View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Financial Panics, the Seasonality of the Nominal Interest Rate,
and the Founding of the Fed
By JEFFREY A. MIRON*

After the founding of the Fed in 1914,1
the frequency of financial panics and the size
of the seasonal movements in nominal interest rates both declined substantially. Since
the Fed was established in part to "furnish
an elastic currency,"2 it is natural to hypothesize that the Fed caused these changes in
the behavior offinancialmarkets. There were,
however, a number of other major changes in
the economy and in the financial system
during this period including World War I,
the shift from agriculture to manufacturing,3
and the loosening of the gold standard.4
Moreover, Robert Shiller (1980) has examined the effect of the Fed's founding on
the seasonal in real interest rates and has
concluded that the Fed's actions had little or
no effect.
This paper investigates the relationship between financial panics, seasonal movements
in nominal interest rates, and the open
market operations of the Fed after 1914. The
paper establishes that the Fed, by carrying
out the seasonal open market policy that
eliminated the seasonal in nominal interest
rates, caused the decrease in the frequency of

panics. Since seasonal movements are anticipated and financial panics are probably real
events, the results show that an anticipated
monetary policy had real effects on the economy.
The issue of whether anticipated monetary
policy can affect real variables, which is at
the heart of monetary economics, has received much recent attention following the
well-known contributions by Robert Barro
(1977, 1978). His results have been subjected
to a barrage of critical review, much of it
supporting his finding that only unanticipated changes in money have real effects
(for example, Barro and Mark Rush, 1980;
Robert Litterman and Lawrence Weiss, 1985;
Robert Lucas, 1973; Shiller; Christopher
Sims, 1980),5 some of it arguing that the
evidence rejects the neutrality of anticipated
money (for example, Robert Gordon, 1982;
Frederic Mishkin, 1982, 1983).6 The generally inconclusive nature of the debate reflects
the difficulty of determining whether policy
caused or responded to changes in the economy and of distinguishing anticipated from
unanticipated policy actions. Thomas Sargent (1976), when describing the possible
observational equivalence of classical and
nonclassical models, suggested that identification would be aided if it were possible to
draw data from two different policy regimes.

* Department of Economics, University of Michigan,
Ann Arbor, MI 48109. I thank Stanley Fischer, Larry
Summers, Peter Temin, Olivier Blanchard, Milton
Friedman, Steve Zeldes, Steve O'Connell, Sue Collins,
Robert Clower, and two anonymous referees for helpful
comments on earlier drafts of this paper.
1
The Federal Reserve Act was passed by Congress on
December 23, 1913. The Board of Governors took office
and began planning the organization of the System on
August 10, 1914. The twelve banks opened for business
on November 16, 1914.
2
This quote is from the preamble to the Federal
Reserve Act.
3
The share of agriculture in Gross Domestic Product
fell from 24 percent in the period 1897-1901 to 12
percent in 1922. See Historical Statistics of the United
States,... (1976, Series F125-129, p. 232).
4
During World War I, several countries (including
Great Britain) left the gold standard, so the United
States was less affected by external conditions.




5
The approach to testing neutrality in Barro and
Rush is the same as in Barro (1977, 1978). LittermanWeiss and Sims use vector autoregressive techniques and
base their conclusions on the failure of money to be
Granger causally prior for real income. Lucas shows in a
cross section of countries that the variance of money
shocks is negatively correlated with the variance of
output movements.
6
Barro (1978) introduced the use of cross-equation
restrictions into this literature. This more powerful way
of testing neutrality has been exploited extensively by
Mishkin (1982, 1983), who has usually found that the
data reject neutrality, contrary to the results of Barro.

125










VOL. 76 NO. 1

MIRON: FOUNDING OF THE FED

the loans made by private banks should have
become less seasonal.
Section II examines empirically the implications of the model and the hypotheses it
suggests about the behavior of the Fed. These
results come from a simple model, but they
do not depend on the particular assumptions
made in order to keep the analysis simple.11
The model presented above is the most complicated one that can be tested empirically; it
is not possible to test the additional implications of more complicated models because of
data limitations.
II. The Evidence

