the actual budget surplus, we use the National Income and Product Accounts

measure of the federal surplus.
7. Because our focus is on movements in aggregate output, we use the dates of the peaks
and troughs in real GDP rather than National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER)
peaks and troughs. The two sets of dates are very similar, however.




18- ROMER & ROMER

output was falling. Even during this recession, however, the overall
movement in the funds rate was a large decline. The average decline
between the peak in output and one quarter after the trough is 3.4
percentage points. For comparison, the standard deviation of move­
ments in the nominal funds rate for the full sample is 1.0 percentage
point for one-quarter changes, and 2.3 percentage points for four-quarter
changes. Thus, the declines in recessions are large.
The bottom half of Table 1 shows that real interest rates also fell
during these recessions. In all eight episodes, the estimated real rate fell

Table 1 THE FEDERAL FUNDS RATE IN RECESSIONS

Date
of peak

Change in nominal rate (percentage points)
53:2

57:3

60:1

69:3

73:4

80:1

81:3

90:2

-0.03
-0.03
“ 0.37
-0.39
0.22

-0.01
-1.37
—0.92

-0.24
-0.76
-0.64
-0.29

-0.04
-0.37
-0.69
-1.18

-0.67
1.93
0.84
-2.74
-3.04
-0.88

-2.36
-2.85

-3.99
0.64
0.29
-3.51
-1.72

-0.08
-0.42
-1.32
-0.56

-2.30

-1.93

-2.28

-4.58

-5.21

-8.29

-2.38

Quarter
relative
to peak
+1
+2
+3
+4
+5
+6

Cumulative
change,
peak to quarter
after trough
-0.59

Change in real rate (percentage points)
Quarter
relative
to peak
+1
+2

+3
+4
+5

0.46
0.61
0.20
-1.84
-0.03

-0.08
-0.21
-0.83

-0.46
0.56
-0.08
-0.11

-0.15
0.25
-0.45
-1.21

-1.11
0.90
1.32
-2.66
-2.40
-1.16

-1.11
-1.88

-0.15
-0.21
1.13
-1.47
-1.98

-0.12
-0.13
-1.19
-0.96

-1.11

-0.08

-1.56

-5.10

-2.98

-2.68

-2.40

+6

Cumulative
change,
peak to quarter
after trough
-0.60

Note: Data for quarters after the. first quarter after the trough are not reported.




What Ends Recessions? • 19
Table 2

THE FEDERAL FUNDS RATE IN RECOVERIES

Date
of trough

Change in nominal rate (percentage points)
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------54:2
58:1
60:4
70:2
75:1
80:2
82:3
91:1

Quarter
relative
to trough
+2
+3
+4
+5

Cumulative
change;
1 to 5 quarters
after trough

0.02
0.29
0.16
0.43

0.38
0.84
0.40
0.52

-0.27
“ 0.06
0.72
0.00

-1.14
-1.71
0.71
0.91

0.74
-0.75
-0.59
0.37

6.02
0.72
1.21
-0.20

-0.63
0.15
0.66
-0.03

“ 0.22
-0.83
-0.79
-0.25

0.90

2.14

0.40

-1.23

-0.22

7.74

0.14

-2.09

Change in real rate (percentage points)
Quarter
relative
to trough
+2
+3
+4
+5

0.56
-0.48
0.12
0.10

-0.36
0.39
0.42
0.57

-0.60
-0.62
0.32
0.19

0.11
-0.83
-0.79
0.19

1.18
-0.27
0.08
1.29

2.97
0.42
1.37
-0.10

0.55
0.35
-0.17
0.22

-0.21
-0.06
-0.28
-0.37

0.30

1.02

-0.71

-1.33

2.27

4.67

0.95

-0.93

Cumulative
change,
1 to 5 quarters
after trough

between the peak and the quarter after the trough. The declines in the
real rate are somewhat smaller and less consistent than the falls in the
nominal rate, however. For example, the average decline is just slightly
over 2 percentage points.8
Once a recovery has begun, there is a moderate tendency for both the
nominal and real funds rates to rise. Table 2 shows the changes in the
nominal and real federal funds rates in the second through fifth
quarters after troughs. About two-thirds of these entries are positive,

8. Section 4.3 shows that the declines in output, prices, and expected inflation during
recessions relative to their normal behavior would have caused only modest falls in
nominal interest rates, and essentially no change in real rates, if the Federal Reserve
had kept the money growth rate fixed in the face of these movements. Thus, even if
we adopted measures of monetary policy that did not attribute these parts of changes
in interest rates to policy, we would still find that monetary policy was the source of
the bulk of the interest rate declines.




20 * ROMER & ROMER

with an average rise of both the nominal and the real rate during these
periods of about 1 percentage point. And although the relevant num­
bers are not reported in the tables, the same general tendency toward
moderate interest rate increases continues through the second year of
recoveries. Table 2 also shows that the 1991 experience is quite unusual.
Rather than rising as is typical, both real and nominal rates fell substan­
tially after the trough.
This examination of movements in interest rates suggests that mone­
tary policy could play a critical role in recoveries: There are large,
consistent declines in interest rates during recessions. Whether these
declines reflect deliberate countercyclical policy, and whether their
timing and magnitude are consistent with the view that they are
important in recoveries, are questions that we address in the next two
sections.
2.2.2 Fiscal Policy Table 3 reports the change in the ratio of the
high-employment surplus to trend GDP from peaks to five quarters
after troughs. These data do not show any pattern of discretionary fiscal
policy as consistent or strong as the declines in interest rates in reces­
sions. The average cumulative change in the high-employment surplus
to GDP ratio from the peak to one quarter after the trough is - 0 .7
percentage points. However, there is great variation around this aver­
age, with some cumulative changes being large and positive, and others
being large and negative. To put the average change in perspective, the
standard deviation of movements in the high-employment surplus to
GDP ratio for the full sample is 0.6 percentage points for one-quarter
changes and 1.1 percentage point for four-quarter changes. Thus, the
average fall during recessions is not large relative to typical movements
in the high-employment surplus to GDP ratio.
To the extent that there is any systematic pattern in deliberate fiscal
policy, it is that policy is generally expansionary around troughs. For
example, in every recession except the one immediately after the
Korean War, the ratio of the high-employment surplus to GDP fell
between two quarters before the trough and the quarter after the
trough; 19 of the 24 individual changes for these quarters were nega­
tive. The overall shifts over these three quarters were generally about
1% of GDP. Thus, it does appear that fiscal policy becomes slightly
expansionary late in recessions.
The record of automatic fiscal policy is decidedly more promising
than that of discretionary fiscal policy. Table 4 shows the change in the
automatic surplus to GDP ratio around the eight troughs since 1950. As
would be expected, the automatic surplus to GDP ratio consistently




What Ends Recessions? * 21
declines during recessions. These automatic falls in the surplus are
moderately large; the average cumulative decline in the automatic
surplus to GDP ratio from the peak to the quarter after the trough is 1.6
percentage points. For comparison, the standard deviation of changes
in the automatic surplus to GDP ratio is 0.3 percentage points for
one-quarter changes and 0.9 percentage point for four-quarter changes.
This simple examination of the data suggests that automatic fiscal
policy is more likely to have affected recoveries than has discretionary
policy. Unless the effects of modest changes in deliberate fiscal policy
are large, or there are consistently important shifts in fiscal policy that
are not reflected in the high-employment surplus, discretionary fiscal
policy cannot have played a central role in ending downturns or in

Table 3 THE HIGH-EMPLOYMENT SURPLUS IN RECESSIONS
AND RECOVERIES

Change in ratio of high-employment surplus to trend GDP
(percentage points)
Date
of trough

54:2

58:1

60:4

70:2

75:1

80:2

82:3

91:1

0.24
-0.22
-0.80
-0.29
0.12
-0.01
-0.36
0.16

0.31
0.02
0.50
-0.69
-0.18
-3.23
2.18
-0.09
0.38
0.40

0.06
-0.03
0.00
0.77
-0.05
-0.16

-0.39
0.17
-0.15
-0.66
-0.70
0.26
-0.05
-0.85
-0.27

0.54
-0.65
0.00
-0.15
0.47
-0.37
-0.31
-0.03

Quarter
relative
to trough
-4
-3
-2
-1
0
+1
+2
+3
+4
+5

0.70
-0.99
1.41
1.52
0.25
0.64
0.41
0.43
-0.26

—0.71
0.45
-0.99
-0.10
-0.07
0.77
0.20

-0.29
-0.31
-0.14
-0.27
-0.27
0.08
—0.08
-0.72

Cumulative
change,
peak to quarter
after trough

2.89

-1.25

-1.00

-1.08

-3.28

0.02

-1.74

-0.26

Cumulative
change,
1 to 5 quarters
after trough

1.21

0.80

-0.99

-0.09

2.88

0.55

-0.92

-0.23

Note: Data for quarters prior to the peak are not reported.




22* ROMER & ROMER

creating strong recoveries. On the other hand, the automatic move­
ments in the surplus during recessions may be large enough and
consistent enough to have significantly affected the path of real output
following troughs.
Despite this negative conclusion on the overall movement of discre­
tionary fiscal policy during recessions, the finding that discretionary
fiscal policy is consistently expansionary around troughs is intriguing. If
these expansions are in fact responses to economic conditions, they
would suggest that deliberate fiscal policy may play some role in
recoveries. More important, they raise the possibility that if such expan­
sions were only undertaken more aggressively, fiscal policy could be a
significant countercyclical tool The key issues are the motives for the
shifts in policy, the reasons they are not larger, and the timing of their
effects. It is to these issues that we now turn.

Table 4 THE AUTOMATIC SURPLUS IN RECESSIONS AND RECOVERIES

uuie
of trough

Change in ratio of automatic surplus to trend GDP
(percentage points)
54:2

58:1

60:4

70:2

75:1

-0.34
-0.41
-0.41
0.01
-0.50
0.35
-0.18
-0.04

80:2

82:3

91:1

-0.46
-0.19
-0.50
-0.44
-1.08
0.07
0.08
0.12
0.34
0.00

-0.90
-0.32
0.30
0.13
-0.17
0.01

-0.48
-0.50
-0.18
-0.30
-0.27
-0.03
0.40
0.40
0.43

-0.37
-0.12
0.85
-0.85
-0.62
-0.04
-0.06
-0.08

—2.60

-1.22

-1.74

-0.49

0.56

0.27

1.21

-0.80

Quarter
relative
to trough
-4
-3
-2
-1
0
+1
+2
+3
+4
+5

-0.32
*0.35
—1.41
-0.84
0.47
-0.11
0.72
0.18
0.22

-0.59
-1.01
-0.15
0.33
0.50
0.26
0.35

-0.29
-0.22
-0.51
-0.08
0.11
0.17
0.37
0.21

Cumulative
change,
peak to quarter
after trough
-2.45 -1.76 -1.09 -1.16
Cumulative
change,
1 to 5 quarters
after trough
1.00
1.44
0.86 -0.37
Note: Data for quarters prior to the peak are not reported.