A. Historical Background: The National
Banking System and the Founding of the Fed

The period from 1863 through 1913 is
known as the period of the National Banking
System because the provisions of the National Banking Acts of 1863, 1864, and 1865
determined the banking and financial structure in several critical ways. The National
Banking Acts were both a response to problems of the financial system that existed before the Civil War and a measure designed to
raise revenue for the North during the war.
The Acts successfully generated revenue and
cured some prewar financial ills (notably the
multiplicity of note issue). During the National Banking Period, however, those in
academia, the banking community, and
government still regarded the financial system as fundamentally flawed because of the
"perverse elasticity of the money supply"
and the high frequency of financial panics.
The term perverse elasticity of the money
supply referred to the tendency of the money
supply to contract in precisely those periods
when it was "needed" most. This occurred in
the spring and fall of each year when seasonal increases in loan and currency demand
forced interest rates up and reserve-deposit
ratios down. These seasonal movements in
loan and currency demand were attributed

11
AppendicesA and B to ch. IV of my disseration
show that the conclusions are still valid if one allows for
a pyramided banking system, or for the general equilibrium interactions of the economy.




129

mainly to the need for both currency and
credit by the agricultural sector of the economy in the spring planting season and the
fall crop-moving season, and to the need for
currency and credit by the corporate sector
for quarterly interest and dividend settlements. Additional currency was needed because the volume of transactions was higher
in these periods. Credit demand was high
because farmers borrowed to finance the
planting and harvesting of the crops.12
The financial panics that occurred in this
period were combinations of bank failures,
bank runs, and stock market crashes. A typical panic began after an individual bank was
hit by either an unexpectedly large deposit
withdrawal or a large loan default. If the
bank had a small amount of reserves, it
would need to call in some of its loans. This
might concern other banks enough so that
they would call in some of their loans, many
of which were in stock market call loans, and
the cumulative effect of loan recall by many
banks tended to depress the stock market. At
the same time, the fact that banks were calling in loans caused the nonbank public to
increase its desired currency-deposit ratio,
and this could cause either individual bank
failures or runs on many banks. Eventually
the process either reversed itself or ended in
a suspension of convertibility.13
There were, of course, differences in the
dynamics of various panics. Some began in
New York as the result of a large loan default at a New York bank and then were
transmitted West as New York banks tried
to acquire additional reserves from the country banks. Others started in the West when
crop failures damaged the liquidity positions
of country banks who then tried to recall
12

E. W. Kemmerer (1910, pp. 223-24) mentions increased rail and barge activity during warm weather and
holiday seasons as additional reasons for seasonal activity in the financial markets. A. Piatt Andrew (1906)
discusses the influence of agriculture on economic activity during the pre-Fed period, and J. Laurence Laughlin
(1912, pp. 309-42), discusses the seasonal cycle in general economic activity. See also O. M. W. Sprague
(1910), C. A. E. Goodhart (1969), and John James
(1978, pp. 127-37) for discussions of the seasonal flows
within the country that accompanied the seasonal
changes in interest rates and reserve positions of banks.
13
Sprague (pp. 1-225).

130

THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

balances from reserve cities. Nevertheless,
the key element of a panic was the same in
all of the major episodes. This key element
was a generally increased demand for reserves that could not be satisfied for all
parties simultaneously in the short run.
The likelihood that an event such as a
large loan default would precipitate a panic
depended on the initial position of the banking system. If such an event happened at a
time when loan demand was high or deposit
demand was low, so that the reserve-deposit
ratios of banks were low, then the costs
imposed by the loan default were higher.
Since there were seasonal movements in loan
and deposit demands that produced seasonal
movements in reserve-deposit ratios, panics
tended to occur in the fall and spring, when
high-loan demand and low-deposit demand
produced low reserve-deposit ratios. Thus the
problems of perverse elasticity and the
accompanying financial panics were partly a
result of and coincided with the seasonal
movements in asset demands.
The academics, bankers, and government
officials of the time understood this phenomenon. J. Laurence Laughlin, a professor of
economics at the University of Chicago,
commented in detail on this relation between
panics and seasonality in his 1912 treatise on
reform of the banking system (pp. 309-42).
Paul Warburg, a Wall Street banker who
later served on the Federal Reserve Board,
wrote in 1910 that "there can be no doubt
whatever that the basis for healthy control
by a central bank must exist in a country
where regular seasonal requirements cause,
with almost absolute regularity, acute increased demand for money and accommodation" (1930, p. 156). Leslie Shaw, Secretary of the Treasury from 1902 to 1906,
actively attempted to accommodate the seasonal demands in financial markets, although
the funds available to him were not sufficient
to allow him to be successful.14
The panic of 1907 precipitated sufficient
concern about panics and elasticity that

14
See Andrew (1907, p. 559), and Richard Timberlake (1978, p. 181). See Andrew (1907) also for an
interesting analysis of Shaw's other activities and
Timberlake (1963) for a critique of Andrew's analysis.




MARCH 1986

Congress passed the Aldrich-Vreeland Act of
1908. This Act addressed the problems of the
banking system by granting certain emergency powers to New York City banks and
by creating the National Monetary Commission. This Commission was assigned to undertake a detailed study of the U.S. banking
system. Its Report, published in 1910, contained in depth examinations of every aspect
of banking theory and practice in the United
States and abroad.
Two parts of the Report deserve particular
notice. O. M. W. Sprague, a professor of
economics at Harvard, wrote History of Crises
Under the National Banking System. This
book examined in detail the operation of the
banking system during five of the worst
financial crises (1873, 1884, 1890, 1893, and
1907). Sprague wrote that "with few exceptions all our crises, panics, and periods of
less severe monetary stringency have occurred in the autumn" (p. 157). E. W.
Kemmerer of Cornell contributed the volume
Seasonal Variations in the Relative Demands
for Money and Capital in the United States.
He noted that "the evidence accordingly
points to a tendency for the panics to occur
during the seasons normally characterized by
a stringent money market" (p. 232). Thus
two parts of the Report mentioned explicitly
the tendency for panics to occur in certain
seasons of the year.
The Federal Reserve Act established the
Federal Reserve System in 1913, three years
after the publication of the Commission's
Report. The preamble to the Act states that it
is "an act to... furnish an elastic currency."
It was to be expected, therefore, that the Fed
would try to eliminate panics by accommodating the seasonal demands in financial
markets.
B. Evidence of the Changes in
Financial Markets
I now document the two facts cited in the
introduction: the frequency of financial panics diminished after the founding of the Fed;
and the size of the seasonal fluctuations in
nominal interest rates diminished also.
Table 1 shows the starting dates of the
financial panics that occurred during the
period 1890-1908 according to Sprague and

TABLE 1—STARTING DATES AND CLASSIFICATION OF
FINANCIAL PANICS ACCORDING TO
SPRAGUE AND KEMMERER

Classification
Sprague
Financial Stringency

Crisis
Crisis
Kemmerer
Major Panics

Minor Panics




Year

Month

1890
1893
1907

August
May
October

1890
1893
1899
1901
1903
1907
1893
1895
1896
1896
1898
1899
1901
1901
1902
1904
1905
1906
1906
1907
1908

September
May
December
May
March
October
February
September
June
December
March
September
July
September
September
December

April
April
December
March
September

Sample
Period

Dependent
Variable

Significance
F- Statistics Level

1890-1908 vs.
1919-28
Nominal Interest Rate
Loans-Reserve Ratio
Loans
Reserves

Sample
Period

Significance
F-Statistics Level

Dependent
Variable

1890-1908 Nominal Interest
Loans-Reserve
Loans
Reserves
1919-28
Nominal Interest
Loans-Reserve
Loans
Reserves
1922-28
Reserve Credit
Total Credit




Rate
Ratio
Rate
Ratio

1.68
4.28
2.46
4.90
2.05
4.90
3.65
1.90
7.09
5.54

.003
.000
.000
.000
.000
.000
.000
.000
.000
.000

2.05
4.90
3.65
1.90

.000
.000
.000
.000

January
February
March
April
May

June
July
August
September
October
November
December




0
1
3
2
2
1
1
0
6
1
0
4










VOL. 76 NO. 1

MIRON: FOUNDING OF THE FED

(1929, 1930, 1932) while two were in the
spring (1931, 1933).20 Thus the recurrence of
panics during this period corroborates the
hypothesis that the Fed caused the reduction
in the frequency of panics after 1914.
The decreased accommodation of the Seasonals in asset demands was probably the
result of a generally restrictive open market
policy that the Fed initiated in late 1928.21
During much of the 1920's, there was fear
that speculation by participants in the stock
market was "excessive," and those who objected to the speculation most encouraged
the Fed to restrain the growth of credit,
particularly loans by banks to stock market
brokers. The officials at the Fed differed in
their view of how much to restrain credit. On
balance, however, they opposed restraining
speculation so much that it might adversely
affect general business activity.
This policy changed toward the end of
1928. Stock market speculation had been
especially virulent, and the Fed responded
with a strongly restrictive policy. The explanation for the change in policy is that
Benjamin Strong, the governor of the New
York Fed, died in October of 1928.22 During
the period 1915-28, Strong was a dominant
force in the Federal Reserve System and in
the entire financial community. In the words
of his biographer, Lester Chandler, Strong
was "one of the world's most influential
leaders in the fields of money and finance.
During the first fourteen turbulent, formative
years of the Federal Reserve System, his was
the greatest influence on American monetary
and banking policies" (1958, p. 3). Strong
intensely disliked stock market speculation,
but was an outspoken critic of restraining
speculation at the cost of causing a recession.
His death allowed the balance of opinion at
the Fed to shift toward greater restraint, and
a highly restrictive policy resulted. One of