What Ends Recessions? •23

3. Motivations for Policy Actions
This section analyzes the nature and motivation of the policy actions
behind the movements in interest rates and the high-employment
surplus described in the previous section. This analysis is crucially
important because our policy indicators could move for reasons other
than antirecessionary policy. Interest rates, for example, could decline
during recessions if the Federal Reserve were targeting money growth
and simply allowed rates to fall as declines in real activity reduced
money demand. They could also fall if the Federal Reserve were
targeting interest rates but changed them in response to international
or financial-market developments rather than in response to recessions.
Similarly, the high-employment surplus could fall because of military
actions or other spending changes unrelated to the state of the econ­
omy. Only by analyzing the motivations of policymakers can we deter­
mine whether the movements in interest rates and the high-employment surplus during recessions were the result of deliberate antireces­
sionary policy.
3.1 MONETARY POLICY
The records of the Federal Reserve provide ample evidence that the
falls in interest rates before recoveries are the result of deliberate
antirecessionary policy. Boschen and Mills (1992) provide a monthly
index of the Federal Reserve's intentions based on the Record of Policy
Actions of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC). Their index
classifies intentions on a scale from - 2 to + 2 , with - 2 indicating a
strong emphasis on inflation reduction and + 2 indicating a strong
emphasis on real growth. Table 5 shows the change in the Boschen-Mills
index from the peak in economic activity to five quarters after the
trough. (Most of the values are in fractions because we have converted
the monthly series to quarterly values to be consistent with our other
indicators.)
The most obvious message of Table 5 is that monetary policy typically
changes toward an emphasis on real growth very soon after the peak in
real GDP. Without exception, the change in the Boschen-Mills index is
positive within two quarters of the peak. In many cases the change
occurs concurrent with or even slightly before the peak in output. This
pattern obviously parallels the finding in Section 2 that interest rates fall
soon after the peak in most cases. The behavior of the Boschen-Mills
index indicates that the Federal Reserve typically responds to weakness
in the economy quite rapidly and that the declines in interest rates are
generally the result of deliberate monetary policy.




24 - ROMER & ROMER

Table 5 THE BOSCHEN-MILLS INDEX IN RECESSIONS AND RECOVERIES

Change in the Boschen-Mills index
Date
of trough

54:2

60:4

58:1

70:2

75:1

80:2

82:3

91:1

0.33
0.67
0.33
0.67
0.33
0.00
-1.00
0.00

0.33
-0.67
0.00
1.00
1.67
0.33
0.00
-0.67
-0.33
-0.33

0.00
0.67
0.33
0.00
0.00
0.00

0.67
0.33
0.00
0.00
1.00
0.00
-0.67
-1.33
0.00

na
na
na
na
na
na
na
na

Quarter
relative
to trough
-4
-3
-2
-1
0
+1
+2
+3
+4
+5

0.67
1.33
0.67
0.00
0.00
-0.33
-1.67
-0.67
-1.00

1.67
0.67
0.67
“ 1.00
“ 1.00
0.00
-0.33

1.00
1.33
0.33
0.00
-0.67
-0.33
-0.33
-0.67

Cumulative
change,
peak to quarter
after trough

2.67

3.00

2.67

ZOO

2.67

0.67

2.00

na

Cumulative
change,
1 to 5 quarters
after trough

-3.67

-2.33

-2.00

-0.67

-1.33

0.33

-2.00

na

^ n a b ^ o r r t , rP1 q q ? erS Pri° r ‘ a ,h e .Pea k Lare not reported. The Boschen-M ills index is not
toward^Loansfon !
‘° \
P° S,-h^
gC “ the Boschen-M ills index indicates a m ove
toward expansion, a negative change indicates a m ove toward contraction.

Table 5 also shows that the emphasis of monetary policy typically
C T u - n soon after the ^ough. In every recession analyzed by Boschen
and Mills, monetary policy turned contractionary within two or three
21ac
. ° / the. l0w P°int in real outPut. This again suggests that the
o
f
t
rates after troughs described in Section 2 are the result
or deliberate Federal Reserve policy.

9' !n fla H r r ecanl V e 0tm ^ aU t ° aU
Hgh T
trough, inflation itself does not comUtpnil

f T ^
Mi" S find that concern about
• • u the Federal Reserve after each

the extent that there is a pattern the inflaHnnSe T r 6*rly ®taSes of the recoveries. To
in the GDP deflator) generally falk Hn • £ate ^measured as the percentage change




s ,- ; ,” 8 i t

s y r

° f “ 0VM“ ' ,h“ |h

What Ends Recessions? ■25
3.1.1 Episodes The Boschen and Mills index, while very useful, is not
perfect for our purposes because it does not consider the Federal
Reserve's perceptions of the state of the economy.10 Therefore, it does
not distinguish between times when the Federal Reserve is counteract­
ing a recession and, for example, times when it believes the economy is
growing normally but desires even faster growth. For this reason, it is
useful to supplement Boschen and Mills's analysis with an independent
reading of the Record of Policy Actions of the Federal Open Market
Committee and the Minutes of the FOMC during recessions.11
1953 The Federal Reserve was very quick to perceive the weakening of
the economy in 1953. In retrospect, we know that the peak in real GDP
occurred in the second quarter of 1953. Yet as early as the June 11, 1953,
meeting, one member of the FOMC expressed the opinion that "the
economy was cresting" ( Minutes, 6 /1 1 /5 3 , p. 50). Throughout the fall,
the economic conditions reviewed by the Board indicated that the
economy was relatively stable, but with "indications of reductions in
demand in some important sectors" (Minutes, 9 /8 /5 3 , p. 2). By Decem­
ber, however, the FOMC felt that "the decline in economic conditions,
though moderate, was unmistakable" (1953, p. 102). The FOMC began
to loosen policy in the summer of 1953. The FOMC initially aimed
merely to end the previous policy of monetary contraction, but by
September 1953 they had adopted a program of "active ease." The
motivations for this policy were summed up by one member, who
stated, "the System should be trying to build factors which would offset
any down-tum in the economy. . . . [Thus] it would be desirable to
pursue a policy of active ease by putting reserves liberally into the
market" ( Minutes, 9 /8 /5 3 , p. 11). This switch to antirecessionary policy
is also indicated by the decision to remove any mention of inflation
from the directive, leaving as the primary goal of open market opera­
tions "avoiding deflationary tendencies" ( Minutes, 9 /2 4 /5 3 , p. 29).12
1957 Monetary policy in 1957 was almost identical to that in 1953. Once
again, the Federal Reserve perceived the downturn immediately. While
10. The speed with which the Federal Reserve recognizes recessions has been analyzed

by other researchers. See, for example, Hinshaw (1968), Kareken and Solow (1963),
and Brunner and Meltzer (1964).
11. The Records of Policy Actions for each year are compiled in the Annual Reports of the
Board of Governors. Citations to this source are only identified by the year and page
number. Citations to the M inutes are identified by the title, date, and page number.
22. Technical considerations involving seasonal demand for reserves and Treasury fi­
nancing operations had some effect on the exact timing of the easing over this period.
Specifically, these considerations appear to have led the FOMC to ease slightly more
in June and September and slightly less in December.




26- ROMER & ROMER

the peak in real GDP occurred in the third quarter of 1957, the records
of the Federal Reserve show that as of the October 1,1957, meeting, the
FOMC noted that "an increasing number of business observers were
suggesting. .. that the prospective movement in activity was a decline"
(1957, p. 51). By the November 12 meeting, the FOMC perceived that
"there no longer was much doubt that at least a mild downturn in
business activity was under way" (1957, p. 56). In response to the
decline, on November 12 the FOMC changed its policy directive "to
eliminate the previous clause (b) which had called for restraining
inflationary pressures and to replace that clause with wording that
provided for open market operations with a v ie w ...'to fostering sus­
tainable growth in the economy without inflation by moderating the
pressures on bank reserves'" (1957, p. 56). The motivation for this
change was summed up by Vice Chairman Hayes, who stated that
"relaxing credit restraint. . . seems desirable in view of the possibility,
however remote, that the business adjustment may be more than a mild
dip" ( Minutes, 1 1 /1 2 /5 7 , p. 18). Thus, monetary policy was clearly
antirecessionary in this episode.
i960 The changes in monetary policy during the 1960 recession were
motivated largely by a belief that economic activity was roughly con­
stant or increasing slightly, not by perceptions that the economy was in
a recession. While the peak in real GDP occurred in the first quarter of
1960, as late as July 1960 the FOMCs perception was only that "little
upward momentum was evident,... and uncertainty regarding future
trends continued to be widespread" (1960, p. 58). The Federal Reserve
nevertheless moved to lower interest rates repeatedly over the first nine
months of the year in order to increase real growth. For example, in
May the FOMC felt that the "lack of exuberance in the business
picture.. .justified moving modestly in the direction of increasing the
supply of reserves available to the banking system" (I960, p. 53). It was
not until November that the FOMC realized that a recession was under
way (1960, pp. 70-71). By that time, however, balance of payments
considerations prevented further easing. Thus, the declines in interest
rates over this period were largely the result of shifts in policy in
response to news about real output, but were not truly antirecessionary.
1969 Real output reached its peak in the fourth quarter of 1969. Over
the last several months of 1969, the Federal Reserve gradually revised
its forecast of short-run growth downward to the point where its
expectation was that growth would be approximately zero over the
next several quarters. Concern about the high level of inflation, how­
ever, kept the FOMC from shifting to easier policy (see, e.g., 1970,




What Ends Recessmis? •27
p. 96). By February 1970 the forecast had been revised to predict
negative growth; as a result, the FOMC “ concluded that, in light of the
latest economic developments and the current business outlook, it was
appropriate to move gradually toward somewhat less restraint" (1970,
p. 103). The stance of policy actually shifted only slightly over the next
several months, however. But beginning in May, the FOMC moved
consistently toward easier policy. In May and June, this shift was to
some extent a response to “ strains" in financial markets. Throughout
the second half of the year, however, the easing was a response to the
weak state of the economy and a perception that inflation was moderat­
ing. In August, for example, the FOMC felt that "expectations of
continuing inflation had abated considerably___It was the consensus of
the Committee that monetary policy at present should be sufficiently
stimulative to foster moderate growth in real economic activity___
Against this background, the Committee decided that open market
operations should be directed at promoting some easing of conditions
in credit markets" (1970, p. 149). Thus, the falls in interest rates during
the 1969 recession were largely the result of deliberate antirecessionary
policies.
1973 Beginning roughly in February 1974, the Federal Reserve ex­
pected real output to fall in the first quarter and then to stay essentially
unchanged (see, for example, 1974, pp. 137, 144). While this suggests
that the Federal Reserve was quick to discern the onset of recession,
which we now date as having begun with the peak in the fourth
quarter of 1973, it was slow to realize its severity. It was not until the
October 14 FOMC meeting that the System acknowledged that there
would be an extended decline in real activity (1974, p. 207). As in
1969-1970, concern about inflation prevented the Federal Reserve from
loosening significantly during the early part of the recession, and in fact
led to considerable tightening in the spring of 1974 (see, e.g., 1974, pp.
107, 161). Beginning in September, however, the FOMC began to move
to ease policy significantly. This easing was clearly a response to the
recession; for example, the summary of actions by the Board of Gover­
nors in September through November states that “ the Board felt that
the weakening tendencies in the economy should be countered initially
through the use of monetary policy instruments other than the dis­
count rate. To this end, System open market operations became increas­
ingly less restrictive as the fall progressed" (1974, pp. 109-110; see also
pp. 202-203, 211, 213, 225). These antirecessionary policies continued
into the first part of 1975 (see, for example, 1975, pp. 142-143).
1980 At every meeting of the FOMC from July 1979 through the
summer of 1980, the Federal Reserve believed that a recession was




2 8 - ROMER & ROMER

either under way or was imminent. Concern about inflation and money
growth, however, prevented policymakers from moving to lower inter­
est rates until the spring of 1980. Beginning in April 1980, just after the
actual peak in real GDP in the first quarter of 1980, the combination of
weak money growth and unfavorable news about real output caused
the FOMC to lower the federal funds rate sharply. The FOMC did not
want to "exacerbate recessionary tendencies in the economy" and was
concerned about "the risk that the contraction would prove to be
deeper than was widely expected" (1980, pp. 117, 122).
1981 Real GDP peaked in the third quarter of 1981. As early as Novem­
ber, "the consensus [of the FOMC] was that the downward drift in
economic activity apparent when the Committee met in early October
had clearly developed into a recession" (1981, p. 136). The major
declines in interest rates occurred in the fourth quarter of 1981 and in
the third and fourth quarters of 1982. The declines in late 1981, like
those in the spring of 1980, were partly a response to weak money
growth and partly a direct response to the recession. By July 1982, the
FOMC wanted "to provide sufficient monetary growth to encourage
recovery in economic activity over the months ahead" (1982,
pp. 109-110). FOMC members stressed "the need for flexibility in
interpreting the behavior of the monetary aggregates" and felt that
money growth "near, or for a time somewhat above, the upper ends of
[the target] ranges would be acceptable" (1982, p. 111). Although con­
cern with the growth of monetary aggregates was an important motive
in monetary policy over this period, direct concern about real activity
and the effects of the recession on the financial system was important as
well
1990 In the most recent recession the Federal Reserve began to worry
about a downturn long before it occurred. As early as December 1989,
the FOMC viewed "the risks of a shortfall in economic activity as
sufficiently high to justify an immediate move to slightly easier reserve
conditions" (1989, pp. 135-136). In July 1990, immediately after what
we now know was the peak in real GDP, the FOMC expected "sus­
tained but subdued growth in economic activity. . . for the next several
quarters (1990, p. 120). In response they called for "some easing fairly
soon unless incoming indicators indicated appreciably stronger mone­
tary growth and greater inflationary pressures than the members cur­
rently expected" (1990, p. 126).

While the Federal Reserve was quick to worry about recession, it was
fairly slow to realize that a recession was actually in progress during the
fall of 1990. In October the FOMC believed that "the available data do




What Ends Recessions? * 29
not point to cumulating weakness and the onset of a recession" (1990,
p. 139). They nevertheless felt that "an easing move was warranted in
light of indications that there was a significant risk of a much weaker
economy" (1990, p. 141). Not until November did a consensus develop
that "the most likely outcome was a relatively mild and brief downturn"
(1990, p. 148). At this point, the FOMC voted for some slight immediate
easing of reserve conditions and indicated that "the growing signs of a
softening economy. . . suggested that the Committee should remain
alert. . . to signals that some further easing was appropriate" (1990,
p. 149). Thus it appears that, although the falls in interest rates through­
out 1990 were motivated by movements in real output, only those after
November 1990 were truly antirecessionary.
3.2.2 Lessons from Postwar Monetary Policy This analysis of the motiva­
tions for policy suggests that monetary policy can respond quickly to
changes in economic conditions. The Federal Reserve has almost always
recognized that a recession was underway very rapidly. Only in 1960
and 1990 was there a lag of more than one quarter between the peak
and when the Federal Reserve perceived a downturn. And even in
these two instances, the Federal Reserve loosened in response to what
it perceived as merely slow growth.
In most instances the Federal Reserve responded to the weakening
economy by increasing reserves immediately. This suggests that the
declines in interest rates during recessions documented in Section 2
were at least partly the result of antirecessionary monetary policy. In
those instances where policymakers did not cut interest rates in re­
sponse to the weakening of the economy, it was typically because some
other factor, such as inflation or balance of payments difficulties, was
thought to necessitate tight policy.
The fact that the Boschen and Mills index of Federal Reserve inten­
tions shows a move toward inflation control soon after the start of most
recoveries is also important. It suggests that most periods of high
inflation are not the result of antirecessionary monetary policy carried
too far. Rather, they are more likely the result of expansionary policies
taken for reasons unrelated to recessions or of insufficient shifts toward
combating inflation once recoveries have begun. Thus, policy mistakes
are not an inherent feature of antirecessionary monetary policy.
3.2 FISCAL POLICY
Our primary source for the history of fiscal policy is the Economic Report
of the President, published biennially from 1948 to 1952 and then annu­
ally from 1953 through the present. The Economic Reports contain




30* ROMER & ROMER

detailed descriptions and justifications of the President's fiscal policy
recommendations. They also summarize the fiscal policies actually im­
plemented in the preceding year. If the policies implemented differ
from those previously recommended by the administration, some dis­
cussion or critique of Congress's motives is usually given. As a result,
the Economic Reports provide unique insight into both the motivation
for policy and the lags in taking fiscal actions.13
3.2.2 Episodes
The end of the Korean War caused a substantial decline in
government spending in 1953. When a recession began in the second
quarter of 1953, the Eisenhower administration did not take any notice­
able steps to increase spending. It did, however, move to reduce taxes
shortly before the trough of the recession in the second quarter of 1954.
In January 1954 an extensive tax cut went into effect that reduced taxes
during the first six months of 1954 by $1.1 billion, or about 0.6% of GDP
over this period (1955, p. 19). This tax cut eliminated two wartime tax
increases: the excess profits tax passed in 1950, and the personal and
corporate income tax increases put into place in 1951.
Whether this fiscal action was truly antirecessionary is ambiguous
because the original legislation called for the excess profits tax to expire
on June 30,1953, and the personal income tax increase to be rescinded
on December 31, 1953. Three pieces of evidence, however, suggest that
it was largely discretionary. First, the excess profits tax was extended for
six months early in 1953 at the urging of President Eisenhower, who
felt that a tax cut in mid-1953 would be inflationary. Second, the 1953
Economic Report includes among its 1954 budget deficit projections, the
situation that would occur "if the post-Korea tax increases are not
allowed to run off as provided by present law" (1953, p. 71). This
suggests that the Truman administration thought an extension of the
wartime taxes was a likely outcome. Finally, the Eisenhower Economic
Report of 1954 treats the tax decrease as an important antirecessionary
act. It states:

1953

The Secretary of the Treasury therefore announced in the plainest possible
language that the Administration, besides relinquishing the excess-profits tax,
would not seek to postpone the reduction of the personal income tax, averag­
ing approximately 10 percent, scheduled for January 1, 1954. This unequivocal
promise of tax relief to both families and business firms bolstered confidence at
a time when trade and employment were slipping slightly. In coming months
23. Unless otherwise noted, all citations in this section refer to the Economic Reports .




What Ends Recessions? •31
these well-timed tax reductions are likely to give substantial support to con­
sumer and investment markets. (1954, p. 52)
Even if the tax reduction was discretionary, it is obvious that this is an
unusual case. The president rarely has a tax cut passed and waiting
prior to the onset of recession. Thus, there was more flexibility in fiscal
policy in 1953 than at almost any other time.14
The 1957 recession began in the third quarter of 1957. The only
significant fiscal change that occurred soon after the onset of the
recession was an acceleration of defense spending. The Eisenhower
administration accelerated the placement of defense contracts, and in
January 1958 requested supplemental appropriations of $1.3 billion
from Congress as an advance on 1959 spending. Although the adminis­
tration stressed that national security was the main motivation for these
actions, it was quick to point out the economic benefits. For example,
the 1958 Economic Report states, "A t the turn of the year, the economy
was beginning to feel the effects of an acceleration of the placement of
defense contract awards, prompted by the need to move forward
quickly with programs essential to the strengthening of the Nation's
defenses" (1958, p. 8). The frequent references to the economic benefits
of this spending suggests that at least some of the motivation was
antirecessionary.
The 1959 Economic Report indicates that similar types of spending
acceleration were undertaken around the trough in the first quarter of
1958. In March and April 1958, spending on federal programs for
building airports, hospitals, and other public buildings was moved
forward. In April 1958, legislation was passed to increase spending on
the interstate highway program (1959, pp. 41-42). Both of these mea­
sures were consistent with the Eisenhower philosophy that "the major
emphasis of Federal countercyclical policy should be placed on mea­
sures that will result in prompt action___ Though a useful contribution
can be made by the acceleration of public works projects that are
already under way or are ready to be started, little reliance can be
placed on large undertakings which. . . can be put into operation only
after an extended interval of planning" (1959, p. 2). In addition to these
measures, Congress passed, at the administration's request, a temporary
extension of unemployment benefits in June 1958 (1959, p. 40). Several
1957

14. Despite the reduction in taxes, the high-employment surplus to GDP ratio actually

rose slightly in 1954 because of an even greater reduction in spending. However, since
the decline in expenditures reflected both external shocks and long-term national
security planning, it seems reasonable to view fiscal policy as quite expansionary in
1954 relative to likely alternatives.




32* ROMER & ROMER

minor spending bills passed in July 1958 were also taken at least partly
in response to the state of the economy (Bartlett, 1993).
i960 Real GDP peaked in the first quarter of 1960. The 1961 Economic
Report indicates that no significant antirecessionary fiscal actions were

taken before the trough in the fourth quarter of 1960. Numerous
actions, however, were taken in the quarter just after the turning point
in GDP. The first Kennedy administration Economic Report in January
1962 reports that "immediately upon taking office, the new Administra­
tion moved vigorously to use the fiscal powers of the Federal Govern­
ment to help bring about economic recovery" (1962, p. 82). Among the
measures proposed and quickly passed were an acceleration of federal
procurement and tax refunds, changes in transfer programs that added
$2 billion to transfer payments over fiscal years 1961 and 1962 com­
bined, and the Temporary Extended Unemployment Compensation
Act, which extended coverage.15 Despite this flurry of activity, the total
amount spent under these programs was quite small.
An investment tax credit equal to 7% of gross investment in deprecia­
ble machinery and equipment was also proposed early in the Kennedy
administration and was passed in October 1962. Interestingly, this
action is discussed in the chapter of the Economic Report on policies to
encourage economic growth, not in the chapter on economic recovery.
The 1962 Report states that "if faster economic growth is desired,
revision of the tax structure is called for, to permit a higher rate of
investment once full use of resources is achieved" (1962, p. 132). While
the Report points out that increased investment will stimulate aggregate
demand, this does not seem to be the primary motivation behind the
program. Thus, this often noted Kennedy fiscal stimulus appears to
have been primarily motivated not by the 1960 recession, but rather by
supply-side issues related to long-term growth.
The motivation for the even more famous 1964 tax cut appears to be a
mixture of concern about sluggish growth and concern about incen­
tives. It is clear from the 1963 Economic Report, which contains the first
discussion of this proposed tax reduction, that the act was not some
grossly delayed response to the 1960 recession. The Report states that
we approach the issue of tax revision, not in an atmosphere of haste
and panic brought on by recession or depression, but in a period of
15. Two other measures, the Area Redevelopment Act enacted in May 1961 and the
Public Works Acceleration Act enacted in September 1962, were designed to aid areas
with particularly high and persistent unemployment. Whether these programs should
be viewed as antirecessionary acts or general antipoverty measures is unclear. How­
ever, neither program was very large.