20

See F r i e d m a n a n d Schwartz (pp. 305, 308, 313,
324).
21
See Paul Trescott (1982) for a more detailed examination of this aspect of F e d policy.
22
F r i e d m a n a n d Schwartz (pp. 4 1 1 - 1 9 a n d p p .
6 9 2 - 9 3 ) discuss in detail the effects of Strong's death o n
the power structure of the Fed.




137

the manifestations of this policy was the
incomplete accommodation of the seasonal
demands in financial markets.
F. The Real Effects of Financial Panics
The final issue discussed in this section is
whether financial panics had real effects on
the economy. It is not possible to test an
explicit model of the real effects of panics
because of data limitations.23 It is possible,
however, to demonstrate support for the
proposition that panics had real effects if one
is willing to make assumptions about what
these effects might have been. I assume here
that panics affected the distribution of output by decreasing the average level of real
activity, increasing the variance of real activity, and increasing the length of business
cycles.24
In the context of this paper there are two
implications of the proposition that panics
were real events. First, the distribution of
output in the pre-Fed period should have
been worse in panic years than in nonpanic
years; second, the distribution of output
post-Fed should have been better than that
pre-Fed.
Table 5 shows the mean and variance of
the rate of growth of annual real GNP for
the period 1890-1908 and for this period
minus the years in which panics occurred
(Kemmerer's major panic definition). The
average level of GNP growth is higher and
the variance of real growth lower for nonpanic years, so these facts support the hypothesis that panics altered the distribution
of output. They do not, of course, prove that
hypothesis, since panics might be the result
of negative output shocks. Nevertheless, the
facts in the table lend plausibility to the
proposition that panics changed the distribution of output during the pre-Fed period.

23

The data in Gordon are interpolations.
See B e n Bernanke (1983) for a n analysis of the
effects of t h e financial crises during the Great Depression, C a g a n for a discussion of the real effects of panics
d u r i n g the p r e - F e d period, a n d G o r t o n (1983) for work
o n t h e general relation between panics a n d business
cycles.
24

Peak

Trough

July 1890
May 1891
January 1893
June 1894
December 1895
June 1897
June 1899
December 1900
September 1902
August 1904
May 1907
June 1908
August 1918
March 1919
January 1920
July 1921
May 1923
July 1924
October 1926
November 1927
Average for Pre-Fed Period = 17.5 months
Average for Post-Fed Period = 14.25 months




Length
11
18
19
19
24
14
9
19
15
14

MIRON: FOUNDING OF THE FED

VOL. 76 NO. 1

above does not necessarily imply that continued elimination of interest rate Seasonals
is desirable. The analysis does show that an
important aspect of Fed policy is its seasonal
behavior, and it demonstrates that this aspect
of policy can have substantial real effects on
the economy.
REFERENCES
Andrew, A. Piatt, "The Influence of Crops
Upon Business in America," Quarterly
Journal of Economics, May 1906, 20,
323-53.
, "The Treasury and the Banks Under
Secretary Shaw," Quarterly Journal of Economics, August 1907, 21, 519-68.
Barro, Robert J., "Unanticipated Money
Growth and Unemployment in the United
States," American Economic Review, March
1977, 67, 101-15.
, "Unanticipated Money, Output, and
the Price Level in the United States,"
Journal of Political Economy, August 1978,
86, 549-80.
and Rush, Mark, "Unanticipated Money and Economic Activity," in Stanley
Fischer, ed., Rational Expectations and
Economic Policy, Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 1980, 27-74.
Bernanke, Ben S., "Nonmonetary Effects of
the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of
the Great Depression," American Economic Review, June 1983, 73, 257-76.
Bryant, John, "A Model of Reserves, Bank
Runs, and Deposit Insurance," Journal of
Banking and Finance, December 1980, 4,
335-44.
Cagan, Phillip, Determinants and Effects of
Changes in the Stock of Money, 18751960, New York: Columbia University
Press, 1965.
Chandler, Lester, Benjamin Strong, Central
Banker, Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1958.
Clark, Truman, "Interest Rate Seasonals and
the Federal Reserve System," unpublished
manuscript, University of Southern California School of Business Administration,
1983.
Diamond, Douglas W. and Dybvig, Philip H.,
"Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and