What Ends Recessions? •33
comparative calm" (1963, p. xiii). The Report goes on to argue that
"O n ly when we have removed the heavy drag our fiscal system now
exerts on personal and business purchasing power and on the financial
incentives for greater risk-taking and personal effort can we expect to
restore the high levels of employment and high rate of growth that we
took for granted in the first decade after the war" (1963, p. xv). While
supply-side effects are certainly emphasized, there is sufficient discus­
sion of underutilized capacity and unemployment in the 1963 and 1964
Economic Reports that it seems clear that the aggregate demand effects of
the tax cut were also a major factor in the proposal, and in the ultimate
passage of the act in February 1964.
1969 Real output peaked in the third quarter of 1969. The 1970 Eco­
nomic Report makes it clear that inflation was such an overriding

concern that the administration resisted efforts by Congress to increase
spending or reduce taxes. It states, "the best hope of curbing inflation
and restricting the rise in unemployment. . . rests with a policy of firm
and persistent restraint on the expansion in the demand for goods,
services, and labor" (1970, p. 22). The one obviously antirecessionary
measure that was proposed (and ultimately passed in August 1970,
shortly after the trough in output) was the Employment Security
Amendments, which provided additional unemployment benefits once
the insured unemployment rate exceeded 4j% for three consecutive
months.
In 1971 the administration sought to run a balanced full-employment
budget. The 1971 Economic Report indicates that the administration
"strongly resisted program expansion which would substantially raise
commitments for expenditures beyond 1970" (1971, p. 26) and took no
fiscal measures aimed at stemming the recession. There were some
increases in transfer payments because of a change in social security
benefits and an increase in revenue-sharing to the states, but neither of
these measures appears to have been related to the state of the econ­
omy. Therefore, any fall in the high-employment surplus in 1970 and
1971 was motivated by considerations other than the recession.16
26. One ambiguity in the 1970 fiscal record concerns the 10% income tax surcharge
implemented in 1968. This surcharge, which was set to expire on June 30, 1969, was
extended in August at the urging of the President to cover the last six months of 1969.
In December Congress approved a reduction of the surcharge to 5% and an extension
to June 30,1970. Given this record of extensions, the failure to extend the surcharge in
mid-1970 could be viewed as an antirecessionary policy. However, the 1970 Economic
Report does not speak of the expiration in this way. It states that "the tight expendi­
ture control recommended for the budget for fiscal 1971... is intended to prevent"
excessive stimulus caused by the expiration of the tax surcharge (1970, p. 59).




34- ROMER & ROMER

in August 1971, more than a year after the trough in the second
quarter of 1970, the Nixon administration proposed the "N e w Eco­
nomic Policy" This proposal called for an end to gold convertibility, a
10% surcharge on imports, a wage and price freeze, and a substantial
fiscal expansion. Among the fiscal changes that were passed by Congress
in 1971 were an increase in the personal income tax exemption, the
removal of some excise taxes, a 7% job development credit, and the
reinstatement of the investment tax credit. According to Carlson (1981),
the Revenue Act of 1971 reduced annual tax revenues by $8 billion, or
0.7% of GDP. The 1972 Economic Report makes clear that the administra­
tion was well aware that the economy was already recovering before
the New Economic Policy was proposed. It states, "[The administration]
believed that a more rapid expansion of the economy than was gener­
ally forecast was desirable and feasible" (1972, p. 21). Thus, the fall in
the high-employment surplus in 1972 was motivated not by an attempt
to end a recession, but by a desire for more rapid growth.
1973 Real GDP peaked in the fourth quarter of 1973. The immediate
response of the administration was to do nothing. According to the
1974 Economic Report, "the budget proposed by the President. . . would
inject no fiscal stimulus to push the economy above its average rate of
expansion" (1974, p. 29).17 By January 1975, shortly before the trough in
real GDP, the administration perceived that the economy was in a
severe recession and proposed a one-year tax cut of $16 billion. The
Economic Report for this year refers to it as an "antirecession tax cut"
(1975, p. 7), and it is clear that there was no motivation other than the
recession. The Tax Reduction Act of 1975 was passed by Congress in
March 1975. The largest component of this act was a rebate of approxi­
mately 10% of 1974 personal income taxes, which was paid in May and
September 1975. The act also lowered individual income taxes for 1975
by increasing the standard deduction and by granting a $30 credit to
each taxpayer. The act also reduced corporate liabilities by a substantial
amount, mainly through an increase in the investment tax credit from
7% to 10%.

There were minor spending changes in 1975 as well. The 1975

Economic Report states that "in response to the sharp rise in unemploy­
ment in the second half of 1974, two new laws that affect the unem­
ployment insurance program were enacted in December 1974" (1975,
p. 120). The Emergency Unemployment Compensation Act extended
unemployment insurance by 13 weeks, and the Emergency Jobs and
Unemployment Assistance Act gave unemployment benefits to some
17. The 1975 Economic Report states that fiscal policy in 1974 was more contractionary
than anticipated because of the revenue-increasing effects of inflation (1975, p. 60).




What Ends Recessions? * 35
uncovered workers and provided for a small public service employment
program. These programs were entirely motivated by the recession. The
only major change in spending that was not unambiguously antireces­
sionary was a 7% increase in social security benefits passed in April
1974. Taken as a whole, antirecessionary fiscal policy actions were very
large in 1975 and explain most of the fall in the high-employment
surplus in this year.
The Revenue Adjustment Act of 1975 extended most of the personal
and corporate tax cuts included in the Tax Reduction Act of 1975
through the first six months of 1976. The 1977 Economic Report states
that “ the objective of fiscal policy in 1976 was to maintain the degree of
stimulus provided during 1975 in order to keep the economy on a
course of moderate, sustained expansion" (1977, p. 69). The Tax Reform
Act of 1976 extended many of the 1975 tax changes through 1977. The
Ford administration argued in favor of a permanent extension, and
even called for larger tax cuts, on the grounds that the changes would
stimulate investment and long-term growth (1977, pp. 4-5). Thus, it
appears that by mid-1976 the motivation for policy had shifted from
antirecessionary considerations to a desire to stimulate long-run eco­
nomic progress.
According to the first Carter administration Economic Report in Jan­
uary 1978, the administration “ proposed a series of measures intended
to raise the rate of growth of real output in 1977 and 1978 to a pace that
would lead to significant reductions in the unemployment rate" (1978,
p. 50). Among the actions taken were the Tax Reduction and Simplifi­
cation Act of 1977, which led to net tax reductions of roughly $5 billion
and $10 billion in 1977 and 1978, respectively, largely through increases
in the personal standard deduction and an employment tax credit. A
variety of public works, public service employment, and training pro­
grams were funded by the Economic Stimulus Appropriations Act in
the spring of 1977 and were aimed at stimulating the economy. These
spending increases amounted to roughly $1 billion in 1977 and $7
billion in 1978. The motivation for all of these programs was clearly to
increase growth from an already moderate level. For example, the
President's section of the 1978 Economic Report states, “ I have begun
from the premise that our economy is basically healthy" and “ the
American economy is completing three years of recovery from the
severe recession of 1974-75“ (1978, p. 3).
1980 The 1980 recession began in the first quarter of 1980 and ended in
the second. The Carter administration, apparently chastened by in­
creases in inflation during its first years in office, took no expansionary
fiscal actions in response to the downturn. The 1981 Economic Report




3 6 - ROMER & ROMER

states, "twice in the last decade the tendency for government to
stimulate the economy somewhat too freely during the recovery from
recession probably played a role in retarding the decline of inflation or
renewing its acceleration. That is why I was so insistent that a tax cut
designed for quick economic stimulus not be enacted last year (1981,
p. 8). In fact, inflation was seen as such an overriding problem that
Carter proposed tightening fiscal policy in January 1980, when the
Economic Report noted "that a mild recession is widely forecast" (1980,
p. 9). The administration believed that "this austere budget policy,
accompanied by supportive policies of monetary restraint, is a neces­
sary condition for controlling inflation" (1980, p. 6).18
1981 Following a brief recovery in late 1980 and early 1981, the econ­
omy slipped into another recession in the third quarter of 1981. This
recession lasted until the third quarter of 1982. Fiscal policy changes in
the first year of the Reagan administration were enormous. The Eco­
nomic Recovery Tax Act of 1981 reduced both personal and business
taxes substantially. In addition to the tax reductions, federal spending
rose substantially, mainly because of increases in real national defense
purchases (as measured by the National Income and Product Accounts)
of 6% in 1981 and 7% in 1982.
Despite its name, the Economic Recovery Tax Act of 1981 appears not
to have been motivated by the recession. The 1982 Economic Report
states that "the major elements of the Administration's economic policy
are designed to increase long-term growth and to reduce inflation.
Uniformly favorable near-term effects were not expected" (1982, p. 24).
It specifically identifies the Economic Recovery Tax Act as one of those
long-term policies, and the short-term stimulatory effects are never
mentioned (1982, p. 44). Even the 1984 Economic Report only mentions
the aggregate demand effects of the tax cut in the context of discussing
why the deficit is not an immediate danger to the economy (1984,
p. 39).

There is similarly little emphasis on the short-term stimulatory effects
of the increase in defense expenditures. The 1982 Economic Report
makes it clear that national security was the main motive behind the
spending program when it states that "any economic effects, however,

H ln
^anom ic Report emphasizes that the fall in the high-employment surplus in
1980 was not deliberate. Rather, it was due to the "delayed effect on individual tax
refunds and final settlements from the Revenue Act of 1978" and “ to large increases
in interest outlays caused by record high interest rates7' (1981 pp 156-157)




What Ends Recessions? •37
must be assessed in the context of the overriding need for maintaining
the level of defense spending necessary for national security" (1982,
p. 85). Furthermore, the main short-term effects that were contemplated
were bottlenecks and price increases in industries that supply defense
goods (1982, p. 86). Thus, it appears that fiscal changes in 1981-1982
were almost entirely motivated by factors other than the recession.
1990 The most recent recession began in the second quarter of 1990
and ended in the first quarter of 1991. Fiscal policy was essentially
unchanged during the recession. One explanation for this absence of
discretionary fiscal policy is that the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act
had been passed in November 1990. Given its stress on "credible and
systematic" policies (1991, p. 4), the Bush administration did not want
to change fiscal policy so soon after the budget agreement.19 The only
significant fiscal action proposed in 1991 was a cut in the tax rate on
long-term capital gains, and this measure was defeated in Congress.
According to the 1993 Economic Report, "w hen the need for a fiscal
policy that would provide immediate stimulus became increasingly
clear in late 1991," the Bush administration proposed several small fiscal
changes (1993, p. 51). Among the measures taken were executive ac­
tions to reduce personal income tax withholding and to accelerate the
spending of previously appropriated Federal funds. Legislation to re­
duce the capital gains tax, to provide for a temporary investment tax
allowance, to enhance depreciation for certain companies, and to pro­
vide for a temporary tax credit for first-time homebuyers was also
proposed. None of these programs were very large, however, and none
were passed by Congress.

3.2.2 Lessons from Postwar Fiscal Policy This analysis of the motivations
of policy suggests some important facts about postwar fiscal policy.
First, there is abundant evidence that limited fiscal stimulus can be
undertaken rapidly.20 Either slightly before or concurrent with most
troughs, there were small increases in government spending that were
motivated almost entirely by the state of the economy. This suggests
19. The 1993 Economic Report states that "the Budget Enforcement Act of 1990, the

ongoing defense downsizing, and a political stalemate between the Administration
and the Congress played important roles in keeping fiscal policy from being more
stimulative" (1993, pp. 55-56).
20. Bartlett (1993) reaches a more pessimistic conclusion about the speed with which even
small fiscal actions can be taken. This difference is attributable mainly to the fact that
Bartlett concentrates on public works programs, rather than on all spending and tax
programs undertaken to end recessions.




38- ROMER & ROMER

that the small falls in the high-employment surplus to GDP ratio
around troughs documented in Section 2 were mainly the result of
antirecessionary policy.
The nature of these rapid spending changes, however, provides
insight into why the changes were almost always quite small. The
spending increases have typically been limited to actions that can be
taken without congressional approval, such as the acceleration of
planned spending or tax refunds, or to actions for which congressional
approval is easy to obtain, such as the extension or expansion of
unemployment insurance benefits. Since the number of such actions is
inherently limited by the structure of the U.S. government, it would be
unrealistic to infer from the modest increases in spending around
postwar troughs that equally rapid but more aggressive fiscal responses
were possible.
The postwar record on major legislated antirecessionary actions is
complicated. There are no examples of major spending changes under­
taken in response to recessions. There are, however, two times when
taxes were cut in response to recessions: 1953 and 1975. (Taxes were
also cut during the 1981 recession, but there is no evidence that this cut
was motivated by the cyclical condition of the economy.) But both tax
cuts were unusual in ways that may limit their relevance to other
recessions. In 1953, the tax cut had already been passed before the
recession began; all Eisenhower had to do was not ask that it be
delayed. In 1975, the recession was particularly long; it had already
been going on for over a year before any policy action was taken. A
more positive interpretation of the 1975 experience, however, is that in
response to a particularly severe recession, effective measures can
eventually be taken. Consistent with this positive interpretation is the
fact that the lag between when the tax cut was officially proposed and
when the first rebate actually appeared was only five months.
Perhaps the most important lesson to be learned from this analysis is
that most large fiscal actions have been taken in response to slow
recoveries rather than to actual recessions. The 1964 tax cut, Nixon's
New Economic Policy," and Carter's tax cut and spending increases
were all passed to increase growth in a sluggish but basically healthy
economy. This fact is significant because the potential for policy mis­
takes, for overheating the economy and generating inflation, is much
higher for such policies than for those passed in the depth of recession.
Finally, the record of the specific actions taken in response to reces­
sions suggests that focusing on the high-employment surplus is likely
to lead, if anything, to overestimates of the extent of antirecessionary




What Ends Recessions? •39
fiscal stimulus. Most of the actions took the form of temporary tax cuts,
temporary changes in transfers, and changes in the timing of disburse­
ments, all of which may have much smaller effects than long-lasting
changes in purchases or taxes.

4. The Contribution of Macroeconomic Policies
to Recoveries
As Sichel (1992) and Beaudry and Koop (1993) document, recessions are
typically followed by periods of very rapid growth. For the eight
recessions since 1950, real growth in the four quarters after the trough
has averaged 4.6%, and has exceeded the average annual postwar
growth rate of 2.75% in every recovery except the current one.21 In this
section we attempt to measure the contribution of policy to this spurt of
rapid growth following troughs. In particular, we ask whether in the
absence of policy actions, output growth after troughs would have
continued to be negative, been equal to its average postwar value, or
been even higher than it actually was.
To measure the role of policy, it is clearly not enough to just establish
how monetary and fiscal policy changed during recessions and recover­
ies; we also need estimates of the magnitude and timing of the policies'
effects. Therefore, in this section we construct such estimates and
analyze their implications. We do not attempt to shed new light on the
underlying question of whether monetary and fiscal policy have real
effects. For this exercise we take it as given that policy affects output,
and seek to provide plausible estimates of the size of those effects.
4.1 ESTIMATING THE EFFECTS OF POLICY
4.2.1 Baseline Policies Any description of how policies have affected the
course of the economy must compare the economy's actual behavior
with how it would have behaved if policies had followed some baseline
paths. Thus, the analysis requires specifying baseline policies. We take
as our baselines a constant real federal funds rate and a constant ratio
of the high-employment surplus to trend GDP. Thus, we are attempting
to estimate the contributions of changes in the real funds rate and in
the ratio of the high-employment surplus to trend GDP to the path of
real output.
21. We calculate average growth over the period 1953:2 to 1993:2, which is the sample
period used in our subsequent calculations. Throughout, percentage changes are
computed as changes in logarithms.




40- ROMER & ROMER

These baseline policies are approximately feasible. Unpredictable
movements in expected inflation, and in receipts and expenditures for a
given level of activity, make it impossible for policymakers to keep the
real funds rate and the high-employment surplus to trend GDP ratio
exactly constant. On a quarterly basis, however, these shocks are likely
to be small. This would not be true of some other potential baselines;
quarterly shocks to the money supply and to the unadjusted deficit, for
example, appear to be large.
Over the longer term, there is no reason that fiscal policy cannot keep
the high-employments surplus to trend GDP ratio roughly constant.
Monetary policy, on the other hand, cannot keep the real interest rate
above or below its long-term equilibrium level indefinitely without
causing unbounded deflation or inflation. But movements in the sus­
tainable level of the real interest rate are likely to be gradual. Thus,
attributing movements in the real interest rate that are in fact due to
changes in its sustainable level to changes in monetary policy will not
have a large effect on the analysis of the sources of short-run output
movements.22
4.2.2 Approaches to Estimating the Effects of Policy We estimate the effects
of monetary and fiscal policy in three ways. The first two approaches
are based on simple regressions, and the third is based on a large
macroeconomic model.
Our first regression is an ordinary least squares (OLS) regression of
real GDP growth on eight lags of the change in our estimate of the real
federal funds rate and on the current and eight lags of the change in
the high-employment surplus to GDP ratio. We also include a constant,
a dummy variable for the post-1973 period (to account for the produc­
tivity growth slowdown), and eight lags of the dependent variable.23
The OLS estimates are likely to provide conservative estimates of the
effects of changes in the real interest rate. Most importantly, if the
Federal Reserve changes the real funds rate on the basis of information
about future output movements beyond that contained in the right-hand
^ VS*

no*

^rue ^ we took a constant nominal funds rate as our baseline.

Attempting to peg the nominal rate at an unsustainable level would lead to accelerat-

I t ? 8® m lnflf on' thAe real rate, and output. Thus, the effect of changes in the
farf a f3 \ ISeX^ ° S1Ve'
3 resu^' attributing shifts in the nominal rate that are in
vpiI l^p°AC
fw ISeS 1Yl u S SUS1tamable ievel to chanSes in monetary policy would have
very large effects on the analysis of the sources of output movements.
the

s s s

UC ° ^ e ChangC in the real

'k

e




s

t

,? , ™ L r * , » r " ng ,he

rate

Bounds that

p° iicy v,,i*bi“

What Ends Recessions? * 41
side variables of the regression, the changes in the real rate will be
positively correlated with the error term. As a result, the OLS estimates
will be biased upward (that is, toward zero). Since, as Section 3 de­
scribes, monetary policy responds very rapidly to economic develop­
ments, this effect is likely be to present to some extent. Similarly, any
additional information that consumers have about future output move­
ments will cause the real rate to rise before increases in output, again
biasing the OLS estimates of the effects of changes in the real rate
toward zero.
Contemporaneous interaction between changes in the real rate and
output growth has more complex effects on the OLS estimates. Since
simple examples suggest that such interaction is likely also to bias the
estimates toward zero, and since the reaction of output to the real
interest rate within the quarter is likely to be small in any event, this
effect is unlikely to reverse the effects of the other biases.24
Thus, the OLS estimates seem much more likely to understate than
overstate the effects of changes in the real funds rate. Since there are
important sources of variation in real interest rates, such as concern
about inflation and political considerations, that are not likely to be
substantially correlated with sources of output movements not included
in the regression, the bias may not be serious. And for fiscal policy,
where major policy shifts appear to require at least several quarters to
implement, and where there are many important sources of variation in
policy other than economic conditions, significant correlation with the
error term appears unlikely. Thus, for fiscal policy the bias from using
OLS is likely to be small.
Because of the potential bias of the OLS estimates, our second set of
estimates of policies' effects are derived from instrumental variables (IV)
estimation of the regression just described, with the changes in the real
rate treated as endogenous. As instruments, we employ the Romer and
Romer (1989, 1994) and Boschen and Mills (1992) indexes of Federal
Reserve policy. We use 16 lags both of the Romer-Romer index and of
the change in the Boschen-Mills index.
The Romer-Romer index is a simple dummy variable equal to one on
dates of apparent shifts by the Federal Reserve to policies designed to
24. Suppose the true model is Ay, = aQbrt + a1Art_1 + bAy,_j + ejf, Ar, = a0Ay* +
aiAy*_i +
+ ert, where the e's are independent white-noise shocks, a0and al
are negative, a0 is positive, b is positive (reflecting the positive serial correlation of
output growth), and (Jis negative (reflecting the negative serial correlation of changes
in the real interest rate). For this case, one can show that the true effect of a change in
Ar on output growth in the subsequent period is larger (in absolute value) than what
one would obtain from an OLS regression of Ay, on Art_t and Ay,„j.




42* ROMER & ROMER

reduce inflation from its current level Because these policy shifts to
combat inflation appear to be largely the result of changes in tastes, and
not responses to additional information about future output move­
ments, the index should be essentially uncorrelated with the error term
of the regression. Thus, the Romer and Romer dates should allow the
IV regression to estimate the output effects of interest rate changes. The
Boschen-Mills index described in the previous section is a less-than-ideal
instrument because Boschen and Mills do not distinguish Federal Re­
serve actions that are independent of the economy from those that are
responses to the predicted behavior of the economy. However, if one
believes that most changes in stated Federal Reserve intentions repre­
sent independent policy shifts, then this index is a useful instrument for
isolating the effects of policy-generated changes in interest rates.
Both the OLS and IV regressions are estimated over the period 1957:2
to 1988:4; the sample period is dictated by the availability of the
Boschen-Mills index. To drive policy multipliers from these regressions,
we use the coefficient estimates to calculate the dynamic multipliers for
a one-percentage-point fall in the real federal funds rate and a one-percentage-point fall in the high-employment surplus to GDP ratio.
Our third set of estimates of policies' effects are from the Data
Resources Incorporated (DRI) model of the U.S. economy. Using a large
macroeconomic model has the advantage that it incorporates a great
deal of information and judgment. It has the disadvantages, however,
that it is much less transparent than the regressions and that its
implications may reflect the model builders' priors rather than charac­
teristics of the data. For monetary policy, the experiment we consider in
the model is a permanent one-percentage-point change in the real
federal funds rate with the parameters governing fiscal policy held
fixed. For fiscal policy, we consider a permanent change in personal
income taxes of 1% of GDP with the real funds rate held fixed.25

4.1.3 Results Figure 3 shows the multipliers for monetary policy im­
plied by the two regressions and by the DRI model. The OLS regression
implies that a permanent one-percentage-point fall in the real funds
rate raises real GDP by 1.7%. Most of this effect comes between the
second and fifth quarters after the increase. As one would expect, the IV
regression implies a somewhat larger impact. The overall effect is now a

25.