139

Liquidity," Journal of Political Economy,
June 1983, 91, 401-19.
Friedman, Milton, A Program for Monetary
Stability, New York: Fordham University
Press, 1959.
, "Monetary Policy: Theory and
Practice," Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking, February 1982, 14, 98-118.
Friedman, Milton and Schwartz, Anna J., A
Monetary History of the United States,
1867-1960, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1963.
Glass, Carter, An Adventure in Constructive
Finance, New York: Doubleday, Page, and
Co., 1927.
Goodhart, C. A. E., The New York Money Market and the Finance of Trade,
1900-1913, Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1969.
Gordon, Robert J., "Price Inertia and Policy Ineffectiveness in the United States,
1890-1980," Journal of Political Economy,
December 1982, 90, 1087-117.
Gorton, Gary, "Demand Deposits and Banking Panics," manuscript, Wharton School,
University of Pennsylvania, 1982.
, "Banking Panics and Business Cycles," manuscript, Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, 1983.
James, John A., Money and Capital in Postbellum America, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1978.
Kemmerer, E. W., Seasonal Variations in the
Relative Demand for Money and Capital in
the United States, National Monetary
Commission, S.Doc.588, 61st Cong., 2d
session, 1910.
Laughlin, J. Laurence, Banking Reform, Chicago: National Citizens League for the
Promotion of a Sound Banking System,
1912.
Litterman, Robert B. and Weiss, Laurence,
"Money, Real Interest Rates, and Output:
A Reinterpretation of Postwar United
States Data," Econometrica, January 1985,
53, 129-56.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr., "Some International
Evidence on Output-Inflation Tradeoffs,"
American Economic Review, June 1973, 63,
326-34.
Miron, Jeffrey A., "The Economics of Seasonal Time Series," unpublished doctoral

140

THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

dissertation, MIT, 1984.
Mishkin, Frederic S., "Does Anticipated Policy
Matter? An Econometric Investigation,"
Journal of Political Economy, February
1982, 90, 22-51.
, "Does Anticipated Aggregate Demand Policy Matter? Further Econometric
Results," American Economic Review, September 1983, 72, 788-802.
Rasche, Robert, "A Review of Empirical Studies of the Money Supply Mechanism,"
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review,
July 1972, 54, 11-19.
Sargent, Thomas, "The Observational Equivalence of Natural and Unnatural Rate
Theories of Macroeconomics," Journal of
Political Economy, July 1976, 84, 631-40.
Shiller, Robert, "Can the Fed Control Real
Interest Rates?," in Stanley Fischer, ed.,
Rational Expectations and Economic Policy,
Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1980, 117-68.
Sims, Christopher, "Comparison of Interwar
and Postwar Business Cycles: Monetarism
Reconsidered," American Economic Review Proceedings, May 1980, 70, 250-57.
Sprague, O. M. W., History of Crises Under the




MARCH 1986

National Banking System, National Monetary Commission, S.Doc.538, 61st Cong.,
2d session, 1910.
Timberlake, Richard H., "Mr. Shaw and His
Critics: Monetary Policy in the Golden
Era Reviewed," Quarterly Journal of Economics, February 1963, 77, 41-54.
, The Origins of Central Banking in
the United States, Cambridge: Harvard
University Press, 1978.
Trescott, Paul B., "Federal Reserve Policy in
the Great Contraction: A Counterfactual
Assessment," Explorations in Economic
History, July 1982, 19, 211-20.
Warburg, Paul M., The Federal Reserve System: Its Origins and Growth, Vol. II, New
York: Macmillan, 1930.
Willis, H. Parker, The Federal Reserve: A Study
of the Banking System of the United States,
New York: Doubleday, Page and Co.,
1915.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Annual Report, Washington: USGPO,
1914-33.
U.S. Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics
of the United States, Colonial Times to
1970, New York: Basic Books, 1976.