I
^
I
investlSated averaging the multipliers for a change in taxes
with those for a change in government purchases. This resulted in a considerably
larger effect m the quarter of the policy change and had Uttle effectThTreafter
chanees iTtax^and
antirf essionary fiscal actions have taken the form of
changes in taxes and transfers, we focus on the multipliers for a change in taxes.




YJhat Ends Recessions? •43
Figure 3 MULTIPLIERS FOR MONETARY POLICY
a. OLS Regression
4 -------------------------------------------------------------------

3 --

1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10 11 12

8

9

10 11 12

Quarters
b. IV Regression

1

0

1

2

3

4

5 6 7
Quarters

c. DRI Model

rise in real GDP of 3.6%; the timing is similar to that with OLS.26 The
DRI model implies a rise in real GDP of 1.1%, with most of the effect

26. We also estimated the IV multipliers using as instruments only the Romer-Romer
index and the exogenous right-hand-side variables. The results are very similar to
those shown in Figure 3. The implied multiplier for a one-percentage-point rise in the
real federal funds rate reaches a maximum impact on real GDP of 4.3% after 12
quarters; the timing is the same as that for the OLS and basic IV regressions. Because
the Romer-Romer index is a dummy equal to one on only a small number of dates,
the point estimates for the limited IV regression are substantially less precise than
those from the standard version.




4 4 - ROMER & ROMER

coming between one and four quarters after the change.
Figure 4 shows the estimated multipliers for fiscal policy. The OLS
regression implies that a permanent fall of one percentage point in the
ratio of the high-employment surplus to trend GDP raises output by
1.1%. The effect occurs gradually over about 10 quarters. The IV esti­
mates imply that the effects of lowering the surplus to GDP ratio are
small and irregular. Taken literally, the estimates imply that fiscal policy
has essentially no effects. However, because the standard errors are

Figure 4 MULTIPLIERS FOR FISCAL POLICY
a. OLS Regression
4 ----------- — ------------------------------------3 ■■

0

1 2

3

4

5

6

7

Quarters

b. IV Regression

Quarters

c. DRI Model




8

9

10 11 12

What Ends Recessions? •45
large, the IV regression does not provide strong evidence against
conventional views of the effects of fiscal policy. For example, the two
standard error confidence interval for the sum of the coefficients on the
surplus to GDP ratio is (-1 .5 9 , 1.70); for comparison, the OLS estimate
is —0.74. We therefore, do not place great emphasis on the point
estimates of the effects of fiscal policy from the IV regression. Finally,
the DRI model implies that the effect of a fall of one percentage point in
the surplus to GDP ratio on real GDP peaks after four quarters at 1.4%
and then gradually declines.
4.2 IMPLICATIONS FOR THE SOURCE OF RECOVERIES
Table 6 summarizes the implications of these estimated multipliers for
the sources of output growth in the four quarters after troughs. Specif­
ically, for each of the three sets of multipliers, Table 6 reports the
implied average contributions during these periods of macroeconomic
policies and other factors. The policy contributions are divided both
according to whether they reflect monetary or fiscal policy and accord­
ing to whether they reflect actions before the peaks in real output or
after. In addition, the contributions of fiscal policy are divided into the
effects of automatic and discretionary policy. The reason for separating
the effects of prepeak and postpeak policies is that the multipliers
suggest that the lags in the effects of monetary policy are sufficiently
long that the shifts to tighter monetary policy before peaks continue to
depress growth even after troughs. Thus, what we need to understand
is not simply why output growth is above normal in recoveries, but
why it is above normal despite the previous monetary tightenings.

Table 6 ESTIMATES OF THE CONTRIBUTIONS OF MONETARY AND FISCAL
POLICIES TO GROWTH IN THE FIRST YEAR OF RECOVERIES
Contribution to growth (percentage points)
Prepeak policies
Source o f
multipliers

Monetary
OLS
IV
DRI

-0 .9 2
-2 .0 5
-0 .1 4

Postpeak policies

Residual

Discretionary Automatic
Discretionary
fiscal
fiscal
Monetary
fiscal
-0 .1 8
0.00
0.27

-0.01
-0 .0 3
0.14

1.59
3.00
1.48

0.25
0.02
0.50

Automatic
fiscal
0.63
-0.41
0.85

0.45
1.30
-1 .3 0

Notes: The residual shows the com ponent o f the difference between mean growth in the year after
troughs and average annual growth that is not accounted for by prepeak and postpeak policies.
The difference between mean growth after troughs and average annual growth is 1.82 percentage
points; the rows may not add to this value due to rounding.




46- ROMER & ROMER

All three sets of estimates imply that the reductions in real interest
rates after peaks are crucial to recoveries. The OLS multipliers imply
that these reductions have added an average of 1.6 percentage points to
real growth during the first year of recoveries, the IV multipliers imply
that they have added 3.0 percentage points, and the DRI multipliers
imply that they have added 1.5 percentage points. Thus, the estimates
imply that the declines in real interest rates in recessions are large
enough, and their effects occur quickly enough, that they play a critical
role in the rapid growth during recoveries. Since average output growth
in the year following troughs is 4.6%, the OLS estimates imply that
without these declines, growth in the year after troughs would average
only 3.0%; the IV estimates imply that it would average just 1.6%; and
the DRI estimates imply it would average only 3.1%.27
The OLS and DRI estimates imply that discretionary fiscal expansions
after peaks contribute moderately to growth (not surprisingly, the IV
estimates imply that the effect is negligible). In both cases, however, the
majority of the estimated effect comes from the recovery from the
1973-1975 recession. In addition, because the changes in discretionary
fiscal policy in recessions have consisted disproportionately of tempo­
rary changes in taxes and transfers, the multipliers are likely to over­
state their effects. Thus, discretionary fiscal policy has played at most a
small role in recoveries.
Our estimates imply that automatic changes in fiscal policy are more
important. As described in Section 2, there are consistent and sub­
stantial changes in the automatic component of the surplus during
recessions. As a result, the OLS estimates suggest that the automatic
movements in fiscal policy after peaks add an average of 0.6 percentage
points to growth in the first year of recoveries, and the DRI model
suggests that they add 0.9 percentage points.
27. Our calculations assume that the changes in the real funds rate resulting from the
Federal Reserve's consistent responses to recessions have the same real effects as
other movements in the real funds rate. This appears to be a reasonable approxima­
tion, for two reasons. First, since the Federal Reserve adjusts the real funds rate
rapidly to economic developments, both the recession-related and the remaining part
of movements in the real funds rate have a large unanticipated component to them.
Second, for the real interest rate (in contrast to the money supply), there is no clear
reason for unanticipated and anticipated changes to have very different effects. As
described in Section 2, the fact that systematic Federal Reserve policy affects the
nominal funds rate, together with the fact that the direction of the effect is that
expansionary policy lowers the nominal rate, strongly suggests that the systematic
component of policy affects the real rate as well. It is possible, of course, that a larger
movement in the money supply is needed to bring about a given change in the real
funds rate when the movement is the result of systematic policy; but this is not
relevant to our calculations.




What Ends Recessions? * 47
Together, these results im ply that policies undertaken during reces­
sions are crucial to strong recoveries. All three sets of estimates suggest
that w ithout these policies, growth during the first year of recoveries
w o u ld be anemic. The OLS estimates im ply that it w ou ld have aver­
aged 2 .1 % , the IV estimates im ply 2 .0% , and the DRI estimates imply
1.4% . O u r results suggest that the main source o f the w eak growth that
w o u ld occur w ithout the postpeak changes in policy is the m onetary
tightening that usually occurs before peaks. The first colum n of Table

6

suggests that prepeak m onetary policy reduces grow th in the year after
troughs by roughly

1

percentage points.

N on policy factors appear to have little effect on growth in the year
follow in g troughs. The final colum n o f Table

6

show s the am ount of

above-average grow th not accounted for by prepeak or postpeak poli­
cies. W h ile this residual varies som ew hat depending on the multipliers
used, it is typically small, im plying that growth w ou ld have been
approxim ately average during the first year o f recoveries in the absence
of policy changes. Thus, nothing in our analysis suggests that output
w ou ld continue to drop indefinitely w ithout governm ental interven­
tion. Similarly, nothing suggests that the econom y possesses strong
self-correction mechanisms that w ou ld cause it to quickly make up the
output losses that occur during recessions.
Considering slightly longer horizons strengthens the case that m on e­
tary policy is critical to recoveries. For exam ple, output growth (at an
annual rate) in the fifth and sixth quarters o f recoveries averages only
0.1 percentage points above normal; but the OLS multipliers im ply that
postpeak m onetary policies contribute 1.4 percentage points to annual
grow th in these quarters, the IV multipliers im ply that they contribute
3.1 percentage points, and the DRI multipliers im ply that they con­
tribute

28.

0.2 percentage

points .28

We also investigated the implications ofusing multipliers from the MPS model
maintainedbytheFederalReserveBoard.TheMPS modelimpliesverygradual,but
verypersistent,effectsofmonetarypolicyonrealoutput.Thisresponseoccursmainly
because thenominallong-termrateisassumed toadjustgraduallytothenominal
short-termrate.Thisgradualadjustmentcausesthereallong-termratetofallessen­
tiallylinearlyinresponsetoapermanentchangeintherealfundsrate.Asaresult,
thechangeinthefundsratehasverylittleeffecton outputinthefirstyearanda
nearlypermanenteffectonoutputgrowth thereafter.Therefore,themodelsuggestsa
verydifferentviewofthesourceofrecoveriesthananyoftheestimatesconsideredin
thetext.The MPS multipliers,liketheOLS and DRI ones,implythatfiscalpolicy
contributesmoderately.Buttheextremelagsintheeffectsofmonetarypolicyinthe
modelmeanthatthemonetaryexpansionsundertakenduringrecessionshaveonlya
modest effecton growthduringthefirstyearofrecoveries.As aresult,themodel
impliesthatnonpolicyfactorsarethecriticalsourceofrecoveries.




48* ROMER & ROMER

4.3 IMPLICATIONS OF AN ALTERNATIVE BASELINE
The preceding analysis takes a constant real federal funds rate as the
baseline monetary policy and, therefore, describes output m ovem ents
resulting from changes in the real funds rate as being due to monetary
policy. But there are other possible baselines. In a conventional textbook
model where the Federal Reserve is targeting the grow th rate of the
m oney supply, nominal interest rates w ould decline in a recession
because of the fall in income and because of the increase in the real
m oney supply resulting from the fall in inflation. The effect on real
interest rates would be mitigated, how ever, by the decline in expected
inflation.
The magnitude of these effects depends on the interest and income
elasticities of m oney demand. Following the standard approach in the
m oney demand literature, assume that m oney dem and takes the form
In m t = a + b In y t - c In it + -

( 1)

dirt + \ In m t_ x,

where m t is real m oney balances, y t is real incom e, it is the nominal
interest rate, and irt is quarterly inflation. Equation ( 1 ) im plies that a
decline in y

with

m held fixed reduces ln z

by ( b / c ) A l n i /

and,

therefore, reduces i by approximately (b / c )[A In y ]i. Similarly, it im­
plies that a fall in the price level with the nom inal m o n ey stock held
fixed reduces i by approximately ( l / c ) ( l period and

[(1

-

d)[ A In p ]i in the initial

X )/c ][ A In p]i in subsequent periods. G oldfeld and

Sichel (1990), Judd and Scadding (1982), and others suggest that reason­
able values of the parameters in Equation ( 1) are b =

0. 12,

c = 0.05,

d = 0.7, and K = 0.8. These values im ply long-run incom e and interest
elasticities of 0.60 and - 0 . 2 5 , respectively.
To estimate the effect of the recession on interest rates w h e n m on ey
growth is held fixed, we need measures of the falls in output, prices,
and expected inflation due to the recession. W e com pute the fall in
output between the peak and the quarter follow ing the trough due to
the recession (the A In y term in the expression above) sim ply as the
o

.

shortfalls of quarterly output growth from its average value
% / 4 , or 0.69% . These values of the change in y , together with

the estimates of b and c and the actual values of the nom inal interest
rate, imply that if the Federal Reserve did not adjust the path o f the
m on ey stock, the falls in real income w ou ld reduce the nom inal interest
rate by an average of 0.9 percentage points over the period from the
peak to one quarter after the trough.
*ke recession on the price level, w e com pare the
actual path of the price level with w hat w o u ld have occurred if




What Ends Recessions? * 49
inflation had sim ply held steady at the value of expected inflation
im plied by our estimated real federal funds rate as of the peak quarter.
These estimates im ply that the increases in the real m oney supply
com ing from the declines in inflation reduce the nominal interest rate
by an average of 0.6 percentage points. Thus, the textbook self-correc­
tion m echanism o f dow nw ard pressure on prices increasing real m oney
balances and, therefore, low ering interest rates accounts for only a small
part of the interest rate declines during recessions .29
Finally, the estimates of expected inflation implied by our real funds
rate series suggest that expected inflation declines by an average of

1.4

percentage points betw een the peak and the quarter after the trough.
The fact that the direct effects of the declines in expected inflation more
than offset the effects of the increases in the real m on ey stock resulting
from the falls in inflation is consistent with the evidence of De Long
and Summers (1986) that price flexibility is on net destabilizing in the
U.S. econom y.
C om bining these three figures, our results suggest that if the Federal
Reserve w ere holding m on ey growth fixed, the behavior of income,
prices, and expected inflation w ou ld lead to only moderate falls in the
nom inal interest rate betw een the peak and the quarter after the trough
and have essentially no effect on the real interest rate. Thus, choosing a
baseline for m onetary policy that takes account of these effects w ould
not affect our conclusion that m onetary policy is the primary engine of
recovery from recessions .30

5. S tabilization and P ersisten ce
O u r analysis o f the contribution of m acroeconomic policy to output
grow th can be used to address tw o other issues. First, w e can examine
the overall role o f macroeconomic policy in economic stabilization.
Even if policy has contributed to recoveries, it is useful to consider its

An alternativewayofcomputingtheeffectoftherecessiononthepricelevelwould
be tocombine thefiguresforthedeclineinoutputwithstandardestimatesofthe
Phillipscurve(forexample,Gordon,1990).Doingthisyieldsaslightlylargerimplied
reductioninnominalinterestrates.
30.By describinganychangesintherealinterestratethatarenotdue tochangesin
income,prices,and expected inflationaschangesinmonetarypolicy,thebaseline
policyimplicithereismoney targetingthataccommodatesanyshiftsinthemoney
demand function.A naturalalternativechoiceofthebaselinewouldbepuremoney
targeting.We do notpursuethispossibilityfortworeasons.First,therehavebeen
largeshiftsinmoney demand, most ofwhich were largelyaccommodated by the
FederalReserve.Second,theresultsarelikelytobesensitivetothespecificationof
what itmeans fortheFederalReserve tocontinuewith "normal" money growth
duringrecessions.
29.




50 - ROMER & ROMER
effects in other periods. Second, we can investigate the extent to w hich
the persistence of overall output movements derives from the persis­
tence of policy changes and their effects.

5.1 THE OVERALL RECORD OF STABILIZATION POLICY
Our estimates of the contributions of policy to output grow th can be
used to construct estimates of what the path of real output w o u ld have
been if policy had held the real interest rate and the h igh -em ploym en t
surplus to GDP ratio constant. Figure 5 shows the implied paths o f real

Figure 5 OVERALL EFFECTS OF ACTIVE POLICY
a. Multipliers from OLS Regression

1.2

0.8
| 0.6

0.2
0

b. Multipliers from IV Regression
1.4 ------------------------ ----

1.2 -




GDP Without Active Policy

N.
./

What Ends Recessions? * 51
Figure 5 (continued)

c.MultipliersfromDRIModel

output under policies of a constant high-em ploym ent surplus to GDP
ratio and a constant real funds rate, together with its actual path, for
the three sets of multipliers. Since, as described earlier, m onetary policy
cannot in fact hold the real rate constant indefinitely, no great signifi­
cance should be attached to the longer-term m ovem ents in the differ­
ence betw een the implied and actual paths. But the shorter-term swings
can be interpreted as largely representing the effects of policy.
The O LS multipliers suggest that departures from the baseline poli­
cies have generally m ade recessions more severe, and recoveries more
rapid, than they otherwise w o u ld have been. The estimates imply, for
exam ple, that the 1960 and 1969 recessions w ou ld not have occurred at
all under the baseline policies, and that the output declines in the 1973
and 1981 recessions w ou ld have been half as large as they actually
were. These estimates suggest that the one major success of active
policy occurred in the last few years: Since growth has been weak
despite a falling real funds rate, the estimates im ply that there w ould
have been a protracted and severe recession under the baseline policies.
The IV multipliers suggest a generally similar picture. They imply,
how ever, that in addition to preventing a major dow nturn over the
past few years, active policy prevented extended periods of approxi­
mately zero grow th in the m id-1950s, m id-1970s, and mid-1980s. Finally,
the DRI multipliers im ply that the 1953 and 1960 recessions w ou ld not
have occurred under the baseline policies, that the 1969 and 1973
recessions w o u ld have occurred later and been slightly more severe,




52- ROMER & ROMER
and again that the 1990 recession w ou ld have been m uch longer and
larger.
This overall record of stabilization policy suggests that policy, espe­
cially monetary policy, helped to both start and stop postwar recessions.
Since both inflation control and output growth are generally considered
valid goals of macroeconomic policy, it w ould be hard to find consensus
that either of these uses of policy was inappropriate. G iven that
throughout most of our sample period inflation was at levels that (both
at the time and in retrospect) were view ed as excessive, it is arguable
that low output growth was likely to be n eeded at some time to reduce
inflation. The only issues concern the timing and speed o f disinflation.
Similarly, when output growth is low and inflation is low or falling,
most economists w ould probably agree that expansionary policy is
appropriate. Thus, the tightening and loosening of policy around reces­
sions and recoveries are hard to question.
In contrast, expansionary policy taken in face of a strong econom y
and of inflation that is high or rising m ight be generally v iew ed as
mistaken. By this standard, three times stand out as periods w h en
policy was

overly expansionary:

1 9 67 -1 968,

1972,

and

1 9 8 6 -1 9 8 7 .

Growth was above normal in all three periods. U nem ploym en t w as also
low to moderate in each case: 3.6% in 1967 -1 9 6 8 , 5.5% in 1972, and
6.5% in 1986-1987. Yet both the OLS and IV multipliers im ply that
policy was adding considerably to real growth in all three periods.
Averaged over these five years, the OLS multipliers im ply that m o n e­
tary policy contributed

1.2

percentage points to real grow th, and

discretionary fiscal policy contributed 0.5 percentage points. The same
numbers for the IV multipliers are 2.4 percentage points for m onetary
policy and

0.2 percentage

points for discretionary fiscal policy. The DRI

multipliers also imply that monetary policy contributed substantially to
growth in these years, with an average contribution of

0.6%

per year.

These multipliers imply, however, that discretionary fiscal policy had an
offsetting effect of - 0.7 percentage points, so that the overall contribu­
tion of policy was essentially zero .31
The nature of the expansionary policies differed across the episodes.
The 1967-1968 and 1 9 8 6 -1 9 8 7 episodes involved m oderately stimula­

31.

AsFigure4 shows,theDRImodelimpliesthatadecreaseinthesurplustoGDP ratio
has anegativeeffecton growthbeginninginthefifthquarterafterthe decrease.
Thesedelayedcontractionaryeffectsarethemainsourceofthemodel'simplication
thatfiscalpolicyreduced growthin1967-1968,1972,and 1986-1987.When these
effectsareomitted, theDRI multipliersimply thatdiscretionaryfiscalpolicycon­
tributedjust-0.1 percentagepointstoaveragegrowthintheseyears.Thedelayed
contractionary effectsof fiscalpolicyare also the main source of the estimated
moderatecontributionofprepeakautomaticanddiscretionaryfiscalpolicytooutput
growthm recoveriesreportedinTable6.




What Ends Recessions? •53
tive policies at relatively late stages in expansions. The stimulus in the
1 9 6 7 -1 9 6 8 period stem m ed from reductions in the high-em ploym ent
surplus in 1965 and 1966 and from an absence of consistent changes in
the nom inal federal funds rate in the face of rising inflation over the
period 1 9 6 5 -1 9 6 7 . The stimulus in 1986 and 1987 was the result o f a
general dow n w ard trend in both the high-em ploym ent surplus and the
nom inal federal funds rate, together with slight upw ard m ovem ents in
inflation. The 1972 episode, on the other hand, resulted from extremely
expansionary m onetary policy in the wake of the mild 1969 recession.
In the three quarters after the recession ended in the second quarter of
1970, the nom inal federal funds rate fell from 7.88%

to 3.86% . It

fluctuated irregularly over the next year, reaching a low of 3.54% in the
first quarter of 1972. Since inflation was, if anything, rising over this
period, the result was that m onetary policy was extremely stimulative.
Despite the differences in the nature of policy across these episodes,
they are united by the fact that expansionary policies stimulated an
already strong econ om y and, thus, set up the inflation that ultimately
induced later tightenings.

5.2 THE PERSISTENCE OF OUTPUT FLUCTUATIONS
A large recent literature examines the persistence of output movements.
The general conclusion of this research is that quarterly changes in real
G D P are h ighly persistent. The usual presum ption in interpreting these
findings, either implicit or explicit, is that output m ovem ents driven by
shifts in aggregate dem and will not be very persistent (see, for example,
N elson and Plosser, 1982, and Blanchard and Q u ah , 1989). As a result,
the conclusion that has been drawn from these studies is that supplyside disturbances m ust be a crucial source of fluctuations.
O u r examination of postwar m onetary and fiscal policies and their
contributions to output m ovem ents suggests that the presumption
underlying this conclusion should be reexamined. There are extended
periods w h en macroeconomic policy— particularly m onetary policy— is
either generally expansionary or generally contractionary. A n d our
estimates o f policies' effects im ply that the impact of any given policy
m ovem en t on the econom y is quite protracted. Thus, monetary and
fiscal policies' contributions to output m ovem ents m ay be highly persis­
tent.
To exam ine this issue formally, w e perform a bivariate experiment
analogous to the univariate one perform ed by Cam pbell and M ankiw
(1987a). C am pbell and M ankiw estimate som e simple processes for
overall outpu t grow th, and then use these processes to address the
question o f h o w forecasts o f the path of output should be revised in
response to an output innovation. A nalogously, w e decom pose output




54 * ROMER & ROMER
growth into the estimated contributions of discretionary policy and of
other factors and then ask h ow one should revise the forecasted path of
output in response to innovations in each of these tw o com ponents.
Specifically, w e estimate a bivariate vector autoregression (V A R ) us­
ing these two variables with four lags and then find the effects of
shocks to each of the variables. The sum of a shock's effects on
policy-related and nonpolicy-related growth represents its effect on the
path of output growth. Cumulating these grow th effects then gives its
effect on the path of the log of total output.
The results suggest that output innovations stem m ing from macroeconomic policies have considerably more persistent effects than inn o­
vations coming from other sources. Consider, for exam ple, the results
when the OLS multipliers are used to estimate the com p on en t of
output growth that is due to monetary policy and discretionary fiscal
policy and, thus, to decom pose output growth into policy and n on p o l­
icy components. The VAR implies that the overall output effect o f a 1%
shock to the nonpolicy com ponent of output peaks at 1.3% tw o quar­
ters after the shock and then gradually declines. The effect returns to
1% after six quarters and is 0.7% after 12. This relatively low persistence
occurs because the policy com ponent of output grow th responds nega­
tively to the nonpolicy component: Policymakers respond to positive
output innovations by tightening. The overall effect of 0.7% after 12
quarters, for example, reflects a contribution of +

1 .5 % from the n on p o l­
0.8% from the policy

icy component and an offsetting contribution of com ponent

The results imply that independent changes in the policy com ponent
of output growth, in contrast, have extremely persistent effects. A 1%
innovation raises overall output by

2.3%

after

4 quarters

and

2.4%

after

12. This strong persistence arises both because the policy com p on en t of
growth is highly serially correlated and because the nonpolicy co m p o ­
nent is essentially unresponsive to the policy com ponent. The strong
serial correlation of the policy com ponent, in turn, stems from the facts
that the estimated effects of real interest rate changes are quite pro­
tracted and that the real interest rate reverts to its m ean only slow ly .32

32.I
tisofcoursepossiblethattheoutputeffectsofashocktothepolicycomponentof

outputareeventuallyreversed.Indeed,ourprocedureforestimatingtheeffectsof
policyimplythatifshockstotherealinterestrateandthesurplus-to-GDPratioare
eventuallycompletelyundone,thelong-runeffectofashocktothepolicycomponent
ofoutputiszero.Asiswellknown,however,datafrom moderate timespanscan
shed littlelighton theeffectsofinnovationsatlong horizons, and conventional
estimatesofthepersistenceoffluctuations(suchasCampbellandMankiw's)reflect
effects at moderate ratherthan long horizons (see,for example, Christiano and
Eichenbaum, 1990).For thatreason,we focus on the effectsofinnovations over
severalyearsandmakenoattempttoestimatetheireffectsatverylonghorizons.




What Ends Recessions? •55
Using the IV and DRI multipliers to decom pose output growth into
the policy and nonpolicy com ponents produces generally similar re­
sults. The IV multipliers im ply that a 1% innovation to growth stem­
m ing from sources other than policy raises the level of output after
quarters b y

0.8% ,

while a

1%

12

innovation to the policy com ponent raises

output after 12 quarters by 1.9% . W ith the DRI multipliers, the figures
are 1.2% and 2 .4 % . Thus, these alternative sets of multipliers continue
to im ply that the policy-induced output m ovem ents are considerably
more persistent than other output m ovem ents.
Taken together, the results using all three sets of multipliers suggest
that the source o f the high degree o f persistence of aggregate output
fluctuations m ay be quite m undane. Rather than reflecting fundamental
characteristics o f fluctuations, it m ay sim ply reflect the fact that shifts in
macroeconomic policy and their effects on the econom y are often quite
protracted .33

6. C on clu sio n s
O ur central conclusion is that monetary policy alone is a sufficiently
pow erful and flexible tool to end recessions. In nearly every postwar
recession, policymakers have been quick to discern the onset of reces­
sion and have responded to the dow nturn with rapid and significant
reductions in nom inal and real interest rates. Plausible estimates of the
size and speed o f the effects of these interest rate cuts suggest that they
were crucial to the subsequent recoveries.
Discretionary fiscal policy, in contrast, does not appear to have had
an im portant role in generating recoveries. Fiscal responses to economic
dow nturns have generally not occurred until real activity was approxi­
mately at its trough. In addition, these responses have generally been
limited to m oderate actions that could be undertaken without congres­
sional approval or for w hich congressional approval was easy to obtain.
As a result, our estimates suggest that fiscal actions have contributed
only m oderately to recoveries. Policymakers have succeeded in making
large adjustm ents in fiscal policy in response to recessions only in
unusual circumstances. Thus, the historical record contradicts the view
that fiscal policy is essential to ending recessions or ensuring strong
recoveries.
W h ile m onetary policy has been crucial to postwar recoveries, our
results suggest that the overall record o f discretionary m onetary and

33.OurresultsareconsistentwiththefindingsofCampbellandMankiw(1987b)thatthe

component ofoutputmovements thatiscorrelatedwithmovements intheunem­
ployment rateisatleastaspersistentasgeneral output fluctuations.West (1988)
shows that a largely conventional model can imply that fluctuations driven by
aggregatedemandmovementsarerelativelypersistent.




56- ROMER & ROMER
fiscal policy is less impressive. O n e apparent error that has been made
on several occasions is for policymakers to becom e overly concerned
about the possibility of weak growth during expansions or excessively
optimistic concerning the prospects for expansion without triggering
inflation and, therefore, to adopt excessively expansionary policies. The
com m on pattern during recoveries is for there to be m odest increases in
interest rates and little change in the high-em ploym ent surplus. H o w ­
ever, in periods where policymakers have been concerned about low
growth, they have often undertaken major fiscal expansions or have
kept nominal interest rates constant or declining in the face o f rising
inflation. O n several occasions, such expansionary policies appear to
have contributed substantially to above normal growth.
Finally, our analysis of the effects of policy m ay help to explain the
persistence of movements in aggregate output. W e find that the large
degree of persistence of m ovem ents in real GDP appears to result to a
considerable extent from extremely high persistence of the contribution
of policy changes. Thus, policy is not only the source o f postwar
recoveries, but also the source of the puzzling serial correlation in
aggregate output.

REFERENCES
Bartlett, B. (1993). How not to stimulate the economy. The Public Interest
(Summer):99-109.
Beaudry, P., and G. Koop. (1993). Do recessions perm anently change output?
Journal of Monetary Economics 31:149-163.
Bemanke, B. S., and A. S. Blinder. (1992). The federal funds rate and the
channels of monetary transmission. American Economic Review 82:901-921.
Blanchard, O. J., and D. Quah. (1989). The dynamic effects of aggregate dem and
and supply disturbances. American Economic Review 79:655-673.
Boschen, J. F., and L. O. Mills. (1992). The effects of countercyclical m onetary
policy on money and interest rates: An evaluation of evidence from FOM C
documents. Manuscript, College of William and Mary (May).
Brunner, K., and A. H. Meltzer. (1964). The Federal Reserve's Attachment to the Free
Reserve Concept. U.S. Congress, House Committee on Banking and Currency,
Subcommittee on Domestic Finance, 88th Congress, 2d Session. W ashington,
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office.
Can £ !? r fl'i]tiY '' ^
G ‘ M ankiw* (1987a). Are output fluctuations transitory?
Quarterly Journal of Economics 102:857-880.




rev" mes: ,955- 86' Federal Reserve
Empl° yn“ " t Ac' of 1946- Federal

WJmt Ends Recessions? * 57
Christiano, L. J., and M. Eichenbaum. (1990). Unit roots in real GNP: Do we
know and do w e care? Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy
32:7-62.
Cook, T., and T. Hahn. (1989). The effect of changes in the federal funds rate
target on market interest rates in the 1970s. Journal of Monetary Economics
24:331-351.
De Long, J. B., and L. H. Summers. (1986). Is increased price flexibility stabiliz­
ing? American Economic Review 76:1031-1044.
Goldfeld, S. M., and D. E. Sichel. (1990). The demand for money. In Handbook of
monetary economics, vol. 1, B. M. Friedman and F. H. Hahn (eds). Amsterdam:
North-Holland, pp. 300-356.
Gordon, R. J. (1990). What is new-Keynesian economics? Journal of Economic
Literature 28 :1115-1171.
Hinshaw, C. E. (1968). The recognition pattern of the Federal Open Market
Committee. In Forecasting and recognizing business cycle turning points, R. Fels
and C. E. Hinshaw (eds). N ew York: Columbia University Press for NBER,
pp. 61-128.
Judd, J. P., and J. L. Scadding. (1982). The search for a stable money demand
function: A survey of the post-1973 literature. Journal of Economic Literature
20:993-1023.
Kareken, J., and R. M. Solow. (1963). Lags in monetary policy. In Stabilization
Policies, Commission on M oney and Credit, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice
Hall, pp. 14-96.
Mishkin, F. (1981). The real interest rate: An empirical investigation. CarnegieRochester Conference Series on Public Policy 15:151-200.
Nelson, C. R., and C. I. Plosser. (1982). Trends and random walks in macroeco­
nomic time series: Some evidence and implications. Journal of Monetary
Economics 10:139-162.
Perry, G. L., and C. L. Schultze. (1993). Was this recession different? Are they all
different? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (1):145-211.
Romer, C. D., and D. H. Romer. (1989). Does monetary policy matter? A new
test in the spirit of Friedman and Schwartz. NBER Macroeconomics Annual
3:121-170.
_____, a n d _____ . (1993). Credit channel or credit actions? An interpretation
of the postwar transmission mechanism. In Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City, Changing Capital Markets: Implications for Monetary Policy, pp. 71-116 .
______ a n d _____ . (1994). Monetary policy matters. Manuscript, University of
California, Berkeley. Journal of Monetary Economics, forthcoming.
Sichel, D. F. (1992). Inventories and the three phases of the business cycle.
Manuscript, Federal Reserve Board (August).
U.S. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Annual Report. Various
years.
U.S. Federal O pen Market Committee of the Federal Reserve System. Minutes.
Various years.
U.S. President. Economic Report of the President. Various years.
West, K. D. (1988). O n the interpretation of near random-walk behavior in GNP.
American Economic Review 78:202-209.